Skip to main content
Log in

Efficient earmarking under decentralized fiscal commitments

  • Published:
International Tax and Public Finance Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

Earmarked federal grants are ubiquitous and significant. Traditional fiscal federalism is unable to explain these grants’ widespread utilization. Recent arguments focusing on the potential benefits of centralized earmarking in reducing incentives for the creation of soft budgets at subcentral government levels merit formalization. I show that universal earmarking improves the efficiency of a federation in which regional governments are able to commit to provision of all regional public goods. However, efficient earmarking need not be universal: It should only involve private consumption and fiscal budgets for public goods subject to decentralized fiscal commitments.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. Source: OECD Fiscal Decentralization database.

  2. This is clearly explained in Oates (2005), which provides an excellent review of the fiscal federalism literature. It includes an overview of the traditional viewpoints that emerged from the first-generation theory of fiscal federalism and the new viewpoints that have been emerging with the second-generation theory of fiscal federalism. The literature that studies the incentives that create soft budget constraints is one of the branches that advance new thinking on fiscal federalism.

  3. Lotz (2013) also makes a similar observation based on cost-efficiency terms.

  4. The analysis here assumes complete information and does not consider political economy issues. Furthermore, the model assumes that regional public goods do not produce interregional spillovers. Hence, earmarked grants cannot possibly be justified in terms of Pigouvian correction incentives.

  5. See also Buettner and Wildasin (2006). In addition, Wildasin (1997) discusses the bailout cases in New York, Philadelphia and São Paulo, among others, and Rodden et al. (2003) discusses bailout cases in Latin America.

  6. It is straightforward to show that the subgame perfect equilibrium for the sequential game in which the center is the Stackelberg leader and the regional governments are the Stackelberg followers is isomorphic to the simultaneous Nash equilibrium considered in the text.

  7. As correctly pointed out by a reviewer, the redistributive constraints (4e) and (4f) are a particular case of a federal redistributive grant system in which the federal government faces the following constraint on federal grants: \({\sum \nolimits _{j=1}^{J}} {s_{c,j} } ={\sum \nolimits _{j=1}^{J}} {{\sum \nolimits _{l=1}^{L}} {s_{l,j} } } \). Under this federal system, the federal government would have the ability to allocate dollars across all programs (private consumption and public consumption) that are controlled by the federal government for equalization purposes. We rule out this grandiose federal system in the analysis for the following two reasons: (i) the grandiose system implies that the federal government is ultimately able to not only equalize expenditure levels per program but also determine the level of final expenditures in each program; and (ii) the restrictive system implied by conditions (4e) and (4f) is the one in which the federal government plays the most limited role in inducing the regional governments to behave efficiently.

  8. In principle, different regional governments may have different abilities to commit to provision of regional public goods. It is, therefore, possible that some regional governments are able to commit more credibly to the provision of some public goods than some other regional governments. For simplicity and to keep the model as symmetric as possible, the case examined in this paper is restricted to a situation in which all regional governments face the same constraint on the ability of making credible commitments.

References

  • Akai, N., & Sato, M. (2008). Too big or too small? A synthetic view of the commitment problem of interregional transfers. Journal of Urban Economics, 64, 551–559.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Baskaran, T. (2012). Soft budget constraints and strategic interactions in subnational borrowing: Evidence from the German states, 1975–2005. Journal of Urban Economics, 71, 114–127.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bird, R. M., Ebel, R. D., & Wallich, C. I. (1995). Fiscal decentralization: From command to market. In R. M. Bird, R. D. Ebel, & C. I. Wallich (Eds.), Decentralization of the socialist state: Intergovernmental finance in transition economies (pp. 1–68). Washington, DC: The World Bank.

    Chapter  Google Scholar 

  • Blöchliger, H. (2013). Measuring decentralization: The OECD fiscal decentralization database. In J. Kim, J. Lotz, & H. Blöchliger (Eds.), Measuring fiscal decentralisation: Concepts and policies. Paris: OECD Publishing.

    Google Scholar 

  • Boadway, R. (2004). The theory and practice of equalization. CESIfo Economic Studies, 50, 211–254.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Breuillé, M.-L., Madiès, T., & Taugourdeau, E. (2006). Does tax competition soften regional budget constraint? Economics Letters, 90, 230–236.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Breuillé, M.-L., Madiès, T., & Taugourdeau, E. (2010). Gross versus net equalization scheme in a federation with decentralized leadership. Journal of Urban Economics, 68, 205–214.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Breuillé, M.-L., & Vigneault, M. (2010). Overlapping soft budget constraints. Journal of Urban Economics, 67, 259–269.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Buettner, T., & Wildasin, D. E. (2006). The dynamics of municipal fiscal adjustment. Journal of Public Economics, 90, 1115–1132.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Caplan, A., Cornes, R., & Silva, E. C. D. (2000). Pure public goods and income redistribution in a federation with decentralized leadership and imperfect labor mobility. Journal of Public Economics, 77, 265–284.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Council of Europe, (1985). European charter of local self government. European Treaty Series No. 122. Strasbourg.

  • Crivelli, E., & Staal, K. (2013). Size, spillovers and soft budget constraints. International Tax and Public Finance, 20, 338–356.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Goodspeed, T. J. (2002). Bailouts in a federation. International Tax and Public Finance, 9, 409–421.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kornai, J., Maskin, E., & Roland, G. (2003). Understanding the soft budget constraint. Journal of Economic Literature, 41, 1095–1136.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lotz, J. (2013). On grant policy and the OECD-taxonomy of grants. In J. Kim, J. Lotz, & H. Blöchliger (Eds.), Measuring fiscal decentralisation: Concepts and policies. Paris: OECD Publishing.

    Google Scholar 

  • Oates, W. E. (2005). Toward a second-generation theory of fiscal federalism. International Tax and Public Finance, 12, 349–373.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Pettersson-Lidbom, P. (2009). Dynamic commitment and the soft budget constraint: An empirical test. American Economic Journal: Economic Policy, 2, 154–179.

    Google Scholar 

  • Prud’homme, R. (1995). The dangers of decentralization. The World Bank Research Observer, 10, 201–220.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Qian, Y., & Roland, G. (1998). Federalism and the soft budget constraint. American Economic Review, 88, 1143–1162.

    Google Scholar 

  • Robinson, J. A., & Torvik, R. (2009). A political economy theory of the soft budget constraint. European Economic Review, 53, 786–798.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Rodden, J., Eskeland, G. S., & Litvack, J. (2003). Fiscal decentralization and the challenge of hard budget constraints. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Silva, E. C. D. (2014). Selective decentralized leadership. Journal of Urban Economics, 83, 1–5.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Silva, E. C. D., & Caplan, A. J. (1997). Transboundary pollution control in federal systems. Journal of Environmental Economics and Management, 34, 173–186.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Silva, E. C. D., & Yamaguchi, C. (2010). Interregional competition, spillovers and attachment in a federation. Journal of Urban Economics, 67, 219–225.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Smart, M., & Bird, R. M. (2009). Earmarked grants and accountability in government. In J. Kim, J. Lotz, & N. J. Mau (Eds.), General grants versus earmarked grants. Copenhagen: Korea Institute of Public Finance and Danish Ministry of Interior and Health.

    Google Scholar 

  • Tanzi, V. (1996). Fiscal federalism and decentralization: A review of some efficiency and macroeconomic aspects. In M. Bruno & B. Pleskovic (Eds.), Annual World Bank conference on development economics (pp. 295–316). Washington, DC: The World Bank.

  • Wildasin, D. E. (1997). Externalities and bailouts: Hard and soft budget constraints in intergovernmental fiscal relations (vol. 1843). Working paper. Washington, DC: The World Bank.

Download references

Acknowledgments

I would like to thank two referees that provided excellent comments and suggestions for improvement and also thank to those who provided comments during my presentation at the IIPF 2014 conference. Any error, however, is solely my own.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Emilson Caputo Delfino Silva.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Silva, E.C.D. Efficient earmarking under decentralized fiscal commitments. Int Tax Public Finance 22, 683–701 (2015). https://doi.org/10.1007/s10797-015-9365-0

Download citation

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s10797-015-9365-0

Keywords

JEL Classification

Navigation