Skip to main content
Log in

Dominant retailers’ incentives for product quality in asymmetric distribution channels

  • Published:
Marketing Letters Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

This paper investigates the diverging incentives for product quality in a channel with two asymmetric retailers and a common supplier. When retailers differ in terms of service provision and channel power, changes in manufactured quality cause channel conflicts. In particular, our results show that if the low service retailer becomes dominant in the channel, it may induce a low level of quality that is detrimental for the other members of the channel. The low service retailer benefits from quality reduction first by improving its competitive standing against its rival retailer by lessening the importance of quality for consumer choice and second by strengthening its relative bargaining position vis-à-vis its supplier. Our results also show that consumer surplus may increase as a result of quality reduction.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1
Fig. 2
Fig. 3

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. A Consumer Reports (2002) survey of shoppers found that Wal-Mart was among the lowest in perceived quality among major retailers in the USA. See also The Mirror (October 15, 2005) for criticisms of Tesco’s quality standards.

  2. See anecdotal discussions of Wal-Mart’s influence on manufactured quality and the impact of this influence on its suppliers and rival retailers in the book of Charles Fishman (2006): “The Wal-Mart Effect”. See also The Scotsman (August 26, 2005) for concerns that Tesco’s use of foreign sourced, low-quality beef, which is labeled to appear locally sourced, adversely affects consumer’s general perceptions of British produced beef.

  3. Fishman (2006) reports the CEO of an instantly recognizable consumer products company in an interview saying, “You know they (Wal-Mart) have a tremendous impact on innovation, on the development of new products. You know they are enormously damaging in that arena.” According to his interviews with an ex-design engineer electronics manufacturer, Philips, faced with pressure from Wal-Mart, made its TV cabinets thinner and took away extra features Wal-Mart did not want (Fishman 2006). Another example is the Snapper Lawn Mowers sold in both Wal-Mart and in specialty lawn care retailers. According to an interview with its CEO, continuing to supply Wal-Mart meant gradual but irresistible corrosion of the very qualities for which Snapper was known (Fishman 2006). Business Week also reports Wal-Mart heavily influences product specifications and is criticized by suppliers that it forces down quality standards (Bianco et al. 2003).

  4. See, for example HBS Case, H-E-B Own Brands and Fortune article “The Wegmans Way” (Boyle and Kratz 2005).

  5. See, for example, http://www.consumeraffairs.com/retail/walmart.htm.

  6. See, again, HBS Case, H-E-B Own Brands and Fortune article “The Wegmans Way (Boyle and Kratz 2005).

  7. An important feature of the equilibrium in our model is that the dominant retailer pays a lower wholesale price than that charged to the weaker retailer. This feature stands in contrast to an antitrust law limiting a manufacturer’s ability to discriminate in wholesale prices to competing retailers (i.e., the Robinson-Patman Act). In practice, however, managers are known to pay special attention to avoid the appearance of offering discounts to favored retailers. Also Supreme Court decisions in the past two decades have raised the hurdle for plaintiffs to establish the existence of price discrimination that is against the Act. Therefore, the potency of the law has been significantly weakened. See discussion and evidence in Luchs et al. (2010).

  8. See, for example, www.walmartwatch.com/consumer_rights

  9. Note that our formulation of Q i  = s i  + h i q is not limited to interpretations of service that are either s i or h i . Rather, Q i permits general notions of retail service, which are combinations of s i and h i . To illustrate, suppose store lighting can make the quality of the product more salient (an h part) and can also make the purchase experience better (an s part). Then store i’s lighting is represented by the vector (s i ,h i).

  10. Notice our assumption that consumers have identical tastes for quality. In a separate analysis available from the authors we show that when there are two segments with different tastes for quality, while the dominant, low-service retailer always prefers lower quality, the marginal benefit from quality reduction may be either strengthened or moderated depending on the size of the consumer segment that values high-quality products.

  11. Influential retailers are known for insisting on price concessions from their supplier. For instance, according to Fortune Wal-Mart is famous for its hard negotiations on wholesale price (Useem et al. 2003).

  12. The assumption that retailer 2 is not able to negotiate wholesale terms reflects that retailer 1 has some degree of dominance in the channel relative to retailer 2. This is consistent with previous literature (Chen 2003) which also assumes dominant retailer has more influence on the manufacturer through negotiations, but other retailers get take-it-or leave-it offers.

  13. Note that our model does not explain the sources of retailer asymmetry in service and channel influence. These two conditions, however, are what generate differences in preferences for quality in our channel setting. By identifying these two conditions, we hope our theoretical results offer testable hypotheses for future empirical research to better understand the role of quality in an asymmetric retail channel.

  14. An interior \( \widehat{q} \) that maximizes Π * M is finite if K(q) is sufficiently convex.

  15. While manufacturers often sell the same product to all retailers, there are many instances in which this is not the case. A manufacturer’s high-quality product may be found only at high service retailers while its lower-quality product only at discounters or low service retailers. In a separate analysis, available upon request, we show that the dominant retailer’s incentive for quality reduction can exist in this case as well if the perceived quality of the high-end product at the high service retailer is adversely affected by the declining quality of the product at the low-service retailer.

  16. We assume that the disagreement payoff to retailer 1 is zero and that the manufacturer can still sell its product through the weak retailer and make a positive profit. For example, with the specification K(q) = cq 2, c sufficiently large, the manufacturer sets \( \tilde{q}=h\left(s+v\right)/\left(8 ct-{h}^2\right) \), yielding the optimal profit \( {\tilde{\varPi}}_M=c{\left(s+v\right)}^2/\left(8 ct-{h}^2\right) \).

  17. One can evaluate the impact of the manufacturer’s disagreement payoff \( {\tilde{\varPi}}_M \) on the negotiated level of quality. All else equal, an increase in \( {\tilde{\varPi}}_M \) gives the manufacturer a stronger say in negotiations over quality and leads to higher q *. \( \left(\mathrm{Formally},{q}^{*}\to \widehat{q}\;\mathrm{as}\;{\tilde{\varPi}}_M\uparrow {\varPi}_M^{*}.\right) \)

  18. Notice that the α used in w *1 and w *2 is real since 2q 2 h 2 + 2s 2 + 6s(v − 2t) + 2qh(3v + 2s − 6t) + 3(31t 2 − 4tv + v 2) > ⋅ (qh − 3t)2 + (s − 3t)2 + (v − 3t)2 > 0.

References

  • Bianco, A., W. Zellner, B. Diane, M. France, T. Lowry, N. Byrnes, S. Zegel, M. Arndt, R. Berner, A. Therese. (2003). Is Wal-Mart too powerful? Business Week (October 6), 100–110.

  • Boyle, M., & Kratz, E. F. (2005). The Wegmans way. Fortune, 151(2), 62–68.

    Google Scholar 

  • Chen, Z. (2003). Dominant retailers and the countervailing-power hypothesis. The Rand Journal of Economics, 34(4), 612–625.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Choi, C. S. (1991). Price competition in a channel structure with a common retailer. Marketing Science, 10(4), 271–296.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Consumer Reports. (2002). Where to buy lawn equipment, appliances electronics, hardware, kitchenware 67(2), 11.

  • Desai, P., Koenigsberg, O., & Purohit, D. (2004). Strategic decentralization and channel coordination. Quantitative Marketing and Economics, 2(1), 5–22.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dobson, P., & Waterson, M. (1997). Countervailing power and consumer prices. The Economic Journal, 107(441), 418–430.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dobson, P., M. Waterson. (1999). Retailer power: recent developments and policy implications. Economic Policy, April, pp. 135–156

  • Dukes, A. T., & Geylani, K. S. (2009). Strategic assortment reduction by a dominant retailer. Marketing Science, 28(2), 309–319.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dukes, A., Gal-Or, E., & Srinivasan, K. (2006). Channel bargaining with retailer asymmetry. Journal of Marketing Research, 43(1), 84–97.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fishman, C. (2006). The Wal-Mart effect. New York: Penguin Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Gerstner, E., & Hess, J. D. (1995). Pull promotions and channel coordination. Marketing Science, 14(1), 43–60.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Geylani, T., Dukes, A., & Srinivasan, K. (2007). Strategic manufacturer response to a dominant retailer. Marketing Science, 26(2), 164–178.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hotelling, H. (1929). Stability in competition. The Economic Journal, 39(153), 41–57.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ingene, C., & Parry, M. (1995). Channel coordination when retailers compete. Marketing Science, 14(4), 360–377.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Jerath, K., Hoch, S., & Zhang, Z. J. (2008). The pursuit of retailing dominance: market dominance, channel dominance, or both? Working Paper. Pittsburgh, PA: Tepper School of Business, Carnegie Mellon University.

    Google Scholar 

  • Jeuland, A., & Shugan, S. (1983). Managing channel profits. Marketing Science, 2(3), 239–272.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lal, R. (1990). Improving channel coordination through franchising. Marketing Science, 9(4), 299–318.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Luchs, R., Geylani, T., Dukes, A., & Srinivasan, K. (2010). The end of the Robinson–Patman Act? Evidence from legal case data. Management Science, 56(12), 2123–2133.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Luo, L., Kannan, P., & Ratchford, B. (2007). New product development under channel acceptance. Marketing Science, 26(2), 149–163.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • McGuire, T., & Staelin, R. (1983). An industry equilibrium analysis of downstream vertical integration. Marketing Science, 2(2), 161–190.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Moorthy, S. (1987). Managing channel profits: comment. Marketing Science, 6(4), 375–379.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Purohit, D. (1997). Dual distribution channels: competition between rental agencies and dealers. Marketing Science, 16(3), 228–245.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Raju, J. S., & Zhang, Z. J. (2005). Channel coordination in the presence of a dominant retailer. Marketing Science, 24(2), 254–262.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Trivedi, M. (1998). Distribution channels: an extension of exclusive retailership. Management Science, 44(7), 896–909.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Useem, J., Schlosser, J., & Kim, H. (2003). One nation under Wal-Mart. Fortune, 147(4), 65–78.

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Yunchuan Liu.

Appendix

Appendix

Proof of proposition 1

Pricing reactions in the second stage, derived from the first order conditions of the maximization in (3), are given by:

$$ {p}_1\left({w}_1,{w}_2\right)=\frac{1}{3}\left(3t+2{w}_1+{w}_2-s- qh\right) $$
(A1)
$$ {p}_2\left({w}_1,{w}_2\right)=\frac{1}{3}\left(3t+{w}_1+2{w}_2+s+ qh\right) $$

The second order conditions for the maximizations of (3) are satisfied because

$$ \frac{\partial^2{\varPi}_i}{\partial {\left({p}_i\right)}^2}=-\frac{1}{t}<0,i=1,2 $$

The first-order condition for the maximization of (5) is:

$$ qh+s+3t+2\left({w}_1-{w}_2\right)=0 $$
(A2)

In the case of a disagreement between the manufacturer and retailer 1, retailer 2 maximizes its profits Π − 12  = D − 12 p − 12 . This maximization implies

$$ {p}_2^{-1}=\frac{v+s+ hq+{w}_2}{2} $$
(A3)

Using (A3) in (12) implies the following first-order condition

$$ \left(3t- qh-s+{w}_2-{w}_1\right)\left\{\begin{array}{l}{\left(s+q-3t\right)}^2+4{w}_1^2\\ {}+{w}_1\left[5\left(s+ qh-3t\right)-8{w}_2\right]+{w}_2\left(s+ qh+3t+6v\right)-2{w}_2^2\end{array}\right\}=0 $$
(A4)

Solving (A2) and (A4) simultaneously we get the wholesale prices given in the proposition.Footnote 18 As mentioned above, second order condition for the maximization of (5) is satisfied since: \( \frac{\partial^2{\varPi}_M}{\partial {\left({w}_2\right)}^2}=-\frac{1}{3t}<0. \) Denoting the Nash product in (12) by F, we also verify the second order condition for the maximization at (w *1 ,w *2 ): \( \frac{\partial^2F}{\partial {\left({w}_1\right)}^2}=-\frac{{\left(s+ qh\right)}^2+\left(243t-36s-36 qh\right)t}{216{t}^2}<0 \). Equilibrium retail prices are found by using (w *1 ,w *2 ) in (A1) and the optimal profits by using (p *1 ,p *2 ) and (w *1 ,w *2 ) in (3) and (5).

Note that the market is covered when the negotiations are successful since under Assumption 1: \( {U}_1\left({D}_1\right)=\frac{1}{2}\left(2v+s+ qh-{p}_2-{p}_1-t\right)=\frac{1}{12}\left(6v+3s+3 qh+3t-2\sqrt{3}\alpha \right)>0 \). And retailer 2 does not sell to the entire market in the case of a breakdown in negotiations since for the consumer at x = 0 under Assumption1: \( {U}_2^{-1}(0)=v+s+ qh-{p}_2^{-1}-t\cdot =\frac{1}{12}\left(3v+3s+3 qh-6t-\sqrt{3}\alpha \right)<0 \). This justifies our demand specifications in (2) and (11). Q.E.D.

Proof of proposition 2

Using the equilibrium values in Proposition 1: \( \frac{\partial {\varPi}_1^{*}}{\partial q}=-\frac{h\left(9t-s- qh\right)}{36t}<0, \) \( \frac{\partial {\varPi}_2^{*}}{\partial q}=\frac{h\left(9t+s+ qh\right)}{36t}>0\;\mathrm{and}\;\frac{\partial \left[{\varPi}_M^{*}+K(q)\right]}{\partial q}=\frac{h}{12 t\alpha}\left[4\sqrt{3}t\left(s+ qh-3t\right)+6\sqrt{3} tv+\alpha \left(s+ qh+3t\right)\right]>0 \) for v > 2t which is implied by the threshold given for v in Assumption 1. Q.E.D.

Proof of proposition 3

Let q* be a maximizer of \( G(q)\equiv {\varPi}_1^{*}\left({\varPi}_M^{*}-{\tilde{\varPi}}_M\right) \), which uniquely exists for K(q) sufficiently convex. Then q* must satisfy the first order condition of this maximization:

$$ {\left.\frac{\partial G}{\partial q}\right|}_{q={q}^{*}}={\left.\frac{\partial {\varPi}_1^{*}}{\partial q}\right|}_{q={q}^{*}}\left[{\varPi}_M^{*}\left({q}^{*}\right)-{\tilde{\varPi}}_M\right]+{\varPi}_1^{*}\left({q}^{*}\right){\left.\frac{\partial \left({\varPi}_M^{*}-{\tilde{\varPi}}_M\right)}{\partial q}\right|}_{q={q}^{*}}=0. $$

By Proposition 2 and the fact that \( {\varPi}_M^{*}\left({q}^{*}\right)-{\tilde{\varPi}}_M>0, \) the first additive term above is negative. Therefore, the second term is positive. Also observe that

$$ \operatorname{sgn}\left\{{\left.\frac{\partial {\varPi}_M^{*}}{\partial q}\right|}_{q={q}^{*}}\right\}=\operatorname{sgn}\left\{{\varPi}_1^{*}\left({q}^{*}\right){\left.\frac{\partial \left({\varPi}_M^{*}-{\tilde{\varPi}}_M\right)}{\partial q}\right|}_{q={q}^{*}}\right\} $$

since Π *1 (q*) > 0 and \( {\tilde{\varPi}}_M \) does not depend on q. Hence, Π * M (q) is increasing in q at q *. Finally, since ∂ 2 Π * M /∂ q 2 < 0 for K(q) sufficiently convex, we can conclude that M’s optimal quality \( \widehat{q} \) must exceed the negotiated quality q *. Q.E.D.

Proof of proposition 4

Computing the consumer surplus in equilibrium as defined in (13) gives the expression: \( C{S}^{*}=\frac{72 tv+{s}^2+{q}^2{h}^2+30t+81{t}^2+2 qh\left(s+15t\right)-24\sqrt{3} t\alpha}{144t}\operatorname{} \) Thus,

$$ \frac{\partial C{S}^{*}}{\partial q}= hz,\frac{\partial C{S}^{*}}{\partial s}=z,\mathrm{and}\kern0.24em \frac{\partial C{S}^{*}}{\partial h}= qz, $$
(A8)

where \( z=\left[-24\sqrt{3}t\left(s+ qh-3t\right)-36\sqrt{3} tv+\alpha \left( qh+s+15t\right)\right]/\left(72 t\alpha \right)\operatorname{} \)

Note that \( \frac{\partial^2C{S}^{*}}{\partial v\partial q}= hy,\frac{\partial^2C{S}^{*}}{\partial v\partial s}=y, \) and \( \frac{\partial^2C{S}^{*}}{\partial v\partial h}= qy \) with \( y=\left[\sqrt{3}\left(2 st-81{t}^2+ qh\left(2t-v\right)\right)- sv\right]/\left(2{\alpha}^3\right) \) and that y < 0 if v > 2 t which holds under Assumption 1. Therefore, the partial derivatives in (A8) are monotonic and decreasing in v. Solving z = 0 for v, we get \( \begin{array}{c}\overline{v}=\frac{1}{3\left(1071{t}^2-{q}^2{h}^2-{s}^2-30 st-2 qh\left(s+15t\right)\right)}\left\{\sqrt{3}\right[{\left( qh+s+15t\right)}^2\Big({q}^4{h}^4+{s}^4+30{s}^3t-720{s}^2{t}^2\\ {}-2430s{t}^3+86751{t}^4+2{q}^3{h}^3\left(2s+15t\right)+6{q}^2{h}^2\left({s}^2+15 st-120{t}^2\right)+2 qh\left(2{s}^3+45{s}^2t-720s{t}^2-1215{t}^3\right)\Big){\Big]}^{0.5}\\ {}+\left[3{q}^3{h}^3+3{s}^3+84{s}^2t-2097s{t}^2+6426{t}^3+3{q}^2{h}^2\left(3s+28t\right)+3 qh\right(3{s}^2+56 st-699{t}^2\left)\right]\Big\}\end{array} \)

Hence, the expressed signs of the derivatives in the proposition depend on the relative order of v and \( \overline{v} \). To see that \( \overline{v} \) is real observe that the term within the square root in \( \overline{v} \) \( \begin{array}{c}m\equiv {\left( qh+s+15t\right)}^2\Big[{q}^4{h}^4+{s}^4+30{s}^3t-720{s}^2{t}^2\\ {}-2430s{t}^3+86751{t}^4+2{q}^3{h}^3\left(2s+15t\right)+6{q}^2{h}^2\left({s}^2+15 st-120{t}^2\right)+2 qh\left(2{s}^3+45{s}^2t-720s{t}^2-1215{t}^3\right)\Big]\end{array} \) is positive when t = 0 (i.e., m t = 0 = (qh + s)5 > 0). Notice also that \( \frac{\partial m}{\partial t}\left|{}_{t=0}=60{\left( qh+s\right)}^2>0\right. \) and ∂ (∂ m/∂ t)/∂ t = 36(28917t 2 − 40(qh + s)2 − 405t(s + qh)) > 0 under Assumption 1. Therefore, ∂ m/∂ t > 0 for all t ≥ 0. This implies that m > 0 and ensures that \( \overline{v}\in \mathfrak{R} \). Furthermore, if s + hq < 3t then \( \overline{v}>0 \). Q.E.D.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Cite this article

Dukes, A., Geylani, T. & Liu, Y. Dominant retailers’ incentives for product quality in asymmetric distribution channels. Mark Lett 25, 93–107 (2014). https://doi.org/10.1007/s11002-013-9245-2

Download citation

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s11002-013-9245-2

Keywords

Navigation