Skip to main content

Advertisement

Log in

How household transportation expenditures have evolved in Canada: a long term perspective

  • Published:
Transportation Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

In recent years, increasing recognition of the challenges associated with global climate change and inequity in developed countries have revived researcher’s interest towards analyzing transportation related expenditure of households. The current research contributes to travel behaviour literature by developing an econometric model of household budgetary allocations with a particular focus on transportation expenditure. Towards this end, we employ the public-use micro-data extracted from the Survey of Household Spending (SHS) for the years 1997–2009. The proposed econometric modeling approach is built on the multiple discrete continuous extreme value model (MDCEV) framework. Specifically, in our analysis, the scaled version of the MDCEV model outperformed its other counterparts. Broadly, the model results indicated that a host of household socio-economic and demographic attributes along with the residential location characteristics affect the apportioning of income to various expenditure categories and savings. We also observed a relatively stable transportation spending behaviour over time. Additionally, a policy analysis exercise is conducted where we observed that with increase in health expenses and reduction in savings results in adjustments in all expenditure categories.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. There has been recent research exploring transport and time budget allocation in a unified framework (see Konduri et al. 2011 and Anas 2007 for such literature).

  2. The adjusted likelihood ratio index \(\left(\bar{\rho}^{2} \right)\) for the traditional MDCEV, scaled MDCEV, and mixed MDCEV models is computed as \(\left( {1 - \frac{LL\left( \beta \right) - K}{LL\left( C \right)}} \right)\), where LL(β) is the log-likelihood at convergence, K is the number of model parameters (excluding the baseline constants and translation parameters), and LL(C) is the likelihood with only the constants and translation parameters.

References

  • Anas, A.: A unified theory of consumption, travel and trip chaining. J. Urban Econ. 62(2), 162–186 (2007)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Anowar, S., Eluru, N., Miranda-Moreno, L.F.: Analysis of vehicle ownership evolution in Montreal, Canada using pseudo panel analysis. Transportation 43(3), 531–548 (2016)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Asensio, J., Matas, A., Raymond, J.-L.: Petrol expenditure and redistributive effects of its taxation in Spain. Transp. Res. Part A Policy Pract. 37(1), 49–69 (2003a)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Asensio, J., Matas, A., Raymond, J.-L.: Redistributive effects of subsidies to urban public transport in Spain. Transp. Rev. 23(4), 433–452 (2003b)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Barr-Telford, L.: Spending patterns of couples without children. Perspectives Labour Income 6, 2 (1994)

    Google Scholar 

  • Bawa, K., Ghosh, A.: A model of household grocery shopping behavior. Mark. Lett. 10(2), 149–160 (1999)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bergantino, A.S.: Estimating Engel curves for transport expenditures: evidence from UK household budget data. Int. J. Trans. Econ./Rivista internazionale di economia dei trasporti 24(2), 279–305 (1997)

    Google Scholar 

  • Bhat, C.R.: A multiple discrete-continuous extreme value model: formulation and application to discretionary time-use decisions. Transp. Res. Part B 39(8), 679–707 (2005)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bhat, C.R.: The multiple discrete-continuous extreme value (MDCEV) model: role of utility function parameters, identification considerations, and model extensions. Transp. Res. Part B Methodol. 42(3), 274–303 (2008)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bhat, C.R., Eluru, N.: The multiple discrete-continuous extreme value (MDCEV) model: formulation and applications. In: Hess, S., Daly, A. (eds.) Choice Modelling: The State-of-the-Art and the State-of-Practice, Proceedings from the Inaugural International Choice Modelling Conference, Chap. 4, pp. 71–100. Emerald Group Publishing (2010)

  • Bilgic, A., Yen, S.T.: Household alcohol and tobacco expenditures in Turkey: a sample-selection system approach. Contemp. Econ. Policy 33(3), 571–585 (2015)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Browning, M.: Children and household economic behavior. J. Econ. Lit. 30, 1434–1475 (1992)

    Google Scholar 

  • Castro, M., Bhat, C.R., Pendyala, R.M., Jara-Diaz, S.: Accommodating multiple constraints in the multiple discrete-continuous extreme value (MDCEV) choice model. Transp. Res. Part B Methodol. 46(6), 729–743 (2012)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Choo, S., Lee, T., Mokhtarian, P.: Do transportation and communications tend to be substitutes, complements, or neither?: U.S. Consumer Expenditures Perspective, 1984–2002. Transp. Res. Rec. J. Transp. Res. Board 2010, 121–132 (2007)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dargay, J.M.: Determinants of car ownership in rural and urban areas: a pseudo-panel analysis. Transp. Res. Part E Log. Transp. Rev. 38(5), 351–366 (2002)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dargay, J.M., Vythoulkas, P.C.: Estimation of a dynamic car ownership model: a pseudo-panel approach. J. Trans. Econ. Policy 33(3), 287–302 (1999)

    Google Scholar 

  • Deaton, A.S., Ruiz-castiiio, J., Thomas, D.: The influence of household composition: on household expenditure patterns: theory and spanish evidence. J. Polit. Econ. 97(1), 179 (1989)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • De Palma, A., Rochat, D.: Mode choices for trips to work in Geneva: an empirical analysis. J. Transp. Geogr. 8(1), 43–51 (2000)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dynan, K.E., Skinner, J., Zeldes, S.P.: Do the Rich Save More? (No. w7906). National Bureau of Economic Research (2000)

  • Eltony, M.N.: Transport gasoline demand in Canada. J. Trans. Econ. Policy 27(2), 193–208 (1993)

    Google Scholar 

  • Ferdous, N., Pinjari, A., Bhat, C., Pendyala, R.: A comprehensive analysis of household transportation expenditures relative to other goods and services: an application to United States consumer expenditure data. Transportation 37(3), 363–390 (2010)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fiebig, D.G., Keane, M.P., Louviere, J., Wasi, N.: The generalized multinomial logit model: accounting for scale and coefficient heterogeneity. Mark. Sci. 29(3), 393–421 (2010)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fousekis, P., Lazaridis, P.: Food expenditure patterns of the urban and the rural households in Greece. A kernel regression analysis. Agric. Econ. Rev. 2(1), 5–19 (2001)

    Google Scholar 

  • Hanly, M., Dargay, J.: Car ownership in Great Britain: panel data analysis. Transp. Res. Record J. Transp. Res. Board 1718, 83–89 (2000)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hong, G.-S., Fan, J.X., Palmer, L., Bhargava, V.: Leisure travel expenditure patterns by family life cycle stages. J. Travel Tour. Mark. 18(2), 15–30 (2005)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Karlaftis, M., Golias, J.: Automobile ownership, households without automobiles, and urban traffic parameters: are they related? Transp. Res. Record J. Transp. Res. Board 1792, 29–35 (2002)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Konduri, K., Astroza, S., Sana, B., Pendyala, R., Jara-Díaz, S.: Joint analysis of time use and consumer expenditure data. Transp. Res. Record J. Transp. Res. Board 2231, 53–60 (2011)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Matas, A., Raymond, J.-L.: Changes in the structure of car ownership in Spain. Transp. Res. Part A Policy Pract. 42(1), 187–202 (2008)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Milligan, K.: The evolution of elderly poverty in Canada. Can. Public Policy 34(4), S79–S94 (2008)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Nolan, A.: The determinants of urban household’s transport decisions: a microeconometric study using Irish data. Int. J. Transp. Econ. 30(1), 103–129 (2003)

    Google Scholar 

  • Oladosu, G.: An almost ideal demand system model of household vehicle fuel expenditure allocation in the United States. Energy J. 1–21; 2003

  • Palm, M., Gregor, B., Wang, H., McMullen, B.S.: The trade-offs between population density and households' transportation-housing costs. Transp. Policy 36, 160–172 (2014)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Paulin, G.D.: A comparison of consumer expenditures by housing tenure. J. Consum. Aff. 29(1), 164–198 (1995)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Pinjari, A.R., Bhat, C.R.: Computationally efficient forecasting procedures for Kuhn-Tucker consumer demand model systems: application to residential energy consumption analysis. Technical paper, Department of Civil and Environmental Engineering, The University of South Florida (2011)

  • Pitts, R.E., Willenborg, J.F., Sherrell, D.L.: Consumer adaptation to gasoline price increases. J. Consum. Res. 8(3), 322–330 (1981)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Sanchez, T.W., Makarewicz, C., Haas, P.M., Dawkins, C.J.: Transportation Costs, Inequities, and Trade-Offs. Paper presented at the 86th Annual Meeting of the Transportation Research Board, Washington D.C (2007)

  • Sanko, N.: Travel demand forecasts improved by using cross-sectional data from multiple time points. Transportation 41(4), 673–695 (2014)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Soberon-Ferrer, H., Dardis, R.: Determinants of household expenditures for services. J. Consum. Res. 17, 385–397 (1991)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Thakuriah, P., Liao, Y.: Analysis of variations in vehicle ownership expenditures. Transp. Res. Record J. Transp. Res. Board 1926, 1–9 (2005)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Thakuriah, P., Liao, Y.: Transportation expenditures and ability to pay: evidence from consumer expenditure survey. Transp. Res. Record J. Transp. Res. Board 1985, 257–265 (2006)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Thakuriah, P., Mallon-Keita, Y.: An analysis of household transportation spending during the 2007-2009 US economic recession. Paper presented at the 93rd Annual Meeting of the Transportation Research Board, Washington D.C (2014)

  • Train, K.: Discrete Choice Methods with Simulation. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge (2009)

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Wu, G., Yamamoto, T., Kitamura, R.: Vehicle ownership model that incorporates the causal structure underlying attitudes toward vehicle ownership. Transp. Res. Record J. Transp. Res. Board 1676, 61–67 (1999)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Yee, J.L., Niemeier, D.: Advantages and disadvantages: longitudinal vs. repeated cross-section surveys. Project Battelle 94, 16–22 (1996)

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgements

The first author gratefully acknowledges the help of Mr Eamon Duffy in providing the data used in the research. The authors would also like to acknowledge the useful feedback from Prof. Patricia Mokhtarian and three anonymous reviewers on a previous version of the paper.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Naveen Eluru.

Electronic supplementary material

Below is the link to the electronic supplementary material.

Supplementary material 1 (DOCX 98 kb)

Appendices

Appendix 1: Mathematical formulation of MDCEV models

We provide a brief formulation of the econometric structure of the traditional MDCEV model and then extend the discussion to the formulation for MMDCEV and SMDCEV.

Basic structure and traditional MDCEV model

It is reasonable to expect that the money allocated to different expenditure categories depends on the marginal utility that households derive from spending in those categories. Let us consider that there are K different expenditure categories that a household can potentially allocate its money to. If x k represents the allotted non-negative amount of the total budget to each expenditure category k (including savings), the total utility derived from such allocation can be expressed in the following additive non-linear functional form (Bhat 2008):

$$U\left( \varvec{x} \right) = \mathop \sum \limits_{k = 1}^{K} \frac{{\gamma_{k} }}{{\alpha_{k} }}\psi_{k} \left\{ {\left( {\frac{{x_{k} }}{{\gamma_{k} }} + 1} \right)^{{\alpha_{k} }} - 1} \right\}; \psi_{k} > 0, \alpha_{k} \le 1, \gamma_{k} > 0$$
(1)

where \(U\left( \varvec{x} \right)\) is a quasi-concave, increasing, and continuously differentiable function with respect to the expenditure quantity (K × 1)—vector x (x k  ≥ 0 for all k alternatives), γ k and α k are parameters associated with alternative k. ψ k represents the baseline marginal utility. Through this term, the effect of observed and unobserved alternative attributes, decision-maker attributes, and the choice environment attributes may be introduced as ψ k  = exp(β z k  + ɛ k ), where z k represents the vector of exogenous variables and ɛ k captures the idiosyncratic characteristics that affect the baseline utility. γ k enables corner solutions while simultaneously influencing satiation and α k influences satiation only. Note that the above utility function is formulated considering absence of outside goods (goods that is always consumed).

If, however, an outside goods is present, the utility function can be modified as follows using the same notational preliminaries:

$$U\left( \varvec{x} \right) = \frac{1}{{\alpha_{1} }}\exp \left( {\varepsilon_{1} } \right)\left\{ {\left( {x_{1} + \gamma_{1} } \right)^{{\alpha_{1} }} } \right\} + \mathop \sum \limits_{k = 2}^{K} \frac{{\gamma_{k} }}{{\alpha_{k} }}exp\left( {\beta^{\prime}z_{k} + \varepsilon_{k} } \right)\left\{ {\left( {\frac{{x_{k} }}{{\gamma_{k} }} + 1} \right)^{{\alpha_{k} }} - 1} \right\}$$
(2)

In the above formula, we need γ 1 ≤ 0, while γ k  > 0 for k > 1. Also, we need (x 1 + γ 1) > 0. The magnitude of γ 1 may be interpreted as the required lower bound (or a “subsistence value”) for consumption of the outside goods. In the above baseline parameter expression, the term ɛ 1 is an idiosyncratic term assumed to be identically and independently standard type I extreme-value distributed across households, as well as independent of the terms in the baseline parameter expression for other alternatives (inside goods).

It is very challenging to identify γ k and α k simultaneously in empirical applications for the outside and inside goods (see, Bhat 2008 and Bhat and Eluru 2010 for an elaborate discussion on the issue). Usually, the analyst can choose to estimate satiation using either γ k or α k , since these two parameters have similar role in terms of allowing for satiation. Depending on the chosen parameter structure for estimation, different utility structures can be estimated and the selection of the most appropriate form is based on statistical considerations.

If only γ k parameters are estimated the utility simplifies to γ-profile

$$U\left( \varvec{x} \right) = \exp \left( {\varepsilon_{1} } \right)\ln \left\{ {\left( {x_{1} + \gamma_{1} } \right)} \right\} + \mathop \sum \limits_{k = 2}^{K} \gamma_{k} exp\left( {\beta^{\prime}z_{k} + \varepsilon_{k} } \right)\left\{ {ln\left( {\frac{{x_{k} }}{{\gamma_{k} }} + 1} \right)} \right\}$$
(3)

Similarly, if only α k parameter are estimated, the corresponding utility expression collapses to α-profile

$$U\left( \varvec{x} \right) = \frac{1}{{\alpha_{1} }}\exp \left( {\varepsilon_{1} } \right)\left\{ {x_{1}^{{\alpha_{1} }} } \right\} + \mathop \sum \limits_{k = 2}^{K} \frac{1}{{\alpha_{k} }}exp\left( {\beta^{\prime}z_{k} + \varepsilon_{k} } \right)\left\{ {\left( {x_{k} + 1} \right)^{{\alpha_{k} }} - 1} \right\}$$
(4)

Let V k be the alternative utility. The expressions for V k for γ-profile and α-profile utility forms are as below:

$$V_{k} = \beta^{\prime}z_{k} - ln\left( {\frac{{x_{k}^{*} }}{{\gamma_{k} }} + 1} \right) - ln p_{k} \left( {k \ge 2} \right); V_{1} = - ln\left( {x_{1} + \gamma_{1} } \right)$$
(5)
$$V_{k} = \beta^{\prime}z_{k} + \left( {\alpha_{k} - 1} \right)\ln \left( {x_{k}^{*} + 1} \right) - ln p_{k} \left( {k \ge 2} \right); V_{1} = \left( {\alpha_{1} - 1} \right)ln\left( {x_{1}^{*} } \right)$$
(6)

We would assume (following Bhat 2005, 2008) that ɛ k ’s are independently and identically distributed across alternatives with a scale parameter of σ. Given the values of the alternative utilities for the two profiles, the probability expression for the expenditure allocation to the first M of the K goods (M ≥ 1) is:

$$P\left( {e_{1}^{*} , e_{2}^{*} , e_{3}^{*} , \ldots ,e_{M}^{*} ,0,0,0, \ldots ,0} \right) = \frac{1}{{\sigma^{M - 1} }}\left[ {\mathop \prod \limits_{i = 1}^{M} C_{i} } \right]\left[ {\mathop \sum \limits_{i = 1}^{M} \frac{1}{{C_{i} }}} \right]\left[ {\frac{{\mathop \prod \nolimits_{i = 1}^{M} \exp^{{\frac{{V_{i} }}{\sigma }}} }}{{\left( {\mathop \sum \nolimits_{k = 1}^{K} \exp^{{\frac{{V_{k} }}{\sigma }}} } \right)^{M} }}} \right]\left( {M - 1} \right)!$$
(7)

where \(C_{i} = \frac{{1 - \alpha_{i} }}{{e_{i}^{*} + \gamma_{i} p_{i} }}\). In the traditional MDCEV model, the scale parameter \(\sigma\) is set to 1 for normalization.

Scaled MDCEV model

In our context, due to the inherent differences across the expenditure databases across years and different economic conditions, we can estimate the scale parameter provided we normalize σ for 1 year. The σ is parameterized as \({ \exp }\left( {\delta y} \right)\) where y is the vector of time elapsed variable as well as the annual economic indicators and δ is the corresponding coefficient vector to be estimated. The δ parameters are significant when they are different from 0 as that would imply that the scale parameter will be different from 1. The same expression in Eq. 7 is adopted with the appropriate σ for probability and likelihood computations.

Mixed MDCEV model

The mixed MDCEV model accommodates unobserved heterogeneity in the effect of exogenous variables (random coefficients structure) and correlations across alternatives (error correlations structure). The baseline parameter expression for the inside alternatives in Eq. 2 can be expressed as follows:

$$\psi_{k} = exp\left\{ {(\beta_{k}^{'} + \alpha_{k}^{'} ) z_{k} + \eta^{\prime}w_{k} + \xi_{k} } \right\}$$
(8)

In the above equation, β and α are column vector of parameters, where β represents the mean effect and α represents household level disturbance of the coefficient. The term η w k constitutes the mechanism to generate household level correlation across unobserved utility components of the alternatives. In this component, w k is specified to be a column vector of dimension H with each row representing a group h (h = 1, 2, …, H) of alternatives sharing common household-specific unobserved components and the vector η may be specified as a H-dimensional realization from a multivariate normally distributed random vector η, \(\eta \,\sim\,N\left( {0,\varOmega } \right).\) As before, the component, ξ k is assumed to be independently and identically Gumbel distributed across households. For complete formulation of likelihood for the MMDCEV model see, Bhat and Eluru (2010).

The parameters of MMDCEV model are estimated using maximum simulated likelihood procedure. Specifically, scrambled Halton sequence is used to draw realizations from the population normal distribution. In this research, the stability of the parameter estimates was tested using varying number of Halton draws per observation for the specifications considered, and the results were found to be stable with 100 draws.

Appendix 2: Dependent variable definition

See Table 3.

Table 3 Dependent variables

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Anowar, S., Eluru, N. & Miranda-Moreno, L.F. How household transportation expenditures have evolved in Canada: a long term perspective. Transportation 45, 1297–1317 (2018). https://doi.org/10.1007/s11116-017-9765-3

Download citation

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s11116-017-9765-3

Keywords

Navigation