Skip to main content

Advertisement

Log in

Local government allocation of cultural services

  • Original Article
  • Published:
Journal of Cultural Economics Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

In the present paper, we analyse the allocation process for cultural services in Norwegian municipalities. The cultural sector at this administrative level is decomposed into the following eight subcategories: children’s and youth activities, libraries, cinemas, museums, arts dissemination, cultural heritage, cultural schools, and other cultural services. By means of budget shares for these eight cultural services and a residual sector consisting of all other municipal services, we estimate a system of demand relations which are interdependently linked to each other by a budget restriction. Our analyses are based on data from 409 out of 429 Norwegian municipalities during the period 2002–2010. In the empirical analyses, we mainly focus on the effects of income variation for the cultural services. We estimate effects of free income, matching grants to each sector, and user fees and other sector-specific income for each sector. We also estimate crowding-out effects for the cultural sectors of demographic variables indicating higher demand for services such as education, childcare, and health services. Our results confirm previous results. There are interesting differences within the group of cultural services, and these are partly related to different levels of national standardisation and regulation among the cultural services.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. Cf. Silberberg (1990) Sect. 10.6 for an overview of relations among various elasticities following from a standard utility maximisation framework.

  2. NOK 1000 = EURO 123.7 in 2010.

  3. If this were not the case, the restrictions would be non-binding and therefore pointless.

  4. We do not test all of the five hypotheses on municipality interdependency as proposed and tested in Werck et al. (2008). We only test the free-rider or spillover hypothesis, and avoid use of the more complicated econometric models, for instance spatial autocorrelation models.

  5. Figures for national-level cultural spending are taken from the Norwegian Ministry of Culture (2013). Gross and net operating expenditures on culture in counties and municipalities are from Statistics Norway’s database for counties and municipalities (Kostra). The gross operating expenditures in the text include intergovernmental transfers, such that some expenditures are counted twice. If we subtract all grants from higher levels of governments, as well as grants from other municipalities and user fees and other payments from the private sector, net operating expenditures on culture in 2012 (without sports) fall to about NOK 5 billion in the municipalities and to about NOK 1.4 billion in the counties.

  6. The national and county levels have the main responsibility for cultural heritage, and thus municipal expenditures on cultural heritage are very limited in the majority of the municipalities.

  7. Data from Statistics Norway on the number of designated protected buildings show that there were fewer than four protected buildings in 124 out of 428 municipalities in 2013. These figures indicate that cultural heritage is a fairly limited issue in some of the municipalities.

  8. The cost index for municipalities is increasing considerably faster than the consumer price index, since the main cost component for the municipalities is wage cost and scope for productivity improvements in municipal services is fairly limited, cf. Baumol (1967).

  9. The total number of counties in Norway is 19 including Oslo, but Oslo has been omitted from the dataset due to some missing variables, thereby reducing the number of counties to 18.

  10. For simplicity, we have assumed that the local governments cannot make any intertemporal adjustments. Thus, savings are not allowed within this model.

  11. To avoid notational clutter, we include the variables I, G, UF, Z and τ in the vector x in the rest of this section. The corresponding vector of parameters for equation i is denoted β i .

  12. For a recent survey of political determinants of public spending on culture, see Sect. 2 in Nogare and Galizzi (2011).

  13. Note that population size is included as a separate variable, cf. results in Sect. 6.5. Thus, the effects for the neighbouring municipalities and central places discussed here are additional effects from belonging to these groups when population size is already controlled for.

  14. The action plan (the Cultural Initiative) includes both monetary and non-monetary measures (e.g. the Culture Act of 2007). Since we are likely to capture the effects of the monetary measures via the income types in the estimated demand system, these results indicate that there are effects from the non-monetary measures as well.

References

  • Aaberge, R., & Langørgen, A. (2003). Fiscal and spending behavior of local governments: Identification of price effects when prices are not observed. Public Choice, 117(1–2), 125–161.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bahl, R., Johnson, M., & Wasylenko, M. (1980). A public employment model. In R. Bahl, J. Burkhead, & B. Jump, Jr. (Eds.), Public employment and state and local government finance (chapter 4). Cambridge, MA.

  • Baumol, W. J. (1967). Macroeconomics of unbalanced growth: The anatomy of urban crisis. American Economic Review, 57(3), 415–426.

    Google Scholar 

  • Benito, B., Bastida, F., & Vicente, C. (2013). Municipal elections and cultural expenditure. Journal of Cultural Economics, 37(1), 3–32.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Borge, L.-E., & Rattsø, J. (1995). Demographic shift, relative costs and the allocation of local public consumption in Norway. Regional Science and Urban Economics, 25(6), 705–726.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Borge, L.-E., Rattsø, J., & Sørensen, R. (1995). Local government service production: The politics of allocative sluggishness. Public Choice, 82(1–2), 135–157.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dessoy, A. (1998). Sociaal-economische typologie van de gemeenten [Social-economic typology of the municipalities]. Tijdschrift van het Gemeentekrediet, 205(3), 17–43.

    Google Scholar 

  • Ehrenberg, R. G. (1973). The demand for state and local government employees. American Economic Review, 63(3), 366–379.

    Google Scholar 

  • Feder, T., & Katz-Gerro, T. (2012). Who benefits from public funding of the performing arts? Comparing the art provision and the hegemony-distinction approaches. Poetics, 40, 359–381.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Getzner, M. (2002). Determinants of public cultural expenditures: An exploratory time series analysis for Austria. Journal of Cultural Economics, 26(4), 287–306.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Getzner, M. (2004). Exploring voter preferences in cultural policy: A case study for Austria. Empirica, 31(1), 27–42.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Håkonsen, L. & Løyland, K. (2011). Er øremerking treffsikkert? Om hvordan kommunene påvirkes av øremerkede tilskudd og andre former for statlig styring. [Is earmarking effective? How local governments are influenced by central government grants and other forms of state control.]. Report No. 290/2011, Telemark Research Institute.

  • Hammond, C. J. (1999). The technology of library service provision: A cost function analysis of public library systems in the United Kingdom. Information Economics and Policy, 11(3), 271–295.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hines, J. R., & Thaler, R. H. (1995). Anomalies. The flypaper effect. Journal of Economic Perspectives, 9(4), 217–226.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Inman, R. P. (1979). The fiscal performance of local governments: An interpretative review. In P. Mieszkowski & M. Straszheim (Eds.), Current issues in urban economics (pp. 270–321). Baltimore: John Hopkins University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Lewis, G. B., & Rushton, M. (2007). Understanding state spending on the arts, 1976–99. State and Government Review, 39(2), 107–114.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lundberg, J. (2006). Spatial interaction model of spillovers from locally provided public services. Regional Studies, 40(6), 631–644.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mangset, P. (1995). Risks and benefits of decentralisation: The development of local cultural administration in Norway. Cultural Policy, 2(1), 67–88.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • McDonald, J., & Moffit, R. (1980). The uses of Tobit analysis. Review of Economics and Statistics, 62(2), 318–321.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Nogare, C. D., & Galizzi, M. M. (2011). The political economy of cultural spending: evidence from Italian cities. Journal of Cultural Economics, 35(3), 203–231.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Norwegian Ministry of Culture. (2013). Kulturutredningen 2014 (Cultural policy 2014). NOU 2013:4. Oslo, the Ministry of Culture.

  • Oates, W. E. (1999). An essay on Fiscal federalism. Journal of Economic Literature, 37, 1120–1149.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Oates, W. E. (2005). Towards a second-generation theory of fiscal federalism. International Tax and Public Finance, 12, 349–373.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Potrafke, N. (2010). Ideology and cultural policy. Working Paper, Thurgau Institute of Economics, University of Konstanz.

  • Rattsø, J. (1989). Local government allocation of labour and the grant system: An applied model analysis of local government behaviour in Norway. Environment and Planning C: Government and Policy, 7(3), 273–284.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ringstad, V., & Løyland, K. (2011). Performing arts and cinema demand: Some evidence of Linder’s disease. Applied Economics Quarterly, 57(4), 255–284.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Rubinfeld, D. (1987). The economics of the local public sector. In A. Auerbach & M. Feldstein (Eds.), Handbook of public economics (Vol. II, pp. 571–645). Amsterdam: Elsevier.

    Google Scholar 

  • Schulze, G. G., & Rose, A. (1998). Public orchestra funding in Germany—An empirical investigation. Journal of Cultural Economics, 22, 227–247.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Schulze, G. G., & Ursprung, H. W. (2000). La donna e mobile—or is she? Voter preferences and public support for the performing arts. Public Choice, 102(1–2), 129–147.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Seaman, B. A. (2006). Empirical studies of demand for the performing arts. In V. Ginsburgh & D. Throsby (Eds.), Handbook of the economics of art and culture (Vol. 1, Chapter 14). Amsterdam; Elsevier.

  • Silberberg, E. (1990). The structure of economics: A mathematical analysis (2nd ed.). Singapore: McGraw-Hill Int. editions.

    Google Scholar 

  • Stastna, L. (2009). Spatial interdependence of local public expenditures: Selected evidence from the Czech Republic. Czech Economic Review, 3(1), 7–25.

    Google Scholar 

  • Tranvik, T., & Fimreite, A. L. (2006). Reform failure: The process of devolution and centralization in Norway. Local government studies, 32(1), 89–107.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Werck, K., Heyndels, B., & Geys, B. (2008). The impact of ‘central places’ on spatial spending patterns: Evidence from Flemish local government cultural expenditures. Journal of Cultural Economics, 32(1), 35–58.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Wert, M. (2006). The political economy of the subsidisation of cultural institutions: Empirical evidence from Germany. Working paper no. 2, Whitman College Economics Department.

  • Wooldridge, J. M. (2002). Econometric analysis of cross section and panel data. Cambridge: MIT Press.

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgments

Vidar Ringstad, Luis César Herrero, Ellen Loots, participants at the IV Workshop on Cultural Economics and Management in Bilbao, 2012, participants at the Sixth European Workshop on Applied Cultural Economics in Ljubljana, 2013, and two anonymous referees are gratefully acknowledged for comments and suggestions for improvements to an earlier version of this paper.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Knut Løyland.

Appendices

Appendix 1: Result tables for the regression models

See Table 11.

Table 11 Estimated coefficients for the Tobit models

Appendix 2: Elasticities with respect to free income, matching grants and fee income

Derivation of (1) with respect to I yields \(\frac{{\partial S_{i} }}{\partial I} = \beta_{i} .\) From the definition of S i , it follows that

$$\frac{{\partial S_{i} }}{\partial I} = \frac{{\partial \left( {\frac{{p_{i} x_{i} }}{Y}} \right)}}{\partial I} = \frac{{p_{i} \frac{{\partial x_{i} }}{\partial I} - A_{i} }}{Y}.$$
(7)

Combining ∂S i /∂I = β i and (7) it follows that

$$\beta_{i} = \frac{{p_{i} \frac{{\partial x_{i} }}{\partial I} - S_{i} }}{Y}.$$
(8)

Rearranging into an elasticity, we find that

$$\varepsilon_{iI} \equiv \frac{{\partial x_{i} }}{\partial I}\frac{I}{{x_{i} }} = \beta_{i} \frac{I}{{S_{i} }} + \frac{I}{Y}.$$
(9)

The same steps as above also yield the corresponding elasticities with respect to matching grants to sector j (G j ) and user fees/box office income to sector j (U F j ):

$$\varepsilon_{{i,G_{j} }} \equiv \frac{{\partial x_{i} }}{{\partial G_{j} }}\frac{{G_{j} }}{{x_{i} }} = \eta_{ij} \frac{{G_{j} }}{{S_{i} }} + \frac{{G_{j} }}{Y}$$
(10)
$$\varepsilon_{{i,UF_{j} }} \equiv \frac{{\partial x_{i} }}{{\partial UF_{j} }}\frac{{UF_{j} }}{{x_{i} }} = \varphi_{ij} \frac{{UF_{j} }}{{S_{i} }} + \frac{{UF_{j} }}{Y}$$
(11)

Instead of presenting elasticities for the effects of matching grants and user fees/box office income per sector, Tables 6 and 7 in the paper show the increase in expenditures per sector following an increase in grants and user fees to the same sector. These tables only show own effects per sector, omitting the cross effects. The interpretation becomes the number of NOK in extra expenditures on each sector if the same sector receives an extra NOK in grants or user fees. The marginal increase in expenditures on each sector (expend i ) arising from an increase in matching grants to that sector (G i ) or user fees (UF i ) is defined from the regression parameters in (1) as follows:

$$\frac{{\partial {\text{expend}}_{i} }}{{\partial G_{i} }} = \eta_{ii} Y + S_{i} ,$$
(12)
$$\frac{{\partial {\text{expend}}_{i} }}{{\partial UF_{i} }} = \varphi_{ii} Y + S_{i} .$$
(13)

However, these derivatives apply only when there are no corner solution outcomes. With corner solution outcomes, the Tobit coefficients in the derivatives must be scaled by the predicted probability of having strictly positive outcomes.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Håkonsen, L., Løyland, K. Local government allocation of cultural services. J Cult Econ 40, 487–528 (2016). https://doi.org/10.1007/s10824-015-9255-4

Download citation

  • Received:

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s10824-015-9255-4

Keywords

JEL Classification

Navigation