Skip to main content
Log in

Fertility and Economic Development: Quantile Regression Evidence on the Inverse J-shaped Pattern

  • Published:
European Journal of Population Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

This paper analyses empirically the relationship between economic development and fertility. Through a new sample selection and quantile regression, it investigates whether there is an inverse J-shaped pattern between these two variables, and, if so, whether it depends on development and fertility levels. Our results confirm that the inverse J-shaped pattern exists, but only when a certain level of economic development is attained. Results also suggest an innovative finding: the J-shape depends not only on the development but also on the fertility level. The higher the fertility rate, the higher the GDP per capita needed to reverse fertility decline, and the faster the negative and positive segments of the J-shape fall and grow.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1

Source: Developed by the authors

Fig. 2

Source: Developed by the authors using estimates from Table 2

Fig. 3

Source: Developed by the authors using estimates from Table 3

Fig. 4

Source: Developed by the authors using estimates from Table 4

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. Myrskylä et al. (2009) define this advanced economic position as a Human Development Index (HDI) of 0.86 or higher, whereas Luci-Greulich and Thévenon (2014) use GDP per capita (GDP pc) to measure development and a GDP pc of 22,000 US dollars or higher to define the advanced economic position.

  2. Some recent papers that attempt to explain this fertility rebound through institutional variables such as female employment, family, and social policies or gender equality include Luci-Greulich and Thévenon (2013, 2014), Myrskylä et al. (2011), and Esping-Andersen and Billari (2015).

  3. This debate is open since studies such as Furuoka (2009, 2013) and Harttgen and Vollmer (2014) find no empirical evidence for the J-shape.

  4. Total Fertility Rate (TFR) indicates number of children that would be born to a woman if she were to live to the end of her childbearing years and bear children in accordance with current age-specific fertility rates (World Bank 2015).

  5. Myrskylä et al. (2009) open a new debate on when reversal occurs. For them, 2005 is an important year for this reversal, but they also identify different years for different countries—such as 1976 in the USA, 1983 in Norway and 1994 in Italy—as well as some countries (e.g. Japan, Canada, South Korea) where decline in fertility does not reverse at all. The question of when the reversal occurs is beyond the scope of this paper.

  6. Since one of our main objectives is to divide the sample by income level to study the relationship between fertility and income, it is preferable to use GDP pc as the main covariate for measuring this relationship. The HDI is a compounded score of 3 indicators: Education Index, Health Index and GDP pc (Malik 2014). According to Luci-Greulich and Thévenon (2014: 192), “as life expectancy and school enrolment are correlated with GDP per capita… it is unclear what elements behind human development drive the fertility rebound in highly developed countries”.

  7. An empirical test—comparing regression coefficients between tertile groups (Allison 2009)—has been made to contrast whether a significantly differentiated effect of the J-shape relationship exists among the tertile groups considered in our analysis. The outcomes of this test—available upon request—prove the importance of considering a differentiated regression analysis for each tertile group to provide a better knowledge of the J-shape pattern, as this pattern is significantly different for each group.

  8. We estimate the log transformation of GDP pc (see Luci-Greulich and Thévenon 2013, 2014) because the logarithmic form reduces absolute increases in the level of this variable and thus captures proportional rather than absolute differences in GDP pc distribution.

  9. Following Luci-Greulich and Thévenon (2014), we include 10-year-period effects to control for variables not observed in the model that influence variation in fertility rate by decade.

  10. The CQR approach, developed by Koenker and Bassett (1978), provides rich characterization for using a regression model to analyse the effect of covariates on conditional distribution of the dependent variable. This new technique is an advance in econometrics that facilitates analysis of the full, conditional distributional properties of the dependent variable, considering a possible differentiated effect estimated between variables depending on the τth quantile considered in the analysis (Hao and Naiman 2007). In contrast to LRM, the CQR technique is quite useful when the conditional distribution of the dependent variable does not meet the normality assumption, as it improves the robustness of the estimates in the presence of outliers.

  11. Although we have applied Pooled-Ordinary Least Squares (Pooled-OLS) and fixed-effects OLS estimates of Eq. (1), Table 1 presents only the later for the sake of clarity and space. However, Pooled-OLS estimates are available upon request.

  12. Table 6 in “Appendix 1” provides the division of the sample by tertiles of income.

  13. Furuoka (2009, 2013) uses threshold regression strategy and Harttgen and Vollmer (2014) applies difference-in-differences estimation methodology.

  14. Although we do not consider the first and second tertiles of income group in this new analysis, we applied additional estimates to test for the linear relationship between fertility and income, and whether this relationship differs for different fertility levels, or quantiles. To do so, we applied a new CQR fixed-effects panel-data analysis (Canay 2011), estimating the following equation:

    $${\text{TFR}}_{it} = \beta_{0} + \beta_{1} {\text{Log\_GDPpc}}_{it} + \alpha_{i} + \delta_{t} + \varepsilon_{it} .$$

    The outcomes obtained indicate a significant and negative relationship between fertility and income, where the slope estimated is greater for the higher levels of fertility (Q.75 and Q.90). Thus, countries with a higher number of children born per woman suffer a greater negative impact of a variation in GDP pc on their fertility level in both tertile groups. Results from this additional analysis are available upon request.

  15. Estimations for first and second tertiles of GDP pc are not included in the paper because their results were not statistically significant in previous subsection. Nevertheless, they are available upon request.

  16. The \({\text{Log\_GDPpc}}_{it}\) adopts different values in OECD and third tertile subsamples.

  17. We repeated the same analysis with the whole sample to prove that the CQR results are not driven by the subsamples selected. This robustness check, available upon request, shows that the main qualitative findings still hold, although the threshold points are lower (US$ 4794.36 for the Q10 and US$ 5092.14 for the Q90). In this regard, we consider our tertile division CQR analysis adequate in order to calculate the threshold points, since the differentiated J-shape pattern by tertile of income is significant, something that is not considered when applying an analysis for the whole sample.

  18. Since GDP per capita is only available from 1990 for some countries, we have also repeated the same analysis with a larger sample of 167 countries and a shorter time period (1990–2010) to confirm our results. This robustness check, available upon request, shows that, although the main qualitative findings still hold, the results for the third tertile of income show a positive and significant relationship between fertility and GDP pc. When reducing the time period in the new sample and including the most recent years and the most highly developed countries, we find the final positive segment of the J-shape curve. This result highlights the importance of considering the time period in fertility studies, as it conditions the results. Further research is needed to analyse this issue in greater depth.

  19. The difference between our outcomes, obtained using the CQR approach, and those obtained by Furuoka (2009, 2013) using the threshold regression methodology (Hansen 2000), is that the later does not find any J-shape relationship, while we do. Our approach can perform a different analysis for the different levels of fertility, something not possible with Furuoka’s methodology. The threshold regression method determines a threshold value or breaking point in the fertility–development (defined by the HDI) relationship. Considering the different levels of fertility in the sample jointly, the threshold value is calculated by dividing the independent variable into two groups (this value is calculated by minimizing the concentrated sum of squared errors of the estimated single threshold equation), avoiding the need to differentiate the presence of several J-shaped patterns between the countries with high fertility levels from those of the lower ones.

References

  • Abrevaya, J., & Dahl, C. M. (2008). The effects of birth inputs on birthweight: Evidence from quantile estimation on panel data. Journal of Business and Economic Statistics, 26, 379–397.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Allison, P. D. (2009). Comparing logit and probit coefficients across groups. Sociological Methods Research, 28(2), 186–208.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Anderson, T., & Kohler, H. P. (2015). Low fertility, socioeconomic development, and gender equity. Population and development review, 41(3), 381–407.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Becker, G. S. (1960). An economic analysis of fertility. Demographic and economic change in developed countries. NBER Conference Series, 11, 209–231.

  • Becker, G. (1981). A treatise on the family. Cambridge: Harvard University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Becker, G., Murphy, K., & Tamura, R. (1990). Human capital, fertility, and economic growth. Journal of Political Economy, 98(5), 812–837.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bisin, A., & Verdier, T. (2000). Beyond the melting pot: Cultural transmission, marriage, and the evolution of ethnic and religious traits. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 115(3), 955–988.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bisin, A., & Verdier, T. (2001). The economics of cultural transmission and the dynamics of preferences. Journal of Economic Theory, 97(2), 298–319.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bongaarts, J. (2008). Fertility transitions in developing countries: Progress or stagnation? Studies in Family Planning, 39(2), 105–110.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Booth, A. L., & Joo Kee, H. (2006). Intergenerational transmission of fertility patterns in Britain. Institute for the Study of Labour (IZA) Discussion Paper number 2437, November 2006.

  • Boserup, E. (1970). Women’s role in economic development. New York: St. Martin’s.

    Google Scholar 

  • Brakman, S., Garretsen, H., & Van Marrewijk, C. (2009). Economic geography within and between European nations: The role of market potential and density across space and time. Journal of Regional Science, 49(4), 777–800.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bryant, J. (2007). Theories of fertility decline and the evidence from development indicators. Population and Development Review, 33(1), 101–127.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Caldwell, J. C. (1976). Toward a restatement of demographic transition theory. Population and Development Review, 2(3–4), 321–366.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Canay, I. A. (2011). A simple approach to quantile regression for panel data. The Econometrics Journal, 14, 368–386.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • D’Addio, A. C., & d’Ercole, M. M. (2005). Trends and determinants of fertility rates: The role of policies, Working Papers No. 27. OECD Publishing.

  • Day, C. (2004). The dynamics of fertility and growth: baby boom, bust and bounce-back. Topics in Macroeconomics, 4(1), 14–132.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • De Lange, M., Wolbers, M. H., Gesthuizen, M., & Ultee, W. C. (2014). The impact of macro-and micro-economic uncertainty on family formation in the Netherlands. European Journal of Population, 30(2), 161–185.

    Google Scholar 

  • Doepke, M. (2004). Accounting for fertility decline during the transition to growth. Journal of Economic Growth, 9(3), 347–383.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Esping-Andersen, G., & Billari, F. C. (2015). Re-theorizing family demographics. Population and Development Review, 41(1), 1–31.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fernández, R., & Fogli, A. (2005). Culture: An empirical investigation of beliefs, work and fertility. Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis, Research Dept. Staff Report 361, April.

  • Furuoka, F. (2009). Looking for a J-shaped development-fertility relationship: Do advances in development really reverse fertility declines. Economics Bulletin, 29(4), 3067–3074.

    Google Scholar 

  • Furuoka, F. (2013). Is there a reversal in fertility decline? An economic analysis of the “Fertility J-Curve”. Transformations in Business & Economics, 12(2), 44–57.

    Google Scholar 

  • Galor, O., & Weil, D. (1996). The gender gap, fertility, and growth. American Economic Review, 86, 374–387.

    Google Scholar 

  • Galor, O., & Weil, D. N. (2000). Population, technology, and growth: From Malthusian stagnation to the demographic transition and beyond. American Economic Review, 90(4), 806–828.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Galvao, A. F. (2011). Quantile regression for dynamic panel data with fixed effects. Journal of Econometrics, 164, 142–157.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Shapiro D., & Gebreselassie, T. (2007). Fertility transition in Sub-Saharan Africa: Falling and stalling. Paper presented at the Meeting of the Population Association of America, New York.

  • Goldstein, J. R., Sobotka, T., & Jasilioniene, A. (2009). The end of lowest-low fertility? Population and Development Review, 35(4), 663–699.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gustavus, S., & Nam, C. (1970). Family structure and children’s achievements. Journal of Population Economics, 14(2), 249–270.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hansen, B. E. (2000). Sample splitting and threshold estimation. Econometrica, 68(3), 575–603.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hao, L., & Naiman, D. Q. (2007). Quantile regression. London: Sage Publications.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Harttgen, K., & Vollmer, S. (2014). A reversal in the relationship of human development with fertility? Demography, 51(1), 173–184.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Heston, A., Summers, R., & Aten, B. (2012). Penn World Table. Version 7.1. Philadelphia, PA: Center for International Comparisons of Production, Income and Prices at the University of Pennsylvania (CICUP).

  • Hotz, V.-J., Kerman, J.-A., & Willis, R.-J. (1997). The economics of fertility in developed countries: A survey. In M. Rosenzweig & O. Stark (Eds.), Handbook of population economics (1A ed., pp. 275–347). Amsterdam: Elsevier.

    Google Scholar 

  • Kirk, D. (1996). Demographic transition theory. Population Studies, 50(3), 361–387.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Koenker, R. (2004). Quantile regression for longitudinal data. Journal of Multivariate Analysis, 91, 74–89.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Koenker, R., & Bassett, G. J. (1978). Regression quantiles. Econometrica, 46(1), 33–50.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lesthaeghe, R. (1995). The second demographic transition in Western countries: An interpretation. In K. O. Mason & A.-M. Jensen (Eds.), Gender and family change in industrialized countries (pp. 17–62). Oxford: Clarendon Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Lesthaeghe, R. (2010). The unfolding story of the second demographic transition. Population and Development Review, 36(2), 211–251.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Luci-Greulich, A., & Thévenon, O. (2013). The impact of family policies on fertility trends in developed countries. European Journal of Population, 29(4), 387–416.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Luci-Greulich, A., & Thévenon, O. (2014). Does economic advancement ‘cause’ a re-increase in fertility? An empirical analysis for OECD countries (1960–2007). European Journal of Population, 30(2), 187–221.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Maddison, A. (2007). The World Economy. Volume 1: A millennial perspective. Volume 2: Historical statistics. New Delhi: Academic Foundation.

    Google Scholar 

  • Malik, K. (2014). Human development report 2014. Sustaining human progress: Reducing vulnerabilities and building resilience. New York: United Nations Development Programme. http://hdr.undp.org/sites/default/files/hdr14-report-en-1.pdf.

  • Martínez, D. F., & Iza, A. (2004). Skill premium effects on fertility and female labor force supply. Journal of Population Economics, 17(1), 1–16.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • McDonald, P. (2000). Gender equity in theories of fertility transition. Population and Development Review, 26, 427–439.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • McNicoll, G. (1980). Institutional determinants of fertility change. Population and Development Review, 6(3), 441–462.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Miranda, A. (2008). Planned fertility and family background: A quantile regression for counts analysis. Journal of Population Economics, 21(1), 67–81.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Moultrie, T., Hosegood, V., McGrath, N., Hill, C., Herbst, K., & Newell, M. L. (2008). Refining the criteria for stalled fertility declines: An application to rural KwaZulu-Natal, South Africa, 1990–2005. Studies in Family Planning, 39(1), 39–48.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Myrskylä, M., Kohler, H. P., & Billari, F. C. (2009). Advances in development reverse fertility declines. Nature, 7256, 741–743.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Myrskylä, M., Kohler, H. P., & Billari, F. (2011). High development and fertility: fertility at older reproductive ages and gender equality explain the positive link. Population Studies Center Working Paper 11-06, University of Pennsylvania.

  • Schoumaker, B. (2009). Stalls in fertility transitions in sub-Saharan Africa: Real or spurious?. Louvain-la-Neuve: Département des sciences de la population et du développement, Université catholique de Louvain.

    Google Scholar 

  • Thévenon, O. (2011). Family policies in OECD countries: A comparative analysis. Population and Development Review, 37(1), 57–87.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Westoff, C. F., & Cross, A. R. (2006). The stall in the fertility transition in Kenya. DHS Analytical Studies No. 9. Calverton, Maryland: ORC Macro.

  • Westoff, C. F., & Potvin, R. H. (1967). College women and fertility values. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Wilcoxon, F. (1945). Individual comparisons by ranking methods. Biometrics, 1, 80–83.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • World Development Indicators (WDI). (2015). “WDI Database.” The World Bank. Accessed 19 June 2014.

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Maricruz Lacalle-Calderon.

Ethics declarations

Conflict of interest

The authors declare that they have no conflict of interest.

Appendices

Appendix 1

See Table 6.

Table 6 List of countries grouped by OECD (a) and income tertile

Appendix 2

See Tables 7 and 8.

Table 7 Fertility rate descriptive statistics by group analysed.
Table 8 GDP pc (in $ PPP 2005 at constant prices) descriptive statistics by group analysed.

Appendix 3

See Figs. 5 and 6.

Fig. 5
figure 5

Quantile regression for different models using the OECD sample (see Table 2). Vertical axes show coefficient estimates of \({\text{Log\_GDPpc}}_{it}\) and \({\text{Log\_GDPpc}}_{it}^{2}\) variables; horizontal axes depict the quantiles of the dependent variable. Quantile regression error bars correspond to bootstrapped 95 % confidence (400 bootstrap replications)

Fig. 6
figure 6

Quantile regression for different models using the third tertile of income sample (see Table 3). Vertical axes show coefficient estimates of \({\text{Log\_GDPpc}}_{it}\) and \({\text{Log\_GDPpc}}_{it}^{2}\) variables; horizontal axes depict the quantiles of the dependent variable). Quantile regression error bars correspond to bootstrapped 95 % confidence (400 bootstrap replications)

Appendix 4

See Tables 9 and 10.

Table 9 Interquantile regression
Table 10 Wilcoxon Signed-rank test for contrasting the equality of distributions of J-shape curves by quantiles (1).

The Wilcoxon Signed-rank test (W test) is a nonparametric test (which does not assume any probability distributions of the variables compared) useful for contrasting differences in the distribution of two variables (see Wilcoxon 1945). The null hypothesis is that both distributions are the same, which means that there are no differences in the behaviour of the variables compared, so there are no differences in the J-shape by fertility levels:

$$H^{0} :{\text{J-shape}} \left( {Q.n} \right) = {\text{J-shape}} \left( {Q.m} \right)$$
(4)

Table 10 presents the results of W test rejecting the null, thus confirming that the J-shape is different by levels of fertility.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Lacalle-Calderon, M., Perez-Trujillo, M. & Neira, I. Fertility and Economic Development: Quantile Regression Evidence on the Inverse J-shaped Pattern. Eur J Population 33, 1–31 (2017). https://doi.org/10.1007/s10680-016-9382-4

Download citation

  • Received:

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s10680-016-9382-4

Keywords

JEL Classification

Navigation