Skip to main content
Log in

Addressing International Empirical Puzzles: the Liquidity of Bonds

  • Research Article
  • Published:
Open Economies Review Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

Models that assume bonds denominated in different currencies are perfect substitutes can not explain certain empirical puzzles: the exchange rate volatility puzzle is that these models can not explain the observed volatility in real and nominal exchange rates; the Backus-Smith puzzle is that these models can not explain the observed low correlation between real exchange rates and the ratio of home to foreign consumption; the Backus-Kehoe-Kydland puzzle is that these models can not explain the observed low correlation between home and foreign consumption; and finally, the uncovered interest parity puzzle is that these models can not explain the observed deviations from that parity. These long standing puzzles make the models harder to defend. In this paper, we present a symmetric two country portfolio balance model in which home and foreign bonds are imperfect substitutes for money in each country’s transactions technology; this of course makes home and foreign bonds imperfect substitutes for each other. Our calibrated model is capable of addressing the Backus-Smith puzzle and the Backus-Kehoe-Kydland puzzle. It does not fully resolve the exchange rate volatility puzzle, but it makes some headway. And finally it generates deviations from uncovered interest parity, though by some estimates these deviations are not large enough to be consistent with the data.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. Moreover, these models are not consistent with the observed behavior of portfolio managers, both private and official. For example, if home and foreign bonds are perfect substitutes, why do currency speculators dump home currency bonds in favor of foreign currency bonds during exchange rate crises. And if home and foreign bonds are perfect substitutes, why do central banks hold foreign reserves to protect against such currency crises, or more generally to intervene in foreign exchange markets?

  2. Wickens (2008) provides a brief review of this literature. Lewis (1995) provides a more extensive review of the earlier literature.

  3. See Pesenti (2008).

  4. See Kollmann (2002, 2005), and McCallum and Nelson (2000).

  5. Lewis (1995) surveys early contributions to this literature. See Alverez et al. (2009) for a more recent application.

  6. In Canzoneri et al. (2011), we developed an asymmetric model with bond liquidity to discuss the role of the dollar as a key currency. In this paper, we make the countries symmetric, since the empirical puzzles are not limited to the dollar.

  7. A note on notation: H and F subscripts will be used to denote Home and Foreign assets or products when those bonds or products are used in both countries; Home money, for example, is not held by Foreign entities, and therefore needs no subscript. Supercript *’s will denote Foreign household demands and supplies of assets or products; they will also denote Foreign interest rates, Foreign inflation rates, and Foreign velocity.

  8. In Canzoneri et al. (2008), we present a closed economy model with banks, bank deposits and bank loans. Here, due to the complexity of the two country model, we take a less structural approach.

  9. It would be straightforward to extend the model to allow both countries to use both currencies. This would not change our results in an interesting way.

  10. The CCAPM bond would be in zero net supply in equilibrium, so we suppressed it in our equations.

  11. Speculators, hedge funds and others entities that we do not model explicitly move funds internationally. We find it convenient to locate these shocks here so that they do not directly effect household decisions.

  12. The model is non-Ricardian in the sense that the timing of tax payments matter, but fiscal policies are Ricardian in the sense of the fiscal theory of the price level.

  13. The U.S. banking sector accounts for about 1.6 % of employment. We assume that roughly half of this is associated with facilitating transactions.

  14. Aspects of this are discussed further in Canzoneri et al. (2011).

  15. Table 2 should not be viewed as a “horse race” between popular models. No attempt was made to find the best calibration of the stripped down versions of the model. Rather, Table 2 is an attempt to identify how various features are important in generating the second moments in our Liquid Bonds model.

  16. There are several sources of bond supply shocks in the model. There is the shock to government demands. But temporary tax shocks and temporary changes in government purchases also affect the supply of bonds.

References

  • Alverez F, Atkeson A, Kehoe P (2009) Time varying risk, interest rates and exchange rates in general equilibrium. Rev Econ Stud 76:851–878

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Backus D, Smith G (1993) Consumption and real exchange rates in dynamic economies with non-traded goods. J Int Econ 35(3–4):297–316

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Backus D, Kehoe P, Kydland F (1995) International business cycles: theory and evidence. In: Cooley T (ed) Frontiers of business cycle research. Princeton University Press, Princeton

    Google Scholar 

  • Bansal R, Coleman WJ (1996) A monetary explanation of the equity premium, term premium, and risk-free rate puzzles J Polit Econ 6:1135–1171

    Google Scholar 

  • Benigno G, Kucuk-Tuger H (2012) Portfolio allocation and risk sharing. Can J Econ 45(2):535–565

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bhattacharjee A, Chadha J, Sun Q (2010) Productivity, preferences and UIP deviations in an open economy business cycle model. Open Econ Rev 21:365–391

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bodenstein M (2008) International asset markets and real exchange rate volatility. Rev Econ Dyn 11:688–705

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Branson WH, Henderson DW (1985) The specification and influence of asset markets. In: Jones RW, Kenen PB (eds) Handbook of international economics II, 1st edn. Elsevier, Amsterdam, pp 749–805

  • Blanchard O, Giavazzi F, Sa F (2005) International investors, the U.S. current account and the dollar. Brookings PapEcon Act 1:1–66

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Calvo G, Végh C (1995) Fighting inflation with high interest rates: the small open economy case under flexible prices. J Money Credit Bank 27(1):49–66

    Google Scholar 

  • Canzoneri M, Cumby R, Diba B (2007) Euler equations and money market interest rates: a challenge for monetary policy models. J Monet Econ 54(7):1863–1881

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Canzoneri M, Cumby R, Diba B, López-Salido D (2008) Monetary aggregates and liquidity in a Neo-Wicksellian Framework. J Money, Credit, Bank 40(8):1667–1698

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Canzoneri M, Cumby R, Diba B, López-Salido D (2011) Key currency status: an exorbitant privilege and an extraordinary risk. mimeo

  • Colacito R, Croce M (2012) International asset pricing with recursive preferences. mimeo

  • Dellas H, Tavlas G (2012) Exchange rate regimes and asset prices. mimeo

  • Devereux M, Smith G, Yetman J (2012) Consumption and real exchange rates in professional forecasts. J Int Econ 86:33–42

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dornbusch R (1976) Expectations and exchange rate dynamics. J Polit Econ 84:1161–1176

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Friedman M (1969) The optimum quantity of money and other essays. Aldine Publishing Company, Chicago

  • Friedman B, Kuttner K (1998) Indicator properties of the paper-bill spread: lessons from recent experience. Rev Econ Stat 80(1):34–44

    Google Scholar 

  • Froot KA, Frankel JA (1989) Forward discount bias: is it an exchange risk premium? Q J Econ 104(1):139–161

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Greenwood R, Vayanos D (2008) Bond supply and excess bond returns. NBER Working Paper No. 13806, February 2008

  • Gourio F, Siemer M, Verdelhan A (2011) International risk cycles. J Int Econ. doi:10.1016/j.jinteco.2011.10.001

  • Heathcote J, Perri F (2002) Financial autarky and international real business cycles. J Monet Econ 49(3):601–627

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Henderson D, Rogoff K (1982) Negative net foreign asset positions and stability in a world portfolio balance model. J Int Econ 13:85–104

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hess G, Shin K (2010) Understanding the Backus–Smith puzzle: it’s the (nominal) exchange rate, stupid. J Int Money Finance 29:169–180

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Holmstrom B, Tirole J (1998) Private and public supply of liquidity. J Polit Econ 106(1):1–40

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hoffmann M (2008) The lack of international consumption risk sharing: Can inflation differentials and trading costs help explain the puzzle? Open Econ Rev 19:183–201

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kocherlakota N, Pistaferri L (2007) Household heterogeneity and real exchange rates. Econ J 117:C1–C25

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kollmann R (2002) Monetary policy rules in the open economy: effects on welfare and business cycles. J Monet Econ 49:989–1015

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kollmann R (2005) Macroeconomic effects of nominal exchange rates regimes: new insights into the role of price dynamics. J Int Money Finance 24:275–292

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kollmann R (2012) Limited asset market participation and the consumption - real exchange rate anomaly. Can J Econ 12:566–584

    Google Scholar 

  • Kouri P (1983) Balance of payments and the foreign exchange market: a dynamic partial equilibrium model. In: Bhandari J, Putnam B (ed) Economic interdependence and flexible exchange rages. MIT Press

  • Krishnamurthy A, Vissing-Jorgensen A (2008) The aggregate demand for treasury debt, mimeo

  • Lewis KK (1995) Puzzles in international financial markets. In: Grossman GM, Rogoff K (eds) Handbook of international economics, Elsevier, Amsterdam, pp 1913–1971

  • Linnemann L, Schabert A (2010) Debt nonneutrality, policy interactions, and macroeconomic stability. Int Econ Rev 51(2):461–474

    Google Scholar 

  • Mandelman F, Rabanal P, Rubio-Ramirez J, Vilan D (2011) Investment-specific technology shocks and international business cycles: an empirical assessment. Rev Econ Dyn 14:136–155

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Masson P (1981) Dynamic stability of portfolio balance models of the exchange rate. J Int Econ 11:467–477

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • McCallum B, E Nelson (2000) Monetary policy for an open economy: an alternative framework with optimizing agents and sticky prices. Oxford Review of Economic Policy, Oxford University Press, vol. 16(4), pp 74–91, Winter

  • Patinkin D (1965) Money, interest, and prices: an integration of monetary and value theory, 2nd ed. Harper & Row, New York

  • Pesenti P (2008) The Global Economy Model (GEM): theoretical framework. NBER Working Paper No. 13795

  • Pflueger C, Viceira L (2011) An empirical decomposition of risk and liquidity in nominal and inflation indexed government bonds. NBER working paper #16892, March

  • Schmitt-Grohe S, Uribe M (2004) Optimal fiscal and monetary policy under sticky prices. Journal of Economic Theory 114:198–230

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Thoenissen C (2011) Exchange rate dynamics, asset market structure, and the role of the trade elasticity. Macroecon Dyn 15:119–143

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Wickens M (2008) Macroeconomic theory, a dynamic general equilibrium approach. Princeton University Press, Princeton and Oxford

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Matthew Canzoneri.

Additional information

We are grateful for comments from Doug Laxton, participants of a seminar at the University of North Carolina and participants of conferences at the Bank of France, the University of St. Andrews, the University of York and a referee. However, the opinions expressed here are solely those of the authors.

Appendix: Estimated Model Parameters

Appendix: Estimated Model Parameters

  1. 1.

    Fiscal Variables

    1. a.

      Government purchases

      • Regress: log(gt) on a time trend and save residuals as detrended series ldt(gt)

      • $$ \mathrm{ldt}\left( {{{\mathrm{g}}_{\mathrm{t}}}} \right)=\gamma +{\rho_{\mathrm{g}}}\,\mathrm{ldt}\left( {{{\mathrm{g}}_{{\mathrm{t}-1}}}} \right)+{\varepsilon_{\mathrm{g}\text{,}\mathrm{t}}} $$
      • Data: log(gt) = log of real government consumption and investment, NIPA Table 1.1.5, deflated to real terms using the price index for GDP

      • Sample: 1974:1–2007:4

      • $$ \begin{array}{*{20}c} {\mathrm{Estimates}:} \hfill & {{\rho_{\mathrm{g}}}=0.98} \hfill \\ {} \hfill & {\sigma \left( {{\varepsilon_{\mathrm{g}}}} \right)=0.0086} \hfill \\ \end{array} $$
    2. b.

      Taxes

      • Regress: log(xt) on a time trend and save residuals as detrended series ldt(xt)

      • $$ \mathrm{ldt}\left( {{{\mathrm{x}}_{\mathrm{t}}}} \right)=\gamma +{\rho_{\tau }}\,\mathrm{ldt}\left( {{{\mathrm{x}}_{{\mathrm{t}-1}}}} \right)+{\varepsilon_{\mathrm{x}\text{,}\mathrm{t}}} $$
      • Data: log(xt) = log of real current government receipts, NIPA Table 3.1, line 1, deflated by price index for GDP

      • Sample: 1974:1–2007:4

      • $$ \begin{array}{*{20}c} {\mathrm{Estimates}:} \hfill & {{\rho_{\mathrm{x}}}=0.90} \hfill \\ {} \hfill & {\sigma \left( {{\varepsilon_{\mathrm{x}}}} \right)=0.02} \hfill \\ \end{array} $$
  2. 2.

    Foreign Official Demand for U.S. Treasury Securities

    • Regress: log(bGH,t*) on a time trend and save residuals as detrended series, ldt(bGH,t*)

    • $$ \mathrm{ldt}\left( {\mathrm{bG}{{\mathrm{H}}_{{,\mathrm{t}*}}}} \right)=\gamma +{\rho_{\mathrm{B}}}\,\mathrm{ldt}\left( {\mathrm{bG}{{\mathrm{H}}_{{,\mathrm{t}*-1}}}} \right)+{\varepsilon_{\mathrm{B}\text{,}\mathrm{t}}} $$
    • Data: bGH,t* = foreign official holdings U.S. Treasury Securities, Flow of Funds, Table L.107, line 9 converted into real terms by dividing by the price index for personal consumption expenditures.

    • Sample period: 1974:1–2007:4

    • $$ \begin{array}{*{20}c} {\mathrm{Estimates}:} \hfill & {{\rho_{\mathrm{B}}}=0.964} \hfill \\ {} \hfill & {\sigma \left( {{\varepsilon_{\mathrm{B}}}} \right)=0.0434} \hfill \\ \end{array} $$
  3. 3.

    Elasticity of substitution in home consumption: Taken from Heathcote and Perri (2002).

    • The elasticity can also be estimated from the regression:

      $$ \log \left( {{{\mathrm{c}}_{\mathrm{F}\text{,}\mathrm{t}}}} \right)={\alpha_0}+{\alpha_1}\log \left( {{{\mathrm{c}}_{\mathrm{t}}}} \right)+{\alpha_2}\log \left( {{{\mathrm{p}}_{\mathrm{F}\text{,}\mathrm{t}}}} \right)+{\varepsilon_{\mathrm{u}}} $$
    • Data: We use two series for cF,t, real imports of consumer goods and services. Both are taken from NIPA table 4.2.5. One is the sum of lines 26, 35, 36, 42, 43 converted into real terms by deflating by price index for non-oil imports. The other is line 38, imports of nondurable consumer goods, deflated by the corresponding price index.

      log(ct) = log of real personal consumption of non-durables and services expenditures

      pF,t = price index for non-oil imports/price index for PCE or the price index for imports of nondurable consumer goods/price index for PCE.

    • Sample period: 1974:1–2007:4

    • $$ \begin{array}{*{20}c} {\mathrm{Estimates}:} \hfill & {{\alpha_1}:\mathrm{The}\;\mathrm{two}\;\mathrm{estimates}\;\mathrm{are}\;0.97\;\mathrm{an}\mathrm{d}\;1.30\;\mathrm{an}\mathrm{d}\;\mathrm{neither}\;\mathrm{differs}\;\mathrm{significantly}\;\mathrm{from}\;1.0,\;\mathrm{the}\;\mathrm{value}\;\mathrm{implied}\;\mathrm{by}\;\mathrm{equation}\;25.} \hfill \\ {} \hfill & {{\alpha_2}:\mathrm{The}\;\mathrm{two}\;\mathrm{estimates}\;\mathrm{are} - 1.03\;\mathrm{an}\mathrm{d} - 0.83,\;\mathrm{which}\;\mathrm{bracket}\;\mathrm{the}\;\mathrm{Heathcoate}-\mathrm{Perri}\;\mathrm{value}, - 0.9.} \hfill \\ {} \hfill & {{\rho_{\mathrm{u}}}:\mathrm{Both}\;\mathrm{estimates}\;\mathrm{are}\;0.89.} \hfill \\ {} \hfill & {\sigma \left( {{\varepsilon_{\mathrm{u}}}} \right)=0.033\;\mathrm{at}\;\mathrm{an}\;\mathrm{an}\mathrm{nual}\;\mathrm{rate}\;\mathrm{or}\;0.00825\;\mathrm{per}\;\mathrm{quarter}} \hfill \\ \end{array} $$
  4. 4.

    Interest Rate Rule

    $$ \log \left( {{{\mathrm{R}}_{\mathrm{t}}}/\mathrm{R}} \right)={\rho_{\mathrm{R}}}\log \left( {{{\mathrm{R}}_{{\mathrm{t}-1}}}/\mathrm{R}} \right)+\left( {1-{\rho_{\mathrm{R}}}} \right){\varphi_{\pi }}\log \left( {{\prod_{\mathrm{t}}}/} \right)+{\varepsilon_{\mathrm{R}\text{,}\mathrm{t}}}. $$
    • Parameter values (ρR = 0.8, φπ = 2.0, and σ(εR) = 0.0024).

    • Here, we just take values that are typical in the literature; the value of σ(εR) comes from Canzoneri et al. (2011). We have not included an income term because it would have made inflation too volatile to fit the data.

  5. 5.

    Interest Rate Differentials and Effective Exchange Rates

    1. a.

      Effective Exchange Rates

      • Data: Nominal and real effective exchange rates from IFS (ULC definition because of length of sample for real effective exchange rate exceeds that based on CPIs).

      • Use first difference of logs

      • Sample: 1974:1–2007:4

      • $$ \begin{array}{*{20}c} {\mathrm{Estimates}:} \hfill & {\sigma \left( {\varDelta \log \mathrm{e}} \right)=0.028} \hfill \\ {} \hfill & {\sigma \left( {\varDelta \log \mathrm{q}} \right)=0.029} \hfill \\ {} \hfill & {\mathrm{corr}\left( {\varDelta \log \mathrm{e},\varDelta \log \mathrm{q}} \right)=0.943} \hfill \\ \end{array} $$
    2. b.

      Interest rate differentials

      • Data: Money market interest rates for United States, United Kingdom, Canada, Germany, and Japan (IFS).

      • Sample: 1974:1–2007:4

      • $$ \begin{array}{*{20}c} {\mathrm{Estimates}:} \hfill & {\sigma \left( \mathrm{R} \right)=0.004} \hfill \\ {} \hfill & {\sigma \left( {\mathrm{R}-\mathrm{R}^*} \right)=.004\left( {\mathrm{average}\;\mathrm{of}\;\mathrm{the}\;\mathrm{four}} \right)} \hfill \\ \end{array} $$
    3. c.

      CCAPM rate and Spread

      The CCAPM rate (equivalently, β) is, of course, unobservable. In Canzoneri et al. (2007) we compute CCAPM rates for several specifications of preferences. We set our real CCAPM rate to 1.0 % per quarter (β = 1/1.01) and our spread at 0.4 % per quarter.

      • Data: Three-month constant maturity Treasury bill rate from 1982 on. Prior to 1983, the secondary market rate on three-month bill, converted from a discount basis to an investment basis. Inflation data are computed as quarterly percent changes in the CPI-U.

  6. 6.

    Asset ratios

    1. a.

      Treasury Securities

      • Data: BH = Private US holdings of Treasury Securities = Total outstanding less sum of central bank holdings, ROW holdings, and Government holdings.

        Source: Flow of Funds, Table L.209.

        BGH,t* = Official ROW holdings of Treasury Securities.

        Source Flow of Funds, Table L.107.

        B*F,t = Private ROW holdings of Treasury Securities.

        Source Flow of Funds, Table L.107.

        Mt = Currency held outside of banks.

        Source Flow of Funds, Table L.108

        C = Personal Consumption Expenditures. Source NIPA Table 1.1.5.

      • Sample: 1974:1–2007:4

        BH/C = bH/c = 0.8

        M/C = m/c = 0.28 (We round to 0.3)

        BGH,*/C = 0.63 (2007:4) (We round to 0.6)

        B*F,t/C = 0.30 (2007:4)

      • We use a different sample for these two ratios to take into account the recent buildup in dollar balances both by foreign central banks and by the foreign private sector.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Cite this article

Canzoneri, M., Cumby, R. & Diba, B. Addressing International Empirical Puzzles: the Liquidity of Bonds. Open Econ Rev 24, 197–215 (2013). https://doi.org/10.1007/s11079-012-9267-z

Download citation

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s11079-012-9267-z

Keyword

Navigation