Skip to main content

Advertisement

Log in

The determinants of support levels for wind energy in the European Union. An econometric study

  • Original Article
  • Published:
Mitigation and Adaptation Strategies for Global Change Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

The aim of this paper is to identify the factors that drive support levels for wind on-shore electricity in the Member States of the European Union (EU) with the help of econometric techniques. The econometric analysis is based on cross-section linear regressions with ordinary least squares. Four alternative specifications of the model have been estimated. The estimates comply with the basic hypotheses of the lineal model, i.e., absence of multicollinearity, accurate functional form, homokedasticity and normality in the distribution of errors. Thus, the estimations are unbiased, efficient and consistent. The results show that countries with higher wind energy generation costs have higher support levels. The higher support levels in countries with higher carbon intensities suggest that wind energy deployment is regarded as effective to mitigate carbon emissions. The type of support scheme also influences support levels, with feed-in tariffs leading to lower levels of support than other instruments. In addition, a general good investment climate in the country makes higher support levels less necessary, stressing the importance of lowering risks in order to reduce support levels and, thus, financial transfers from consumers to producers. Thus, providing stable regulatory frameworks should be a priority of policy-makers. The rest of variables (renewable energy resource potentials, administrative barriers, energy import dependency, interest rates, share of wind energy in total electricity generation as a proxy of lobbying pressures and electricity demand) are not statistically significant in most specifications and some of them do not have the expected sign.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. Many papers focus on the functioning of RES-E policies in certain countries and, while they show the influence of some stakeholders on policy choices, they do not focus specifically on factors influencing their adoption. See, among others, Bechberger and Reiche (2004) for Germany, Agterbosch et al. (2004), Van Sambeek and Van Thuijil (2003) and Junginger et al. (2004) for the Netherlands, Varho (2006) for Finland, Foxon et al. (2006) for United Kingdom (U.K), Menz (2005) and Bird et al. (2005) for the US and Meyer and Koefoed (2003) for Denmark.

  2. An RPS ensures that a minimum amount of RES-E is included in the portfolio of electricity resources, and does so by requiring electricity suppliers to add a specified amount or percentage of eligible renewable resources to their supply mix. In some U.S. states electricity suppliers can use renewable energy certificates (RECs) to comply with their RPS requirements (Wiser et al. 2005). In the EU, the aforementioned minimum amount of RES-E and RECs are called “quota” and tradable green certificates (TGCs), respectively.

  3. See Appendix for further details on this instrument.

  4. As the development proceeds, self-reinforcing properties cause the costs of reversing or altering previous decisions to increase, narrowing the decision-making scope (Woerdmann 2004).

  5. For a brief survey of the empirical literature on path dependence, see Greener (2005) and del Río and Labandeira (2009).

  6. For example, the European Commission has warned governments that administrative barriers are a major deterrent for RES-E investments and the renewable energy Directive (Directive 28/2009/EC) includes significant requirements for governments in this regard.

  7. As argued by Agnolucci (2008), a relevant proxy could also be the (relative) size of national wind energy associations. However, these data are not publicly available in a consistent manner across countries. In addition, negotiation power might not be related to such size. Actual deployment, which is likely to be correlated to the size of national associations, seems to be a better proxy.

  8. These authors comparatively assess the effectiveness and cost-effectiveness of support schemes in the EU. Effectiveness is defined as the ability to deliver an increase of the share of renewable electricity consumed and cost-effectiveness is defined as the comparison of the total amount of support received and the generation cost.

  9. See Mitchell et al. (2006) for the U.K. In Sweden, TGC prices fluctuated between 150 and 250 SEK in 2008 (see Swedish Energy Agency 2009).

  10. It is beyond the scope and length of this paper to provide a detailed assessment of all these instruments, however. See Del Río and Gual (2004) and Ragwitz et al. (2007) for further details.

References

  • Agnolucci P (2008) Factors influencing the likelihood of regulatory changes in renewable electricity policies. Renew Sust Energ Rev 12:141–161

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Agterbosch S, Vermeulen W, Glasbergen P (2004) Implementation of wind energy in the Netherlands: the importance of the social–institutional setting. Energy Policy 32(18):2049–2066

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bechberger M, Reiche D (2004) Renewable energy policy in Germany: pioneering and exemplary regulations. Energy Sust Dev 7(1):47–57

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bird L, Bolinger M, Gagliano T, Wiser R, Brown M, Parsons B (2005) Policies and market factors driving wind power development in the United States. Energy Policy 33:1397–1407

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Chandler J (2009) Trendy solutions: why do states adopt sustainable energy portfolio standards? Energy Policy 37(8):3274–3281

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Chang T, Huang C, Lee M (2009) Threshold effect of the economic growth rate on the renewable energy development from a change in energy price: evidence from OECD countries. Energy Policy 37:5796–5802

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • de Jager D, Klessmann C, Stricker E, Winkel T, de Visser E, Koper M, Ragwitz M, Held A, Resch G, Busch S, Panzer C, Gazzo A, Roulleau T, Gousseland P, Henriet M, Bouille A (2011) Financing Renewable Energy in the European Energy Market. Final Report. Ecofys, Utrecht

    Google Scholar 

  • Del Río P (2008) Ten years of renewable electricity policies in Spain: an analysis of successive feed-in tariff reforms. Energy Policy 36(8):2917–2929

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Del Río P, Gual MA (2004) The promotion of green electricity in Europe: present and future. Eur Environ J 14:219–234

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Del Río P, Labandeira X (2009) Barriers to the introduction of market-based instruments in climate policies: an integrated theoretical framework. Environ Econ Policy Stud 10(1):1–20

    Google Scholar 

  • Del Río P et al. (2012) Pathways for a harmonised RES-E support scheme in the EU. In: IEE project beyond2020 – Design and impact of a harmonised policy for renewable electricity in Europe. http://www.res-policy-beyond2020.eu/

  • European Commission (EC) (2008a) Energy and Transport in figures 2008. Eurostat, Brussels

    Google Scholar 

  • European Commission (EC) (2008b) The support of electricity from renewable energy sources Accompanying document to the Proposal for a Directive of the European Parliament and of the Council on the promotion of the use of energy from renewable sources {COM(2008) 19} SEC(2008) 57, Brussels

  • European Commission (EC) (2009) Energy and Transport in figures. Eurostat, Brussels

    Google Scholar 

  • European Commission (EC) (2011) Communication from the Commission to the European Parliament, the Council, the European Economic and Social Committee and the Committee of the Regions. Energy Roadmap 2050. COM(2011) 885 final, Brussels

    Google Scholar 

  • European Commission (EC) (2012) Renewable Energy: a major player in the European energy market. Communication from the Commission to the European Parliament, the Council, the European Economic and Social Committee and the Committee of the regions COM(2012) 271 final, Brussels

  • European Wind Energy Association (2010) Final Report of the WindBarriers project, Brussels

  • Foxon TJ, Gross R, Chase A, Howes J, Arnall A, Anderson D (2006) U.K. innovation systems for new and renewable energy technologies: drivers, barriers and systems failures. Energy Policy 33(16):2123–2137

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Greener I (2005) The potential of path dependence in political studies. Politics 25(1):62–72

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Huang MY, Alavalapati JRR, Carter DR, Langholtz MH (2007) Is the choice of renewable portfolio standards random? Energy Policy 35:5571–5575

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • International Energy Agency (IEA) (2011) Deploying renewables. OECD/IEA, Paris

    Google Scholar 

  • International European Agency (IEA) (2008) Deploying renewables. Principles for effective policies. OECD/IEA, Paris

    Google Scholar 

  • Jacobbson S, Lauber V (2006) The politics and policy of energy system transformation—explaining the German diffusion of renewable energy technology. Energy Policy 34:256–276

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Jenner S, Chan G, Frankenberger R, Gabel M (2012) What drives states to support renewable energy? Energy J 33(2):1–12

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Junginger M, Agterbosch S, Faaij A, Turkenburg W (2004) Renewable electricity in the Netherlands. Energy Policy 32(9):1053–1073

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lauber V, Mez L (2004) Three decades of renewable electricity policiesin Germany. Energy Environ 15(4):599–623

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Laussel D (2006) Special interest politics and endogenous lobby formation. Top Theor Econ 6(1):1–14

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lipp J (2007) Lessons for effective renewable electricity policy from Denmark, Germany and the United Kingdom. Energy Policy 35:5481–5495

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lyon TP, Yin H (2010) Why Do states adopt renewable portfolio standards? an empirical investigation. Energy J 31:133–157

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Marques A, Fuinhas J, Pires J (2010) Motivations driving renewable energy in European countries: a panel data approach. Energy Policy 38:6877–6885

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Menz FC (2005) Green electricity policies in the United States: case study. Energy Policy 33:2398–2410

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Meyer N, Koefoed A (2003) Danish energy reform: policy implications for renewables. Energy Policy 31(7):597–607

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Michaelowa A (1998) Impact of interest groups on EU climate policy. Eur Environ 8(5):152–160

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Michaelowa A (2005) The German wind energy lobby: how to promote costly technological change successfully. Eur Environ 15:192–199

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Michaels R (2007) Intermittent Currents: The Failure of Renewable Electricity Requirements. Available at: http://papers.ssrn.com/sol3/papers.cfm?abstract_id=1026318

  • Mitchell C, Connor P (2004) Renewable energy policy in the UK 1990–2003. Energy Policy 32(17):1935–1947

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mitchell C, Bauknecht D, Connor PM (2006) Effectiveness through risk reduction: a comparison of the renewable obligation in England and Wales and the feed-in system in Germany. Energy Policy 34(3):297–305

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Muller DC (1989) Public Choice II. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge

    Google Scholar 

  • Nielsen L, Jeppesen T (2003) Tradable Green Certificates in selected European countries—overview and assessment. Energy Policy 31:3–14

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • North DC (1990) Institutions, Institutional Change and Economic Performance. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Nye M, Owens S (2008) Creating the UK emission trading scheme: motives and symbolic politics. Eur Environ 18:1–15

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Oates W, Portney P (2003) The political economy of environmental policy. In: Mäler KG, Vincent JR (eds) Handbook of Environmental Economics, 1st edn. vol 1, chapter 8. Elsevier, pp 325–354

  • Olson M (1965) The Logic of Collective Action. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge

    Google Scholar 

  • Oosterhuis F (2006) Innovation dynamics induced by environmental policy. IVM Report E-07/05, Amsterdam

  • Pearce D (2006) The political economy of an energy tax: the United Kingdom’s climate change levy. Energy Econ 28:149–158

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Peters BG (2001) Institutional Theory in Political Science. Continuum, London

    Google Scholar 

  • Pierson P (2000) Increasing returns, path dependence, and the study of politics. Am Polit Sci Rev 94(2):251–267

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ragwitz M (2010) Personal communication. April 3rd 2010

  • Ragwitz M, Held A, Resch G, Faber T, Haas R, Huber C, Coenraads R, Voogt M, Reece G, Morthorst PE, Jensen SG, Konstantinaviciute I, Heyder B (2007) OPTRES—Assessment and optimisation of renewable energy support schemes in the European electricity market. Supported by the European Commission (D.G. Energy and Transport), Brussels

  • Resch G, Ragwitz M, Faber T, Panzer C, Haas R (2009) 20 % RES by 2020. An assessment of the new EU RES policy framework. Presented at the 10th IAEE European Conference, Viena, 2009

  • Schmalensee R (2011) Evaluating Policies to Increase the Generation of Electricity from Renewable Energy. Center for Energy and Environmental Policy Research, MIT Working Paper 2011–008

  • Schneider F, Volkert J (1999) No chance for incentive-oriented environmental policies in representative democracies? A Public Choice analysis. Ecol Econ 31:123–138

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Stigler GJ (1971) The theory of economic regulation. Bell J Econ Manag Sci 2(1):3–21

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Svendsen GT (1999) U.S. Interest groups prefer emission trading: a new perspective. Public Choice 101(1–2):109–128

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Svendsen GT (2000) Public Choice and Environmental Regulation. Tradable Permit Systems in the United State and CO2 Taxation in Europe. Edward Elgar, Cheltenham

    Google Scholar 

  • Swedish Energy Agency (2009) The electricity certificate system 2008. Stockholm

  • Vachon S, Menz FC (2006) The role of social, political, and economic interests in promoting state green electricity policies. Environ Sci Pol 9:652–662

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Van Sambeek EJW, Van Thuijil E (2003) The Dutch renewable electricity market in 2003. An Overview and Evaluation of Current Changes in Renewable Electricity Policy in the Netherlands, ECN Report-C—03-037, Amsterdam

  • Varho V (2006) Wind power policy options in Finland—Analysis of energy policyactors’ views. Eur Environ 16(4):198–212

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Wiser R, Porter K, Grace R (2005) Evaluating experience with renewables portfolio standards in the United States. Mitig Adapt Strateg Glob Chang 10(2):237–263

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Woerdmann E (2004) The Institutional Economics of Market-Based Climate Policy. Elsevier, Amsterdam

    Google Scholar 

  • World Economic Forum (WEF) (2006) The Global Competitiveness Report 2006–2007. Macmillan, Palgrave

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgments

Cristina Peñasco gratefully acknowledges support from the Ministry of Science and Innovation and CSIC through the JAE (Junta para la Ampliación de Estudios) predoc program.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Pablo del Río.

Appendix. RES-E policy: main components

Appendix. RES-E policy: main components

Crucial components of RES-E support policies include targets, instruments and design elements.

  1. 1.

    Deployment targets.

    According to the EU renewable energy Directive 28/2009/EC, renewable energy will have to contribute 20 % to gross energy consumption in the EU in 2020. This target includes the electricity, heat and transport sectors combined. Since the penetration of renewables in electricity is easier than in the other two sectors, its share should be higher than 20 % (35 %, according to calculations made by Resch et al. 2009), in order to achieve that target cost-effectively. Member State targets are a result of burden sharing to achieve the EU targets. Countries may adopt more stringent targets (than those set at EU level) and, thus, provide more financial support in order to achieve further CO2 emisions reductions, industrial development or reductions of energy import dependency.

  1. 2.

    Instruments.

    The new RES Directive does not establish a harmonised, EU-wide instrument to promote RES and leaves the decision on which support scheme (and support level) to apply in the hands of EU Member States. A wide array of direct support schemes for RES-E deployment is currently being applied by the Member States. Deployment support has traditionally been based on three main (primary) mechanisms, however: FITs, quota systems with TGCS and bidding/tendering systems. These have been supplemented by other complementary instruments (investment subsidies, fiscal and financial incentives and green pricing).

    FITs are subsidies per kWh generated, combined with a purchase obligation by the utilities. They are widespread in Europe, with 19 Member States currently using this instrument.

    Quotas with TGCs are certificates issued for every megawatt-hour (MWh) of RES-E, allowing generators to obtain additional revenue to the sale of electricity (i.e., two streams of revenue). Demand for TGCs originates from an obligation on electricity distributors to surrender a number of TGCs as a share of their annual consumption (quota). Otherwise, they have to pay a penalty. The TGC price depends on the interaction of supply and demand. They are currently applied in six European countries.

    Tendering/bidding systems. The government invites RES-E generators to compete for either a financial budget or RES-E generation capacity. Within each technology band, the cheapest bids per kWh are awarded contracts and receive the subsidy (i.e., bid price per kWh). A fund financed by a levy on electricity consumers covers the difference between the bid price and the market price of electricity. In the EU, tendering schemes have been applied in the U.K., Ireland, France and Denmark (for wind off-shore).

    In theory, FITs can be a relatively effective instrument, but if support is set at a high level, they can also be expensive. By setting the quota and allowing trading of TGCs, quotas with TGCs are expected to be a cost-effective instrument to achieve a pre-defined level of RES-E generation. By introducing competition between generators, bidding schemes would encourage RES-E at low costs. In practice, however, FITs have proven to be effective at relatively low costs compared to other instruments, at least for wind energy promotion (see Ragwitz et al. 2007; European Commission 2008b).Footnote 8 This is due to the lower risks for investors under FITs. They know in advance the amount of remuneration that they will receive. In contrast, uncertain and volatile TGC prices involve a risk premium which increases the costs of financing projects.Footnote 9 Furthermore, since the price of TGCs is set by the marginal costs of the last technology needed to comply with the quota, and this is usually a high-cost technology, the TGC price is relatively high for mature, low cost technologies such as on-shore wind, leading to overcompensation for these technologies. Finally, bidding schemes have proven ineffective, since the low level of support does not make investments attractive enough.Footnote 10

  1. 3.

    Design elements.

    The literature on RES-E support has stressed that the success of RES-E support schemes depends as much on their design elements as on the specific instrument chosen (IEA 2008), i.e., FITs, bidding, or quota with TGCs can work well or not depending on how they are designed. Ragwitz et al. (2007) show that several design elements can/should be included in FITs and TGCs in order to make these instruments more effective and cost-effective. Support levels are related to, both, instruments and design elements.

    The above mentioned components critically affect policy stability, which is crucial for effective and cost-effective RES-E deployment. RES-E policy is one of the main determinants of the profitability of renewable energy investments. Investments depend on keeping risks for investors at low levels. Risks may be associated to the absence of targets, changes in the instrument or key design elements.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Cite this article

del Río, P., Tarancón, M.A. & Peñasco, C. The determinants of support levels for wind energy in the European Union. An econometric study. Mitig Adapt Strateg Glob Change 19, 391–410 (2014). https://doi.org/10.1007/s11027-012-9439-6

Download citation

  • Received:

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s11027-012-9439-6

Keywords

Navigation