Skip to main content
Log in

A political economy of tax havens

  • Published:
International Tax and Public Finance Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

The welfare effect of the existence of tax havens on high-tax countries has not been conclusive in the theoretical literature. Some papers show that the existence of tax havens is harmful to high-tax countries, while other studies argue that the opposite could occur. We aim to address a question: Do these welfare-reducing or welfare-enhancing properties still hold in the presence of lobbying? We find that the welfare-enhancing property does not hold, provided that the policy-maker attaches a sufficiently large weight to the political contribution received. Moreover, we point out that the cooperation among high-tax countries in restricting the international tax planning activity can lead to a lower level of social welfare in all high-tax countries.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. In the USA, several organized groups have been actively lobbying for lower corporate taxes. For example, the Alliance for Competitive Taxation asserts that its mission is to support comprehensive tax reform that lowers the corporate tax rate to 25 %. One of the main objectives of the Tax Innovation Equality is to press the US Congress to lower the corporate tax rate, so that it is competitive with the corresponding tax rates of other developed nations.

  2. We can also specify that there are two types of capitalists: the owners of immobile capital and the owners of mobile capital. This setting will not alter the results that follow.

  3. Allowing tax havens to impose a positive tax rate on capital income does not alter the results that follow.

  4. According to the empirical evidence, tax havens are usually very small jurisdictions (Hines and Rice 1994; Dharmapala and Hines 2009). Without loss of generality, we neglect productive activities in tax havens.

  5. See Desai et al. (2007) and Hong and Smart (2010) for more discussion.

  6. For notational simplicity, the fixed labor input is omitted in the production function.

  7. One may consult Audretsch (2007) for a detailed discussion on entrepreneurial capital.

  8. Differentiating \(r^n\) with respect to \(t\) gives \(\partial r^{n}/\partial t={f}''\cdot \partial k/\partial t-1\). Then, inserting (5) into this equation gives rise to (7).

  9. We can see this by inserting the equilibrium tax rate (derived later in (12)) into (9e) to derive that, in equilibrium, the tax revenues increase with a higher tax rate. We thank a reviewer for pointing this out.

  10. In settings without political concern, Bucovetsky and Haufler (2008) and Johannesen (2012) endogenize the access to international tax planning.

  11. The derivation of the first-order condition without the global-truthfulness assumption can be found in Appendix .

  12. Bernheim and Whinston (1986) show that a truthful schedule is a best response to any strategy of the opponent, even if it is not the only best response. Therefore, they argue that truthful Nash equilibria may be focal among the set of Nash equilibria. See also Grossman and Helpman (1994) for a related discussion on the global-truthfulness assumption.

  13. This can be seen by inserting \(\theta =0\), indicating that the policy-maker is benevolent, into (13), which gives \(\frac{\partial t^{*}}{\partial \psi }=\frac{-n^{k}{f}''}{(1+\beta )(1-\psi )^{3}}(\beta -\psi \beta +2h\beta )\). This equation shows that \(t^{*}\) does not change with \(\psi \), when \(\beta \) (equity concern) is equal to zero, while \(t^{*}\) increases with \(\psi \), when \(\beta \) is positive.

  14. See Appendix for the derivation of (15).

  15. The welfare effects of a change in the tax rate are still captured by (9a), (9c), and (9e), because countries take \(\psi \) as given when choosing \(t\).

  16. See Appendix for the derivation of (17).

  17. Note that since we restrict \(t^{e}\) to be non-negative, we rule out the case where \(\beta <\theta =\delta \), which leads to a negative equilibrium tax rate.

  18. This can be seen from (9a) and (9c). When \(\psi \) rises, the adverse welfare effect of the capital tax on the capitalists increases, and the effect on the workers decreases.

  19. For example, Bucovetsky and Haufler (2008) develop a model where the government sequentially sets the tax base and the tax rate.

References

  • Anand, B. N., & Sansing, R. (2000). The weighting game: Formula apportionment as an instrument of public policy. National Tax Journal, 53, 183–200.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Audretsch, D. B. (2007). Entrepreneurship capital and economic growth. Oxford Review of Economic Policy, 23, 63–78.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bergemann, D., & Valimaki, J. (2003). Dynamic common agency. Journal of Economic Theory, 111, 23–48.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bernheim, B. D., & Whinston, M. D. (1986). Menu auction, resource allocation, and economic influence. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 101, 1–31.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bucovetsky, S., & Haufler, A. (2008). Tax competition when firms choose their organizational form: Should tax loopholes for multinationals be closed? Journal of International Economics, 74, 188–201.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bucovetsky, S., & Wilson, J. D. (1991). Tax competition with two tax instruments. Regional Science and Urban Economics, 21, 333–350.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Desai, A., Dyck, A., & Zingales, L. (2007). Theft and taxes. Journal of Financial Economics, 84, 591–623.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dharmapala, D., & Hines, J. R, Jr. (2009). Which countries become tax havens? Journal of Public Economics, 93, 1058–1068.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fuest, C., & Huber, B. (2001). Why is there so little tax coordination? The role of majority voting and international tax evasion. Regional Science and Urban Economics, 31, 299–317.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gordon, R. H. (1986). Taxation of investment and savings in a world economy. American Economic Review, 76, 1086–1102.

    Google Scholar 

  • Grossman, G. M., & Helpman, E. (1994). Protection for sale. American Economic Review, 84, 833–850.

    Google Scholar 

  • Grossman, G. M., & Helpman, E. (2002). Interest groups and trade policy. Princeton NJ: Princeton University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Haufler, A., & Runkel, M. (2012). Firms’ financial choices and thin capitalization rules under corporate tax competition. European Economic Review, 56, 1087–1103.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hillman, A. L. (1982). Declining industries and political-support protection motives. American Economic Review, 72, 1180–1187.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hillman, A. L. (1989). The political economy of protection, Harwood Academic Publishers, Chur. Reprinted 2001. London: Routledge.

  • Hines, J. R, Jr, & Rice, E. M. (1994). Fiscal paradise: Foreign tax havens and American business. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 109, 149–182.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hong, Q., & Smart, M. (2010). In praise of tax havens: International tax planning and foreign direct investment. European Economic Review, 54, 82–95.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Johannesen, N. (2010). Imperfect tax competition for profits, asymmetric equilibrium and beneficial tax havens. Journal of International Economics, 81, 253–264.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Johannesen, N. (2012). Optimal fiscal barriers to international economic integration in the presence of tax havens. Journal of Public Economics, 96, 400–416.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Johannesen, N. (2014). Tax avoidance with cross-border hybrid instruments. Journal of Public Economics, 112, 40–52.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Krautheim, S., & Schmidt-Eisenlohr, T. (2011). Heterogeneous firms, ‘profit shifting’ FDI and international tax competition. Journal of Public Economics, 95, 122–133.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lai, Y. B. (2010). The political economy of capital market integration and tax competition. European Journal of Political Economy, 26, 475–487.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lockwood, B., & Makris, M. (2006). Tax incidence, majority voting and capital market integration. Journal of Public Economics, 90, 1007–1025.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Marceau, N., Mongrain, S., & Wilson, J. D. (2010). Why do most countries set high tax rates on capital? Journal of International Economics, 80, 249–259.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Nicodème, G. (2009). On recent developments in fighting harmful tax practices. National Tax Journal, 62, 755–771.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • OECD. (1998). Harmful tax competition: An emerging global issue. Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development, Paris, France.

  • OECD. (2000). Towards global tax cooperation: Progress in identifying and eliminating harmful tax practices. Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development, Paris, France.

  • Persson, T., & Tabellini, G. (1992). The politics of 1992: Fiscal policy and European integration. Review of Economic Studies, 59, 689–701.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Poterba, J. M. (1998). Public finance and public choice. National Tax Journal, 51, 391–396.

    Google Scholar 

  • Slemrod, J., & Wilson, J. D. (2009). Tax competition with parasitic tax havens. Journal of Public Economics, 93, 1261–1270.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Zodrow, G. R., & Mieszkowski, P. (1986). Pigou, Tiebout, property taxation and the underprovision of local public goods. Journal of Urban Economics, 19, 356–370.

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgments

The authors are grateful to the editor Andreas Haufler and the two referees for the helpful comments and suggestions. Financial support from the Ministry of Science and Technology [Grant 102-2410-H-004 -002 -MY2] is gratefully acknowledged.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Yu-Bong Lai.

Appendices

Appendix 1: Derivation of (11) without the global-truthfulness assumption

According to Grossman and Helpman (1994), \(t^{e}\)is a sub-game-perfect Nash equilibrium of the lobbying game, if (i) \(t^{e}\) maximizes \(\theta m^{k}(t)+W(t)\) and (ii) \(t^{e}\) maximizes \(W^{k}(t)-m^{k}(t)+[\theta m^{k}(t)+W(t)]\). Condition (i) stipulates that, given the contribution schedule provided by the lobbyists, the policy-maker chooses \(t\) to maximize his own welfare. Condition (ii) states that the equilibrium tax rate should maximize the joint welfare of the lobbyists and the policy-maker. If this condition is violated, then the lobbyists could reformulate the political contribution schedule to induce the policy-maker to choose the jointly optimal policy.

Condition (i) implies that

$$\begin{aligned} \theta \frac{\partial m^{k}(t^{e})}{\partial t}+\frac{\partial W(t^{e})}{\partial t}=0 \end{aligned}$$
(22)

and condition (ii) implies that

$$\begin{aligned} \frac{\partial W^{k}(t^{e})}{\partial t}-\frac{\partial m^{k}(t^{e})}{\partial t}+\left[ {\theta \frac{\partial m^{k}(t^{e})}{\partial t}+\frac{\partial W(t^{e})}{\partial t}} \right] =0 \end{aligned}$$
(23)

Taken together, the two conditions ensure that

$$\begin{aligned} \frac{\partial m^{k}(t^{e})}{\partial t}=\frac{\partial W^{k}(t^{e})}{\partial t} \end{aligned}$$
(24)

This condition shows that the contribution schedule is locally truthful around the equilibrium \(t\); i.e., the lobbying group sets its contribution schedule so that the marginal change in the contribution for a small change in the tax rate fits the effect of the change in \(t\) on the lobbying group’s gross welfare.

Then by inserting (24) into (22), we obtain (11), which is the same as the first-order condition with the global-truthfulness assumption. Thus, the equilibrium policy under the global-truthfulness assumption is the same as that without the assumption. The workers’ and pensioners’ lobbying can be obtained by a similar approach, and so we do not repeat it here.

Appendix 2: Derivation of (15)

We first derive the effects of the capital tax and tax planning on the social welfare by using (8) and (9a)–(9f):

$$\begin{aligned}&\frac{\partial W}{\partial t}=-n^{k}h\psi -n^{k}(1+h)(1-\psi )+(1+\beta )\left[ {n^{k}(1-\psi +h)+(1-\psi )^{2}\frac{t}{{f}''}} \right] \nonumber \\ \end{aligned}$$
(25)
$$\begin{aligned}&\frac{\partial W}{\partial \psi }=-n^{k}ht+n^{k}(1+h)t+(1+\beta )t\left[ {-(1-\psi )\frac{t}{{f}''}-n^{k}} \right] \end{aligned}$$
(26)

Supposing the economy is initially in equilibrium, we can then substitute (12) into (25) and (26), and further substitute them into (14), which gives:

$$\begin{aligned}&\frac{dW}{d\psi }=\frac{\partial W}{\partial t}\frac{dt}{d\psi }+\frac{\partial W}{\partial \psi }=\frac{-n^{k2}h\psi {f}''\theta }{(1+\beta )(1-\psi )^{3}}(\beta -\beta \psi +2\beta h-h\psi \theta -h\theta )\\&\quad -\frac{n^{k2}{f}''}{(1+\beta )(1-\psi )^{3}}(\beta h-h\psi \theta )\beta (1-\psi +h-h\psi \theta ). \end{aligned}$$

By rearranging the above equation, we can obtain (15) in the main text.

Appendix 3: Proof of Proposition 3

From (14), we see that

$$\begin{aligned} \frac{dW}{d\psi }\frac{>}{<}0\Leftrightarrow -\psi h\theta ^{2}+(1-\psi +h)\beta ^{2}\frac{>}{<}0. \end{aligned}$$

Rearranging the above equation yields

$$\begin{aligned} \frac{dW}{d\psi }\frac{>}{<}0\Leftrightarrow \theta ^{2}\frac{<}{>}\frac{(1-\psi +h)\beta ^{2}}{h\psi }, \end{aligned}$$

and since \(\theta \) and \(\beta \) are non-negative, we have proved Proposition 3.

Appendix 4: Derivation of (17)

The change in each country’s welfare in response to \(\hat{{\psi }}\) can be expressed as:

$$\begin{aligned} \frac{dW}{d\hat{{\psi }}}=\frac{\partial W}{\partial t}\frac{dt}{d\hat{{\psi }}}+\frac{\partial W}{\partial \hat{{\psi }}}. \end{aligned}$$
(27)

First, we use the conditions \(\partial W^{k}/\partial \hat{{\psi }}=n^{k}t,\, \partial W^{l}/\partial \hat{{\psi }}=0\) and \(\partial W^{p}/\partial \hat{{\psi }}=-n^{k}t\) to obtain \(\partial W/\partial \hat{{\psi }}=-\beta n^{k}t\). Substituting this condition and (25) into (27) gives:

$$\begin{aligned} \frac{dW}{d\hat{{\psi }}}=\frac{-n^{k2}h\psi {f}''\theta }{(1+\beta )(1-\psi )^{3}}(\beta -\beta \psi +2\beta h-h\psi \theta -h\theta )-\beta n^{k}t. \end{aligned}$$
(28)

Now we insert the initial equilibrium tax rate (12) into (28):

$$\begin{aligned} \frac{dW}{d\hat{{\psi }}}&= \frac{-n^{k2}h\psi {f}''\theta }{(1+\beta )(1-\psi )^{3}}(\beta -\beta \psi +2\beta h-h\psi \theta -h\theta ) \\&+\,\beta n^{k}\frac{n^{k}{f}''}{(1+\beta )(1-\psi )^{2}}\left[ {\beta (1-\psi +h)-h\psi \theta } \right] \\&= \frac{n^{k2}{f}''\left\{ {\beta (1-\psi )\left[ {\beta (1-\psi +h)-h\psi \theta } \right] -(\beta -\beta \psi +2\beta h-h\psi \theta -h\theta )h\psi \theta } \right\} }{(1+\beta )(1-\psi )^{3}} \\ \end{aligned}$$

After some algebra we can obtain (17) in the main text.

Appendix 5: Proof of Proposition 5

Let us define the function

$$\begin{aligned} \Omega (\theta )=-h^{2}\psi (1+\psi )\theta ^{2}+2h\beta \theta (1-\psi +h)-\beta ^{2}(1-\psi +h)(1-\psi ), \end{aligned}$$

and let \(D\) be the discriminant of \(\Omega (\theta )=0\). Thus, we have:

$$\begin{aligned} D=4h^{2}\beta ^{2}(1-\psi +h)\psi (\psi +h\psi -1). \end{aligned}$$

From (17), it can obviously be seen that \(\partial W/\partial \hat{{\psi }}\) and \(\Omega (\theta )\) share the same sign. If \((\psi +h\psi -1)<0\), then \(D<0,\, \Omega (\theta )<0\) so that \(\partial W/\partial \hat{{\psi }}<0\). However, if \((\psi +h\psi -1)>0\), \(\Omega (\theta )\) can be rewritten as:

$$\begin{aligned} \Omega (\theta )&= \left[ {\theta -\frac{\psi (1-\psi +h)+\sqrt{(1-\psi +h)\psi (\psi +h\psi -1)}}{(1+\psi )h\psi }\beta } \right] \nonumber \\&\; \times \left[ {\theta -\frac{\psi (1-\psi +h)-\sqrt{(1-\psi +h)\psi (\psi +h\psi -1)}}{(1+\psi )h\psi }\beta } \right] . \end{aligned}$$
(29)

Thus, we have proved that, under the condition \((\psi +h\psi -1)>0\), \(\partial W/\partial \hat{{\psi }}\) is positive if \(\theta \) lies within a positive interval.

Appendix 6: Worker’s lobbying

We first replace \((\theta , \beta )\) in (15) by \((\Theta , B)\) to derive the condition:

$$\begin{aligned} \frac{dW}{d\psi }\frac{>}{<}0\;if\;\left[ {-\psi h\Theta ^{2}+(1-\psi +h)B^{2}} \right] \frac{>}{<}0. \end{aligned}$$

Hence, we see that \(dW/d\psi \) is more likely to be negative if \(|\Theta |\) is larger, that is, if the difference between \(\theta \) and \(\delta \) is larger. Next, by replacing \((\theta , \beta )\) in (29) by \((\Theta , B)\), we can show that, under the condition \((\psi +h\psi -1)>0\), \(\partial W/\partial \hat{{\psi }}\) will be positive, if \(\theta \) lies within the following interval:

$$\begin{aligned} \frac{\psi (1-\psi +h)-\Gamma }{(1+\psi )h\psi }(\beta -\delta )+\delta <\theta <\frac{\psi (1-\psi +h)+\Gamma }{(1+\psi )h\psi }(\beta -\delta )+\delta , \end{aligned}$$

where \(\Gamma =\sqrt{(1-\psi +h)\psi (\psi +h\psi -1)}\).

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Chu, H., Cheng, CC. & Lai, YB. A political economy of tax havens. Int Tax Public Finance 22, 956–976 (2015). https://doi.org/10.1007/s10797-014-9338-8

Download citation

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s10797-014-9338-8

Keywords

JEL Classification

Navigation