Skip to main content

Advertisement

Log in

The inter-industry employment effects of technological change

  • Published:
Journal of Productivity Analysis Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

This paper analyzes the inter-industry effects of a technological change on the employment in the Turkish manufacturing industry case over the 1985–1998 period. The inter-industry effects are calculated using input-output tables; the technological change is estimated as the growth of total factor productivity. The calculated simple employment multipliers show that the textile and garment industry has the highest capacity to generate employment in all manufacturing industries via intra- and inter-industry linkages. The study suggests that there is a labor substitution on the production employees whereas the forward linkages induced by technological change in other industries have positive effects. However, there is no evidence regarding the backward linkages. The technological change has a positive effect on the administrative employees but a negative effect on the production labor in the skilled labor intensive industries.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1
Fig. 2
Fig. 3
Fig. 4
Fig. 5

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. These multipliers are based only on backward linkages. As forward linkages can also be important in inter-industry employment effects and can be traced out only by econometric analysis, this study takes an econometric approach.

  2. Neary (1981) proposed that a labor saving technological change will reduce demand for labor. But, the negative effect of technological change will be minimized if real wages do not significantly increase (Sinclair 1981).

  3. For the inter-industry effects on wages, see Sicherman and Bartel (1999).

  4. The form of technological change, process and product innovation, matters for backward linkages. If process innovation leads to only a cost advantage as less inputs used, but not an increased output of industry j, a negative effect via backward linkages can be expected. However, process innovation which replaces labor in user industries may increase the employment in machine producer industries (Vivarelli 2014). When process innovation causes expanded output, a positive employment effect through backward linkages can be observed. In the case of product innovation, output volume would rise, so would employment, through backward linkages. Both process and product innovation are supposed to reduce output prices, which would generate positive employment effects via forward linkages. Due to the lack of data for the period covered in this study, product/process innovation distinction will not be made in the empirical analysis.

  5. Domestic in this expression refers to the exclusion of imported inputs.

  6. Output coefficient matrix should be used (Jones 1976) for forward linkages.

  7. A vector of n×1 technological change of industries, T, was turned into n×n matrix t where n is the number of industries.

  8. The capital price is approximated by the following equation: \(r\, = \,\alpha Y/K\, = \,\partial F/\partial K\) where r is the price of capital, Y real value added, K is capital stock. The idea is based on the standard intuition, i.e., firms will rent capital until the marginal product of capital becomes equal to the rental price. A Cobb-Douglas production function is assumed for the calculation of marginal product. Note that α multiplies the capital productivity ratio, therefore the estimated coefficient of this variable does not reflect the exact magnitude but the sign. K here was calculated by the standard capital accumulation equation and the initial capital stock was calculated as \({K_0}\, = \,I/(g\, + \,\delta )\) where I is real investment, g is the average growth rate of investment, and δ is depreciation rate (for the initial capital stock calculation see, Hall and Jones 1999).

  9. See appendix for the classification of industries.

  10. See the footnote 8 for the calculation of capital.

  11. Output data in Turkish Lira was converted into US Dollars for a comparison purpose.

  12. Total Factor Productivity was estimated as the Solow residual of a standard Cobb-Douglas production function. More specifically, \(TFP\, = \,VA - \alpha * K - \beta * L\) where TFP, VA, K and L stand for total factor productivity, value added, capital stock, and man-hour worked, respectively. α and β are the elasticity of capital and labor, respectively. In order to approximate these parameters, a Cobb-Douglass production function was estimated for the 77 four-digit industries over the period between 1982 and 2000 by using data obtained from Turkstat (varios years). A system GMM method used to control for endogeneity in capital.

  13. The reason why this period was studied is that the input-output tables and the manufacturing industry statistics are compatible only in this period. The methodology of both the input-output tables and the manufacturing industry statistics changed in 2002 in Turkey; so, the industries and their content changed. The manufacturing industries were defined according to the International Standard Industrial Classification (ISIC) prior to 2002; and according to the statistical classification of economic activities in the European Community (NACE- Nomenclature statistique des activités économiques dans la Communauté Européenne) following 2002.

  14. Since some industries included in the 1998 input-output table were merged to be compatible with the 1985 and the 1990 tables, 24 industries were left for the analysis. The forward and backward linkages were calculated for the years 1985, 1990, and 1998, for which the input-output tables are available; the linkages were interpolated for missing values.

  15. Greene (2005) proposes to compare 3SLS estimation results with 2SLS.

  16. This estimator was developed for datasets with large time dimension. Although the time dimension is 13 in the dataset, Hoechle (2007) states that small sample properties are much better than other robust estimators when cross-sectional dependence exists. So, this estimator was preferred.

  17. Using the normalized values of other control variables in the model lead to variance inflation factor to increase above 5, therefore, these variables were not normalized.

  18. Please note that variables are standardized, therefore, interpretations are made on the basis of standard deviation rather than percentage change.

References

  • Acemoğlu D (2002) Technical change, inequality and the labor market. J Econ Lit 40(1):7–72

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Acemoğlu D (2003) Labor and capital augmenting technical change. J Eur Econ Assoc 1(1):1–37

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Aydoğuş O (1999) Girdi-Çıktı modellerine giriş. Gazi Kitabevi, Ankara

  • Baltagi B, Rich D (2005) Skill-biased technical change in US manufacturing: a general index approach. J Econometrics 126:549–570

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bauer TK, Bender S (2004) Technological change, organizational change and job turnover. Lab Econ 11:265–291

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Baum CF (2006) An introduction to modern Econometrics using Stata. Stata Press, Texas

    Google Scholar 

  • Baum CF, Schaffer ME (2013) actest: Stata module to perform Cumby-Huizinga general test for autocorrelation in time series. Statistical Software Components S457668, Department of Economics, Boston College, Boston, http://ideas.repec.org/c/boc/bocode/s457668.html

  • Conte A, Vivarelli M (2011) Imported skill-biased technological change in developing countries. Dev Econ 49(1):36–65

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Çolak ÖF, Aydoğuş O and Lenger A (2012) Türkiye’nin Büyüme Stratejisi: Yapısal Analiz ve Politikalar, TİSK Yayınları, 325, Ankara

  • Cyert RM, Mowery DC (1987) Technology and employment: innovation and growth in the US economy. National Academy Press, Washington

    Google Scholar 

  • De Hoyos RE, Sarafidis V (2006) Testing for cross-sectional dependence in panel-data models. Stata J 6(4):482–496

    Google Scholar 

  • Driscoll JC, Kraay AC (1998) Consistent covariance matrix estimation with spatially dependent panel data. Rev Econ Stat 80:549–560

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Edquist C, Hommen L, McKelvey M (2001) Innovation and employment. Edward Elgar, Cheltenham

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Feldman H (2013) Technological unemployment in industrial countries. J Evol Econ 23:1099–1126

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gourvitch A (1966) Survey of economic theory on technological change and employment, 2nd edn. Augustus McKelley Publishers, New York

    Google Scholar 

  • Greene WH (2005) Econometric analysis, 3rd edn. Prentice Hall, New Jersey

    Google Scholar 

  • Gujaraati DN, Porter DC (2009) Basic econometrics, 5th edn. Mc-Graw-Hill, New York

    Google Scholar 

  • Hall R, Jones C (1999) Why do some countries produce so much more output per worker than others? Quar J Econ 114(1):83–116

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hoechle D (2007) Robust standard errors with panel regressions with cross-sectional dependence. Stata J 7(3):281–312

    Google Scholar 

  • Horn RA, Johnson CR (1999) Topics in Matrix Analysis. Cambridge University Press, New York

    Google Scholar 

  • Hornstein A, Krusell P, Violante GL (2007) Technology-policy interaction in frictional labour markets. Rev Econ Stud 74:1089–1124

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Howell DR (1985) The future employment effects of industrial robots: an input-output approach. Technol Forecast Soc Change 28:297–310. cited in Cyert RM and Mowery DC (1987) Technology and employment: innovation and growth in the US economy. National Academy Press, Washington

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Jenkins R (2008) Trade technology and employment in South Africa. J Dev Stud 44:60–79

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Jones LP (1976) The measurement of Hirscmanian linkages. Quar J Econ 90:323–333

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Katz LF and Margo RA (2013) Technical change and the relative demand for skilled labor: the United States in historical perspective. NBER Working Paper 18772

  • Leontieff W, Duchin F (1985) The future impact of automation on workers. Oxford University Press, Washington, New York cited in Cyert RM and Mowery DC (1987) Technology and employment: innovation and growth in the US economy. National Academy Press, Washington

    Google Scholar 

  • Manning A (2004) We can work it out: the impact of technological change on the demand for low-skill workers. Scot J Pol Econ 51(5):581–608

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Meschi E, Taymaz E, Vivarelli M (2009) Trade, technology and skills: evidence from Turkish microdata. Lab Econ 18:60–70

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Miller RE, Blair PD (2009) Input-output analysis: foundations and extensions, 2nd edn. Cambridge University Press, New York

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Mutl J (2002) Capturing technological change in an IO model: with application to calculations of embodied carbon emissions. International IO Conference 14, Montreal

  • Neary JP (1981) On the short-run effects of technological progress. Oxf Econ Pap 33(2):224–233

    Google Scholar 

  • Paul CJM, Siegel DS (2001) The impacts of technology, trade and outsourcing on employment and labor composition. Scan J Econ 103(2):241–264

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Pesaran MH (2004) General diagnostic tests for cross section dependence in panels. University of Cambridge Faculty of Economics, Cambridge Working Papers in Economics No. 0435

  • Piva M, Vivarelli M (2004) Technological change and employment: some micro evidence from Italy. App Econ Let 11:373–376

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • van Reenen J (1997) Employment and technological innovation: evidence from U.K manufacturing firms. J Lab Econ 15:255–284

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Rubart J (2007) The employment effects of technological change. Springer-Verlag, Berlin Heidelberg

    Google Scholar 

  • Sicherman N, Bartel AP (1999) Technological change and wages: an inter-industry analysis. J Pol Econ 107:285–325

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Sinclair PJN (1981) When will technical progress destroy jobs? Oxf Econ Pap 33(1):1–18

    Google Scholar 

  • Taymaz E (1998) Türkiye imalat sanayiinde teknolojik değişme ve istihdam. In: Bulutay T (ed) Teknoloji ve İstihdam. Devlet İstatistik Ensitüsü Yayınları, Ankara, pp 185–223

    Google Scholar 

  • Turkstat (1985, 1990, 1998) Input-Output Tables. Turkish Institution of Statistics, Ankara

  • Turkstat (various years) Manufacturing Industry Statistics, Turkish Institution of Statistics, Ankara

  • US Bureau of Labor Statistics (1986) Technology and employment: innovation and growth in the US economy. National Academy Press, Washington, Employment projections for 1995: data and methods. Government Printing Office, Washington DC cited in Cyert RM and Mowery DC (1987) Technology and employment: innovation and growth in the US economy. National Academy Press, Washington

    Google Scholar 

  • Vivarelli M (2014) Innovation, employment and skills in advanced and developing countries: a survey of economic literature. J Econ Issues 48(1):123–154

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Yaşar M, Paul CJM (2008) Capital-skill complementarity, productivity and wages: evidence from plant-level data for a developing country. Lab Econ 15:1–17

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Young K, Lawson C (1986) Technology and employment: innovation and growth in the US economy. National Academy Press, Washington, What fuels US job growth? Changes in technology and demand on employment growth across industries, 1972-84. Paper prepared for the Panel on Technology and Employment cited in Cyert RM and Mowery DC (1987) Technology and employment: innovation and growth in the US economy. National Academy Press, Washington

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgments

I am grateful to Erol Taymaz and Anıl Duman for their valuable comments and advices, and to Ebru Voyvoda, who generously shared her work on the harmonization of industries between the input-output tables and the international standard classification (ISIC). The financial support provided by The Scientific and Technological Research Council of Turkey (TUBITAK) with project no. 107K384 is greatly acknowledged. Earlier versions of this paper were presented in North American Productivity Workshop VI, June 3–5, 2010, Houston, USA, and at a departmental seminar Oviedo University, Spain. I also thank the participants of both events for their comments. The usual disclaimer applies.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Aykut Lenger.

Ethics declarations

Conflict of interest

The authors declare that they have no conflict of interest.

Appendıx

Appendıx

Table 6

Table 6 Skill intensity of industries

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Lenger, A. The inter-industry employment effects of technological change. J Prod Anal 46, 235–248 (2016). https://doi.org/10.1007/s11123-016-0485-z

Download citation

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s11123-016-0485-z

Keywords

JEL Classification

Navigation