Skip to main content
Log in

Measuring Efficiency in Imperfectly Competitive Markets: An Example of Rational Inefficiency

  • Published:
Journal of Optimization Theory and Applications Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

The standard assumption in the efficiency literature, that firms attempt to produce on the production frontier, may not hold in markets that are not perfectly competitive, where the production decisions of all firms will determine the market price, i.e., an increase in a firm’s output level leads to a lower market clearing price and potentially lower profits. This paper models both the production possibility set and the inverse demand function, and identifies a Nash equilibrium and improvement targets which may not be on the production frontier when some inputs or outputs are fixed. This behavior is referred to as rational inefficiency because the firm reduces its productivity levels in order to increase profits. For a general short-run multiple input/output production process, which allows a firm to adjust its output levels and variable input levels, the existence and the uniqueness of the Nash equilibrium is proven. The estimation of a production frontier extends standard market analysis by allowing benchmark performance to be identified. On-line supplementary materials include all proofs and two additional results; when changes in quantity have a significant influence on price and all input and outputs are adjustable, we observe more benchmark production plans on the increasing returns to scale portion of the frontier. Additionally, a direction for improvement toward the economic efficient production plan is estimated, thus providing a solution to the direction selection issue in a directional distance analysis.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1
Fig. 2
Fig. 3

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. A production function is commonly defined as the maximum set of output(s) that can be produced with a given set of inputs. Thus, we will use the terms production function and production frontier interchangeable as is commonly done in the productivity and efficiency literature [2].

  2. A firm is said to be rationally inefficient when they intentionally lower productivity levels to maximize revenues or profits, or alternatively, minimizes costs.

  3. Firms will either expand their outputs, contract their inputs, or both, depending on the cost/price structure of inputs/outputs and adjustment costs associated with changing input levels. For now, we will assume input adjustment costs are very large and consider only output adjustment consistent with an output-oriented efficiency analysis in the efficiency literature [15]. This assumption is relaxed in Sect. 4.

    Fig. 1
    figure 1

    Economic efficiency and production frontier

    Fig. 2
    figure 2

    Change in supply and equilibrium price

  4. This is consistent with an output-oriented efficiency analysis in the productivity literature [15].

  5. This is consistent with a profit maximization model, given fixed input prices and levels.

  6. The output level \(\bar{y}_r\) will be chosen by all firms. Clearly, the firms using input levels less than \(X_r\) will only be able to produce the output level defined by the production frontier. And firms using more than \(X_\mathrm{r}\) input cannot adjust their input levels by assumption, so they will produce \(\bar{y}_r\) with more than \(X_\mathrm{r}\) input.

  7. Note that all output variables need to be normalized in data pre-processing to eliminate unit dependence.

  8. For a discussion of the relationship among these properties see the weak, moderate, and strong dominance section in the on-line electronic supplementary material.

  9. Note the exchange of \(q\) and \(h\).

  10. This result is illustrated in Table 2, Case 2, DC 5.

  11. The intuition for case 6 can be built using the single-output case considering only product \(q_2 \). The related problem of negative demand in demand function is modified using the price mappings (described in [27, 29, 30]).

  12. In a special case, in which input markets are perfectly competitive \(\beta _{jl} =0\), the inverse supply function will be constant and the cost function becomes a linear function. This does not affect the optimality condition, i.e., the profit function is still a strictly concave function if the revenue function is strictly concave.

  13. Weakly efficient frontier is defined as the portion of the input (output) isoquant along which one of the inputs (outputs) can be reduced (expanded) while holding all other netputs constant and remaining on the isoquant; see Färe and Lovell [34] for more details.

  14. Bougnol and Dulá [35] propose a procedure to identify anchor points and show that, if a point is an anchor point, then increasing an input or decreasing an output generates a new point on the free-disposability portion of the production possibility set.

References

  1. Cherchyea, L., Kuosmanen, T., Post, T.: Non-parametric production analysis in non-competitive environments. Int. J. Prod. Econ. 80, 279–294 (2002)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  2. Fried, H.O., Lovell, C.A.K., Schmidt, S.S.: The Measurement of Productive Efficiency and Productivity Growth. Oxford University Press, Oxford (2008)

    Book  Google Scholar 

  3. Farrell, M.J.: The measurement of productive efficiency. J. R. Stat. Soc., Ser. A, Gen. 120, 253–281 (1957)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  4. Leibenstein, H.: Allocative efficiency versus ’X-efficiency’. Am. Econ. Rev. 56, 392–415 (1966)

    Google Scholar 

  5. Leibenstein, H., Maital, S.: The organizational foundation of X-inefficiency: a game theoretic interpretation of Argyris’ model of organizational learning. J. Econ. Behav. Organ. 23, 251–268 (1994)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  6. Stigler, G.: The Xistence of X-efficiency. Am. Econ. Rev. 66, 213–216 (1976)

    Google Scholar 

  7. Foster, L., Haltiwanger, J., Syverson, C.: Reallocation, firm turnover, and efficiency: selection on productivity or profitability? Am. Econ. Rev. 98(1), 394–425 (2008)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  8. Bloom, N., van Reenen, J.: Measuring and explaining management practices across firms and countries. Q. J. Econ. 122(4), 1351–1408 (2007)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  9. Bogetoft, P., Hougaard, J.L.: Rational inefficiencies. J. Prod. Anal. 20, 243–271 (2003)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  10. Cournot, A.A.: Recherches sur les Principes Mathématiques de la Théorie des Richesses. Librairie des sciences politiques et sociales, M. Rivière et cie, Paris (1838)

    Google Scholar 

  11. Nash, J.F.: Equilibrium points in n-person games. Proc. Natl. Acad. Sci. 36, 48–49 (1950)

    Article  MATH  MathSciNet  Google Scholar 

  12. Nash, J.F.: Noncooperative games. Ann. Math. 45, 286–295 (1951)

    Article  MathSciNet  Google Scholar 

  13. Rosen, J.B.: Existence and uniqueness of equilibrium points for concave n-person games. Econometrica 33(3), 520–534 (1965)

    Article  MATH  MathSciNet  Google Scholar 

  14. Arrow, K.J., Debreu, G.: Existence of an equilibrium for a competitive economy. Econometrica 22(3), 265–290 (1954)

    Article  MATH  MathSciNet  Google Scholar 

  15. Färe, R., Primont, D.: Multi-Output Production and Duality: Theory and Applications. Kluwer Academic Publishers, Boston (1995)

    Book  Google Scholar 

  16. Murphy, F.H., Sherali, H.D., Soyster, A.L.: A mathematical programming approach for determining oligopolistic market equilibrium. Math. Program. 24, 92–106 (1982)

    Article  MATH  MathSciNet  Google Scholar 

  17. Harker, P.T.: A variational inequality approach for the determination of oligopolistic market equilibrium. Math. Program. 30, 105–111 (1984)

    Article  MATH  MathSciNet  Google Scholar 

  18. Bonanno, G.: General equilibrium theory with imperfect competition. J. Econ. Surv. 4(4), 297–328 (1990)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  19. Boles, J.N.: Efficiency squared-efficient computation of efficiency indexes. In Western Farm Economic Association, Proceedings 1966, Pullman, Washington, pp. 137–142 (1967)

  20. Afriat, S.N.: Efficiency estimation of production functions. Int. Econ. Rev. 13(3), 568–598 (1972)

    Article  MATH  MathSciNet  Google Scholar 

  21. Charnes, A., Cooper, W.W., Rhodes, E.: Measuring the efficiency of decision making units. Eur. J. Oper. Res. 2, 429–444 (1978)

    Article  MATH  MathSciNet  Google Scholar 

  22. Lee, C.-Y., Johnson, A.L.: Proactive data envelopment analysis: effective production and capacity expansion in stochastic environments. Eur. J. Oper. Res. 232(3), 537–548 (2014)

    Article  MathSciNet  Google Scholar 

  23. Facchinei, F., Pang, J.S.: Finite-dimensional Variational Inequalities and Complementarity Problems. Springer, New York (2003)

    Google Scholar 

  24. Gabay, D. Moulin, H.: On the uniqueness and stability of Nash-equilibria in noncooperative games. In Applied Stochastic Control in Economics and Management Science, A. Bensoussan, P. Kleindorfer, C. S. Tapiero, editors, North-Holland, Amsterdam, The Netherlands, pp. 271–294 (1980)

  25. Karamardian, S.: Generalized complementarity problem. J. Optim. Theory Appl. 8, 161–168 (1971)

    Article  MATH  MathSciNet  Google Scholar 

  26. Dyson, G., Thanassoulis, E., Boussofiane, A.: Data envelopment analysis. In: Hendry, L.C., Eglese, R.W. (eds.) Tutorial Papers in Operational Research. Operational Research Society, Birmingham (1990)

    Google Scholar 

  27. Farahat, A., Perakis, G.: A nonnegative extension of the affine demand function and equilibrium analysis for multiproduct price competition. Oper. Res. Lett. 38, 280–286 (2010)

    Article  MATH  MathSciNet  Google Scholar 

  28. Bernstein, F., Federgruen, A.: Comparative statics, strategic complements and substitutes in oligopolies. J. Math. Econ. 40, 713–746 (2004)

    Article  MATH  MathSciNet  Google Scholar 

  29. Shubik, M., Levitan, R.: Market Structure and Behavior. Harvard University Press, Cambridge (1980)

    Book  Google Scholar 

  30. Soon, W.M., Zhao, G.Y., Zhang, J.P.: Complementarity demand functions and pricing models for multi-product markets. Eur. J. Appl. Math. 20(5), 399–430 (2009)

    Article  MATH  MathSciNet  Google Scholar 

  31. Marshall, A.: Principles of Economics, 8th edn. Macmillan and Co., Ltd., London (1920)

    Google Scholar 

  32. Stigler, G.: Production and distribution in the short run. J. Political Econ. 47(3), 305–327 (1939)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  33. Färe, R., Grosskopf, S., Lovell, C.A.K.: Production Frontiers. Cambridge University Press, New York (1994)

    Google Scholar 

  34. Färe, R., Lovell, C.A.K.: Measuring the technical efficiency of production. J. Econ. Theory 19, 150–162 (1978)

    Article  MATH  Google Scholar 

  35. Bougnol, M.-L., Dulá, J.H.: Anchor points in DEA. Eur. J. Oper. Res. 192(2), 668–676 (2009)

    Article  MATH  Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgments

The authors thank Steven Puller and Robin C. Sickles for providing constructive suggestions and helpful discussion. Any errors are the responsibilities of the authors. This research was partially funded by National Science Council, Taiwan (NSC101-2218-E-006-023), and Research Center for Energy Technology and Strategy at National Cheng Kung University, Taiwan.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Andrew L. Johnson.

Additional information

Communicated by Kaoru Tone.

Electronic supplementary material

Below is the link to the electronic supplementary material.

Supplementary material 1 (docx 139 KB)

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Cite this article

Lee, C.Y., Johnson, A.L. Measuring Efficiency in Imperfectly Competitive Markets: An Example of Rational Inefficiency. J Optim Theory Appl 164, 702–722 (2015). https://doi.org/10.1007/s10957-014-0557-z

Download citation

  • Received:

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s10957-014-0557-z

Keywords

Mathematics Subject Classification

Navigation