Skip to main content
Log in

Illusion of control and the pursuit of authority

  • Original Paper
  • Published:
Experimental Economics Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

We measure participants’ willingness to pay for transparently useless authority—the right to make a completely uninformed task decision. We further elicit participants’ beliefs about receiving their preferred outcome if they make the decision themselves, and if another participant makes the decision for them. We find that participants pay more to make the decision themselves if they also believe that they can thus increase the probability of getting their preferred outcome. Illusion of control therefore exists in a controlled laboratory environment with monetary incentives and is connected to peoples’ pursuit of authority.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1
Fig. 2
Fig. 3

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. Numerous articles study the allocation of decision rights in organizations. For very useful surveys of the economics literature, see Bolton and Dewatripont (2013), and Gibbons et al. (2013).

  2. See, for example, Langer (1975), Thompson (1999), Fast et al. (2009), and Fenton-O’Creevy et al. (2003).

  3. Since we do not exogenously vary illusion of control, we cannot identify a causal link between illusion of control and the pursuit of authority. This holds because our measure of illusion of control can of course be correlated with some unobservable characteristic, which in turn affects the decision to seek authority.

  4. We studied the same research questions with two previous experiments based on slightly different designs. The main differences to the current design were the labeling of task choices, what beliefs were measured, and whether and how belief elicitation was incentivized. Other changes included location (now Frankfurt, before Amsterdam), stake size, and the set of personal traits considered in the ex-post questionnaire. All versions of the design led to the same conclusions.

  5. This corresponds to 78.42 eurocents. The small amounts involved in our experiment may suggest that preferences for authority and illusion of control are negligible in practice. We discuss this important argument in our conclusion.

  6. Owens et al. (2014) estimate an authority premium of 8–15 % of average earnings. Based on the subjects with fully rational beliefs, we find an authority premium of 8 % of average earnings if only the activity in the third part was payoff relevant. Our findings are thus consistent with Owens et al. (2014) but seem to suggest that the authority premium is closer to the lower bound they infer.

  7. The results are almost the same when excluding the three outliers apparent in Fig. 3. These are the observations with Belief-Own-Minus-Belief-Other of −55, 75, and 100. The only difference to the above results is that the positive Spearman rank and Pearson correlations between Willingness-To-Pay and Belief-Other are now statistically significant (p-values of 0.09 and 0.03). Regression analysis reported later shows that the link between Belief-Other and Willingness-To-Pay becomes negative and statistically significant once controlling for Belief-Own.

  8. More intelligent people gain more from getting their preferred activity. They could therefore—wrongly—assign authority higher instrumental value. This might explain why the link between reported beliefs and willingness to pay is stronger for subjects with higher mathematical ability.

  9. Results are essentially the same for two-sided Tobit regressions. The only difference is that in the Tobit regression corresponding to the simple linear regression reported in column (3) the negative coefficient on Belief-Other is no longer statistically significant. Results are also essentially same when we drop three outliers as seen in Fig. 3. The only difference is that in the regression corresponding to the regression reported in column (6) the coefficient on Entrepreneurship Intentions is then no longer statistically significant.

References

  • Bartling, B., Engl, F., & Weber, R. A. (2015). Game form misconceptions are not necessary for a willingness-to-pay vs. willingness-to-accept gap. Journal of the Economic Science Associations, 1, 72–85.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bartling, B., Fehr, E., & Herz, H. (2014). The intrinsic value of decision rights. Econometrica, 82(6), 2005–2039.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bolton, P., & Dewatripont, M. (2013). Authority in organizations. In R. Gibbons & J. Roberts (Eds.), Handboook of organizational economics (pp. 342–372). Princeton: Princeton University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Burger, J. M., & Cooper, H. M. (1979). The desirability of control. Motivation and Emotion, 3(4), 381–393.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cason, T. N., & Plott, C. R. (2014). Misconceptions and game form recognition: Challenges to theories of revealed preferences and framing. Journal of Political Economy, 122(6), 1235–1270.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Charness, G., & Gneezy, U. (2010). Portfolio choice and risk attitudes: An experiment. Economic Inquiry, 48(1), 133–146.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cobb-Clark, D. A., & Schurer, S. (2013). Two economists’ musings on the stability of locus of control. Economic Journal, 123, 359–400.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dohmen, T., Falk, A., Huffman, D., & Sunde, U. (2009). Homo reciprocans: Survey evidence on prevalence, behavior and success. Economic Journal, 119(536), 592–612.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dominguez Martinez, S., Sloof, R., & von Siemens, F. A. (2014). Monitored by your friends, not your foes: Strategic ignorance and the delegation of real authority. Games and Economic Behavior, 85, 289–305.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Falk, A., & Kosfeld, M. (2006). The hidden costs of control. American Economic Review, 96(5), 1611–1630.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fast, N. J., Gruenfeld, D. H., Sivanathan, N., & Galinsky, A. D. (2009). Illusory control: A generative force behind power’s far-reaching effects. Psycholgical Science, 20(4), 502–508.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fehr, E., Herz, H., & Wilkening, T. (2013). The lure of authority: Motivation and incentive effects of power. American Economic Review, 103(4), 1325–1359.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fenton-O’Creevy, M., Nicholson, N., Soane, E., & Willman, P. (2003). Trading on illusions: Unrealistic perceptions of control and trading performance. Journal of Occupational and Organizational Psychology, 76, 53–68.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Foss, N. J. (2003). Selective intervention and internal hybrids: Interpreting and learning from the rise and decline of the Oticon Spaghetti organization. Organization Science, 14(3), 331–349.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gibbons, R., Matouschek, N., & Roberts, J. (2013). Decisions in organizations. In R. Gibbons & J. Roberts (Eds.), Handbook of organizational economics (pp. 373–431). Princeton: Princeton University Press.

    Chapter  Google Scholar 

  • Karni, E. (2009). A mechanism for eliciting probabilities. Econometrica, 77, 603–606.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Langer, E. J. (1975). The illusion of control. Journal of Personality and Social Psychology, 32, 311–328.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Owens, D., Grossman, Z., & Fackler, R. (2014). The control premium: A preference for payoff autonomy. American Economic Journal: Microeconomics, 6(4), 138–161.

    Google Scholar 

  • Pfeffer, J., Cialdini, R. B., Hanna, B., & Knopoff, K. (1998). Faith in supervision and the self-enhancement bias: Two psychological reasons why managers don’t empower workers. Basic and Applied Social Psychology, 20(4), 313–321.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Plott, C. R., & Zeiler, K. (2005). The willingness to pay–willingness to accept gap, the “endowment effect”, subject misconceptions, and experimental procedures to eliciting valuations. American Economic Review, 95(3), 530–545.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Plott, C. R., & Zeiler, K. (2007). Exchange asymmetries incorrectly interpreted as evidence of endowment effect theory and prospect theory? American Economic Review, 97(4), 1449–1466.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Plott, C. R., & Zeiler, K. (2011). The willingness to pay–willingness to accept gap, the “endowment effect”, subject misconceptions, and experimental procedures to eliciting valuations: Reply. American Economic Review, 101(2), 1012–1028.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Powdthavee, N., & Riyanto, Y. E. (2015). Would you pay for transparently useless advice? A test of boundaries of beliefs in the folly of predictions. Review of Economics and Statistics, 97(2), 257–272.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Savage, L. J. (1971). Elicitation of personal probabilities and expectations. Journal of the American Statistical Association, 66(336), 783–801.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Schlag, K., Tremewan, J., & van der Weele, J. (2015). A penny for your thoughts: A survey of methods for eliciting beliefs. Experimental Economics, 18(3), 457–490.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Thompson, S. C. (1999). Illusion of control: How we overstimate our personal influence. Current Directions in Psychological Science, 8(6), 187–190.

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgments

We are very grateful to Thomas Buser, Holger Herz, Joep Sonnemans, Jeroen van de Ven, and Joël van der Weele for very helpful comments. We thank David Cooper, Charles Noussair, and two anonymous referees for their very valuable suggestions that greatly improved our experimental design and the paper in general.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Ferdinand A. von Siemens.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Sloof, R., von Siemens, F.A. Illusion of control and the pursuit of authority. Exp Econ 20, 556–573 (2017). https://doi.org/10.1007/s10683-016-9499-7

Download citation

  • Received:

  • Revised:

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s10683-016-9499-7

Keywords

JEL Classification

Navigation