Skip to main content
Log in

Understanding Public Sector Debt: Financial Vicious Circle under the Soft Budget Constraint

  • Published:
Public Organization Review Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

The article explains why debt of public sector organizations grows beyond the sustainable level by focusing on the principal-agent relationship under the soft budget constraint. Specifically, this article explores the extent to which factors affect the level of public sector debt in the context of quasi-autonomous non-governmental organizations (quangos) in Korea over the past two decades (1993–2012). The findings from the panel data analysis suggest that the level of public sector debt increases as an outcome of the financial vicious circle created by the soft budget constraint: a knock-on effect of the moral hazard of quangos as well as the opportunistic behavior of political principals. Public sector debt is positively associated with agency-specific factors as well as the factors related to the political incentives such as policy preferences and electoral considerations. However, macroeconomic factors made little difference to the general pattern of the evidence.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1
Fig. 2

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. Deficit occurs when expenditure exceeds revenue in a given time, while debt is an accumulation of yearly deficits. Therefore, large deficit results in the rise in public debt.

  2. Since 2011, the Korean government has compiled public debt from the general government as well as public sector debt generated by quangos, corporate debt, and household debt.

  3. Rogoff (1990: 21) argues that a political business cycle is the result of the temporal information asymmetries about the incumbent leader’s “competence” and the biases resulting from attempts at “pre-election signaling,” which increases government consumption expenditure before elections.

  4. A more recent model developed by Moesen and van Cauwenberge (2000: 208) predicts that voters are more reluctant to increase the production of public goods when they know they have to pay the full production costs of those goods. However, such arguments were criticized later for lack of rigor and for being “based upon... somewhat questionable notions” (Alesina and Tabellini 1990: 403).

  5. A bilateral monopoly between bureaucrats and politicians allows us to consider their preferences and incentives separately in the democratic political system (Casas-Pardo and Puchades-Navarro 2001).

  6. Rodden (2007) used the concept to describe the behavior of lower level governments under fiscal federalism relying on fiscal rescue or bailout through intergovernmental grants.

  7. Such stimulative fiscal policies as tax cuts, interest rate cuts, and spending increases are politically popular before elections, but result in serious long-term costs such as inflation (Nordhaus 1975).

  8. A liberal or left-wing government favors default on outstanding debt, while a conservative or right-wing government can take advantage of the deliberate accumulation of debt (Aghion and Bolton 1990).

  9. Although quangos are separated from the government, politicians and public officials are able to control them by keeping their involvement “arms’ length but hands on” (Taylor 1997) through formal and informal connections, such as political patronage (Skelcher 1998).

  10. Bad projects can be financed not only for political reasons but also for economic ones, such as sunk costs and profitability (Dewatripont and Maskin 1995: 542–543). Bad projects may not be terminated if the cost of continuing them is smaller than the cost of starting new projects, which might be worse than the existing ones (Bai and Wang 1998: 42).

  11. President Young-sam Kim (1993–1998) focused on improving/reducing financial/economic regulations, industry promotion, inspection/verification; President Dae-jung Kim (1998–2003) focused on the economy, international relations, privatization, IT, and real estate; President Moo-hyun Roh (2003–2008) prioritized social welfare, labor relations, participation, and decentralization; and the main agendas for President Myoung-bak Lee (2008–2013) were natural resources, construction, energy, environment, science and technology.

References

  • Aghion, P., & Bolton, P. (1990). Government domestic debt and the risk of default: A political-economic model of the strategic role of debt. In Dornbrusch & Draghi (Eds.), Public debt management: Theory and history. Cambridge, UK: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Alesina, A., & Tabellini, G. (1990). A positive theory of fiscal deficits and government debt. The Review of Economic Studies, 57(3), 403–414.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Alt, J. E., & Lassen, D. D. (2006). Fiscal transparency, political parties, and debt in OECD countries. European Economic Review, 50(6), 1403–1439.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Baber, W. R., & Sen, P. K. (1986). The political process and the use of debt financing by state governments. Public Choice, 48(4), 201–215.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bai, C., & Wang, Y. (1998). Bureaucratic control and the soft budget constraint. Journal of Comparative Economics, 26, 41–61.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bartel, A. P., & Harrison A. E. (1999). “Ownership versus Environment: Why Are Public Sector Firms Inefficient?” NBER Working Paper No. 7043.

  • Benito, B., & Bastida, F. (2009). Budget transparency, fiscal performance, and political turnout: an international approach. Public Administration Review, 69(3), 403–417.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bennett, J. T. (2004). Underground government: the off-budget public sector. The Encyclopedia of Public Choice, 587–589.

  • Bennett, J. T., & DiLorenzo, T. J. (1983, May 24). “Underground government.” Proquest Historical Newspapers: The Christian Science Monitor (1908–1999), p. 23.

  • Bertelli, A. (2006). The role of political ideology in the structural Design of New Governance Agencies. Public Administration Review, 66(4), 583–595.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bertelli, A. M. (2008). Credible governance? Transparency, political control, the personal vote and British quangos. Political Science, 56(4), 807–829.

    Google Scholar 

  • Boycko, M., Shleifer, A., & Vishny, R. (1996). A theory of privatisation. The Economic Journal, 106(435), 309–319.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Buchanan, J. M., & Wagner, R. E. (1977). Democracy in deficit: The political legacy of Lord Keynes. New York: Academic Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Casas-Pardo, J., & Puchades-Navarro, M. (2001). A critical comment on Niskanen’s model. Public Choice, 107, 147–167.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cho, S. (2011). “Korea’s sovereign debt management and challenges.” Capital Market Opinion, Korea Capital Market Institute. http://www.kcmi.re.kr/common/downloadw.asp?fid=2924&fgu=002001&fty=004003. Accessed 9 August 2016.

  • Clingermayer, J. C., & B. D. Wood. (1995). Disentangling patterns of state debt financing. The American Political Science Review, 89(1), 108–120.

  • Coate, S., & Morris, S. (1995). On the form of transfers to special interests. Journal of Political Economy, 103(6), 1210–1235.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cook, F. L., Tyler, T. R., Goetz, E. G., Gordon, M. T., Protess, D., Leff, D. R., & Molotch, H. L. (1983). Media and agenda setting: effects on the public, interest group leaders, policy makers, and policy. The Public Opinion Quarterly, 47(1), 16–35.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Desai, R. M., & Olofsgard, A. (2006). The political advantage of soft budget constraints. European Journal of Political Economy, 22(2), 370–387.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Deshpande, A. (1997). The debt overhang and the disincentive to invest. Journal of Development Economics, 52(1), 169–187.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dewatripont, M., & Maskin, E. (1995). Credit and efficiency in centralized and decentralized economies. The Review of Economic Studies, 62(4), 541–555.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dixit, A., & Londregan, J. (1996). The determinants of success of special interests in redistributive politics. The Journal of Politics, 58(4), 1132–1155.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dolan, J. (2002). The budget-minimizing bureaucrat? Empirical evidence from the senior executive service. Public Administration Review, 62(1), 42–50.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Downs, A. (1967). Inside bureaucracy. Boston: Little, Brown.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Epstein, D., & O’Halloran, S. (1999). Delegating powers: A transaction cost politics approach to policy making under separate powers. Cambridge, UK: Cambridge University Press.

  • Fiorina, M. P. (1982). Legislative choice of regulatory forms: legal process or administrative process? Public Choice, 39, 33–66.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fiorina, M. P. (1986). Legislator uncertainty, legislative control, and the delegation of legislative power. Journal of Law, Economics, and Organization, 2(1), 33–51.

    Google Scholar 

  • Frederickson, G. H. (1990). Public administration and social equity. Public Administration Review, 50, 228–237.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Glomm, G., & Rioja, F. (2012). The generational effects of fiscal policy in a small open economy. Public Finance Review, 40(2), 151–176.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Goodsell, C. T. (2003). The case for bureaucracy: A public administration polemic. 4th Edition. Washington D.C.: CQ Press.

  • Greer, R. A. (2015). Overlapping local government debt and the fiscal common. Public Finance Review, 43(6), 762–785.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hahm, S. D. (1996). The political economy of deficit spending: a cross comparison of industrialized democracies, 1955–90. Environment and Planning C: Government and Policy, 14, 227–250.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hahm, S. D., Kamlet, M. S., & Mowery, D. C. (1996). The political economy of deficit spending in nine industrialized parliamentary democracies: the role of fiscal institutions. Comparative Political Studies, 29, 52–77.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hallerberg, M., Strauch, R. R., & von Hagen, J. (2009). Fiscal governance in Europe. Cambridge, UK: Cambridge University Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Hood, C. (2011). The blame game: Spin, Bureaucracy and self-preservation in government. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Horn, M. J. (1995). The political economy of public administration: Institutional choice in the public sector. New York: Cambridge University Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Huber, J. D., & Shipan, C. R. (2002). Deliberate discretion: The institutional foundations of bureaucratic autonomy. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • IMF (2011). Government finance statistics: Compilation guide for developing countries. Washington, D.C.: International Monetary Fund. https://www.imf.org/external/pubs/ft/gfs/manual/compil.pdf. Accessed 9 August 2016.

  • IMF & World Bank (2003). Developing government bond markets: A handbook. Washington, D.C.: International Monetary Fund and World Bank. http://www.imf.org/external/np/mfd/pdebt/2003/eng/am/120903.pdf. Accessed 9 August 2016.

  • Jalan, B. (1991). India’s economic crisis. Delhi: Oxford University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Johnson, C. L., Kioko, S. N., & Wang, J. Q. (2010). State government debt management: the forgotten tool in the financial Manager’s triage bag. Municipal Finance Journal, 31(1), 21–40.

    Google Scholar 

  • Jones, B. D., & Baumgartner, F. R. (2005). A model of choice for public policy. Journal of Public Administration Research and Theory, 15(3), 325–351.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kappagoda, N. (2001). Public debt management: a new priority. Bulletin on Asia-Pacific.

  • Kernell, S. (2007). Going public: New strategies of presidential leadership. Washington, D.C.: CQ Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Kioko, S. N., Marlowe, J., Matkin, D. S. T., Moody, M., Smith, D. L., & Zhao, Z. J. (2011). Why public financial management matters. Journal of Public Administration Research and Theory, 21, i113–i124.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kornai, J. (1998). The place of the soft budget constraint syndrome in economic theory. Journal of Comparative Economics, 26, 11–17.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kornai, J., Maskin, E., & Roland, G. (2003). Understanding the soft budget constraint. Journal of Economic Literature, XLI, 1095–1136.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Krugman, P. (1998). “What happened to Asia?” January 1998. http://web.mit.edu/krugman/www/DISINTER.html. Accessed 9 August 2016.

  • Light, P. C. (1999). The true size of government. Washington, D.C.: Brookings Institution Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Lin, H. M., & Bo, H. (2001). State-ownership and financial constraints on Investment of Chinese-listed firms: new evidence. European Journal of Finance, 18(6), 497–513.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Majone, G. (1997). From the positive to the regulatory state: causes and consequences of changes in the mode of governance. Journal of Public Policy, 17(2), 139–167.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Majumdar, S. K., & Sen, K. (2007). The debt wish: rent seeking by business groups and the structure of corporate borrowing in India. Public Choice, 130(1), 209–223.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Martell, C. R. (2007). Debt burdens of overlapping jurisdictions. Municipal Finance Journal, 28(2), 1–23.

    Google Scholar 

  • Maskin, E., & Xu, C. (2001). Soft budget constraint theories: from centralization to the market. The Economics of Transition, 9(1), 1–27.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • McCubbins, Noll, & Weingast (1987). Administrative procedures as instruments of political control. Journal of Law, Economics, and Organization, 3, 243–277.

    Google Scholar 

  • Moe, T. M. (1997). The positive theory of public bureaucracy. In D. C. Mueller (Ed.), Perspectives on public choice: A handbook (pp. 455–480). New York: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Moesen, W., & van Cauwenberge, P. (2000). The status of the budget constraint, federalism and the relative size of government: a bureaucracy approach. Public Choice, 104(3/4), 207–224.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mullins, D. R., & Wallin, B. A. (2004). Tax and expenditure limitations: introduction and overview. Public Budgeting & Finance, 24, 2–15.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mutz, D. C., & Soss, J. (1997). Reading public opinion: the influence of news coverage on perceptions of public sentiment. Public Opinion Quarterly, 61, 431–451.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Neck, R., & Getzner, M. (2001). Politico-economic determinants of public debt growth: a case study for Austria. Public Choice, 109, 243–268.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Niskanen, W. A. (1971). Bureaucracy and representative government. Chicago: Aldine.

    Google Scholar 

  • Nordhaus, W. D. (1975). The political business cycle. Review of Economic Studies, 42(2), 169–190.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • OECD Economic Outlook. (2014). Issue 1, May 2014. doi:10.1787/eco_outlook-v2014-1-en.

  • Park, S. (2013). What causes the death of public sector organizations? Understanding structural changes and continuities in Korean quangos. International Public Management Journal, 16(3), 413–437.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Perry, J. L. (1996). Measuring public service motivation: an assessment of construct reliability and validity. JPART, 6(1), 5–22.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Persson, T., & Svensson, L. E. O. (1989). Why a stubborn conservative would run a deficit: policy with time-inconsistent preferences. The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 104(2), 325–345.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Persson, T., & Tabellini, G. (1992). “The politics of 1992: fiscal policy and European integration.” Review of Economic Studies, 59(4), 689–701.

  • Pogue, T. F. (1970). The effect of debt limits: some new evidence. National Tax Journal, 23(1), 36–49.

    Google Scholar 

  • Pollitt, C., Talbot, C., Caulfield, J., & Smullen, A. (2004). Agencies: How government do things through semi-autonomous organizations. New York: Palgrave Macmillan.

    Google Scholar 

  • Poterba, J. M. (1995). Balanced budget rules and fiscal policy: evidence from the states. National Tax Journal, 48(3), 329–336.

    Google Scholar 

  • Qian, Y., & Roland, G. (1998). “Federalism and the soft budget constraint.” American Economic Review, 88(5), 143–162.

  • Robinson, J. A. and R. Torvik. (2006). “A political economy theory of the soft budget constraint.” Working Paper Series #12133, National Bureau of Economic Research.

  • Rodden, J. A. (2007). Hamilton’s paradox: The promise and peril of fiscal federalism. New York, NY: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Rogers, D. L., & Rogers, J. H. (2000). Political competition and state government size: do tighter elections produce looser budgets? Public Choice, 105, 1–21.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Rogoff, K. (1990). Equilibrium political budget cycles. American Economic Review, 80(1), 21–36.

    Google Scholar 

  • Roubini, N., & Sachs, J. D. (1989). Political and economic determinants of budget deficits in the industrial democracies. European Economic Review, 33, 903–938.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Schwarcz, S. L. (2002). Restructuring subnational debt. Municipal Finance Journal, 23(3), 1–42.

    Google Scholar 

  • Shleifer, A., & Vishny, R. W. (1994). Politicians and firms. The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 109(4), 995–1025.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Skelcher, C. (1998). The appointed state: Quasi-governmental organizations and democracy. Buckingham: Open University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Skilling, D., & Zeckhauser, R. J. (2002). Political competition and debt trajectories in Japan and the OECD. Japan and the World Economy, 14(2), 121–135.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Taylor, A. (1997). “‘Arm’s length but hands on’. Mapping the new governance: the department of national heritage and cultural politics in Britain.” Public Administration, 75(3), 441–466.

  • The Bank of Korea. (2014). Public sector account by the new guide. Retrieved at (in Korean).

  • Van Thiel, S. (2004). Trends in the public sector. Journal of Theoretical Politics, 16(2), 175–201.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Von Hagen, J. (2006). Political economy of fiscal institutions. In Barry & Wittman (Eds.), The oxford handbook of political economy. New York: Oxford University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Wagner, R. E. (2013). Deficits, debt, and democracy: Wrestling with tragedy on the fiscal commons. Cheltenham, UK: Edward Elgar Publishing.

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Sanghee Park.

Ethics declarations

Funding

This work was supported by the National Research Foundation of Korea Grant funded by the Korean Government (NRF-2013S1A5B5A07045822).

Appendix

Appendix

Appendix 1 Descriptive statistics
Appendix 2 Pairwise correlations among continuous variables

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Park, S. Understanding Public Sector Debt: Financial Vicious Circle under the Soft Budget Constraint. Public Organiz Rev 18, 71–92 (2018). https://doi.org/10.1007/s11115-016-0358-y

Download citation

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s11115-016-0358-y

Keywords

Navigation