Skip to main content
Log in

The debt brake: business cycle and welfare consequences of Germany’s new fiscal policy rule

  • Original Paper
  • Published:
Empirica Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

In a New Keynesian DSGE model with non-Ricardian consumers, we show that automatic stabilization according to a countercyclical spending rule following the idea of the debt brake is well suited both to steer the economy and in terms of welfare. In particular, the adjustment account set up to record public deficits and surpluses serves well to keep the level of government debt stable. However, it is essential to design its feedback to government spending correctly, where discretionary lapses should be corrected faster than lapses due to estimation errors.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1
Fig. 2
Fig. 3
Fig. 4
Fig. 5
Fig. 6
Fig. 7
Fig. 8
Fig. 9
Fig. 10
Fig. 11

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. The German Economic Association (Verein für Socialpolitik) just recently devoted a special issue of its journal “Perspektiven der Wirtschaftspolitik” (in German) to the German debt brake. Therein, Feld (2010) and Korioth (2010) discuss the rationale and the effectiveness of the debt brake, Heinemann (2010) assesses its stabilizing effects, Ragnitz (2010) addresses the system of consolidation transfers to the Länder in order to be able to get the debt brake started in 2020, Renzsch (2010) assesses the (general) difficulty of incorporating such systems into federal countries and König et al. (2010) analyze the history of the evolution of the debt brake in the light of political economic arguments.

  2. Brunez (2003), Döpke (2006) and Kremer and Stegarescu (2008) provide evidence for estimation errors being an issue. Heinemann (2006) even suggests that politicians may have an incentive to misestimate.

References

  • Allsopp C, Vines D (2005) The macroeconomic role of fiscal policy. Oxf Rev Econ Policy 21:485–508

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Álvarez LJ, Emmanuel D, Hoeberichts M, Kwapil C, Le Bihan H, Lünnemann P, Martins F, Sabbatini R, Stahl H, Vermeulen P, Vilmunen J (2006) Sticky prices in the euro area: a summary of new micro evidence. J Eur Econ Assoc 4:575–584

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Artis MJ, Buti M (2000) Close to balance or in surplus’—a policy maker’s guide to the implementation of the stability and growth pact. J Common Mark Stud 38:563–592

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Baxter M, King RG (1993) Fiscal policy in general equilibrium. Am Econ Rev 83:315–334

    Google Scholar 

  • Benigno P, Woodford M (2003) Optimal monetary and fiscal policy: a linear-quadratic approach. NBER Macroecon Annu 18:271–333

    Google Scholar 

  • Bilbiie FO, Meier A, Müller GJ (2008) What accounts for the changes in US fiscal policy transmission? J Money Credit Bank 40:1139–1169

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Blanchard O, Perotti R (2002) An empirical characterization of the dynamic effects of changes in government spending and taxes on output. Quart J Econ 117:1329–1368

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bodmer F (2003) The Swiss debt brake: how it works and what can go wrong. Schweizerische Zeitschrift für Volkswirtschaft und Statistik 142(3):307–330

    Google Scholar 

  • Bohn H (1998) The behavior of US public debt and deficits. Quart J Econ 113:949–963

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Brunez PA (2003) A modification of the HP filter aiming at reducing the end-point bias. Eidgenössische Finanzverwaltung, Working Paper No. 18, Bern

  • Buti M, Roeger W, in’t Veld J (2001) Stabilizing output and inflation: policy conflicts and co-operation under a stability pact. J Common Mark Stud 39:801–821

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Calvo G (1983) Staggered prices in a utility-maximizing framework. J Monet Econ 12:383–398

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Chari VV, Kehoe P, McGrattan E (2007) Business cycle dynamics. Econometrica 75:781–836

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Coenen G, McAdam P, Straub R (2008) Tax reform and labour-market performance in the Euro area: a simulation-based analysis using the new area-wide model. J Econ Dyn Control 32:2543–2583

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Coenen G, Mohr M, Straub R (2008) Fiscal consolidation in the Euro area: long-run benefits and short-run costs. Econ Model 25:912–932

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Corsetti G, Kuester K, Meier A, Müller GJ (2010) Debt consolidation and fiscal stabilization of deep recessions. Am Econ Rev Paper Proc 100:41–45

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Corsetti G, Meier A, Müller GJ (2009) Fiscal stimulus with spending reversals. CEPR Discussion Paper Series, no. 7302

  • Danninger S (2002) The Swiss debt brake. IMF Working Paper, no. WP/02/18

  • Del Negro M, Schorfheide F, Smets F, Wouters R (2005) On the fit and forecasting performance of new Keynesian models. J Bus Econ Stat Lecture 25:123–43

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Erceg D, Henderson D, Levin A (2000) Optimal monetary policy with staggered wage and price contracts. J Monet Econ 46:281–313

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Eslava M (2010) The political economy of fiscal deficits: a survey. J Econ Surv, forthcoming

  • Fatas A, Mihov I (2001) The effects of fiscal policy on consumption and employment: theory and evidence. CEPR Discussion Paper, no. 2760

  • Feld LP (2010) Sinnhaftigkeit und Effektivität der deutschen Schuldenbremse. Perspektiven der Wirtschaftspolitik 11:226–245

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fragetta M, Kirsanova T (2007) Strategic monetary and fiscal policy interactions: an empirical investigation. University of Exeter, Mimeo, Exeter

    Google Scholar 

  • Gali J, Perotti R (2003) Fiscal policy and monetary integration in Europe. Econ Policy 37:533–572

    Google Scholar 

  • Gali J, Lopez-Salido D, Valles J (2004) Rule-of-thumb consumers and the design of interest rate rules. J Money Credit Bank 36(4):739–763

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gali J, Lopez-Salido D, Valles J (2007) Understanding the effects of government spending on consumption. J Eur Econ Assoc 5(1):227–270

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gali J, Monacelli T (2008) Optimal monetary and fiscal policy in a currency union. J Int Econ 76:116–132

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gerberding C, Seitz F, Worms A (2005) How the Bundesbank Really conducted monetary policy. North Am J Econ Finance 16:277–292

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • German Council of Economic Experts (2007) Staatsverschuldung wirksam begrenzen. Expertise im Auftrag des Bundesministers für Wirtschaft und Technologie, Elsevier Group, Reutlingen

  • Heinemann F (2006) Planning or propaganda? An evaluation of Germany’s medium-term budgetary planning. FinanzArchiv 62:551–578

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Heinemann F (2010) Eine Gabe an St. Nimmerlein?—Zur zeitlichen Dimension der Schuldenbremse. Perspektiven der Wirtschaftspolitik 11:246–259

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Heppke-Falk K, Tenhofen J, Wolff GB (2010) The macroeconomic effects of exogenous fiscal policy shocks in Germany: a disaggregated SVAR analysis. J Econ Stat (Jahrbuecher fuer Nationaloekonomie und Statistik) 230:328–355

    Google Scholar 

  • IMF (2008) World Economic Outlook: Financial Stress, Downturns, and Recoveries. International Monetary Fund, October 2008, Washington, DC

  • Kastrop C, Snelting M (2008) Das Modell des Bundesfinanzministeriums für eine neue Schuldenregel. Wirtschaftsdienst 88(6):375–382

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kirsanova T, Stehn SJ, Vines D (2005) The interactions between fiscal policy and monetary policy. Oxf Rev Econ Policy 21(4):532–564

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kirsanova T, Satchi M, Vines D (2007) Optimal fiscal policy rules in a monetary union. J Money Credit Bank 39(7):1759–1784

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kirsanova T, Wren-Lewis S (2007) Optimal fiscal feedback on debt in an economy with nominal rigidities. University of Exeter, Mimeo, Exeter

    Google Scholar 

  • König T, Luig B, Solomon SM (2010) Sachverständige und der Einfluss von Expertise auf Reformen: Eine räumliche Analyse der Föderal- ismusreform II. Perspektiven der Wirtschaftspolitik 11:307–323

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Korioth S (2010) Die neuen Schuldenbegrenzungsregeln für Bund und Länder—symbolische Verfassungsänderung oder gelungene Schuldenbrem-se? Perspektiven der Wirtschaftspolitik 11:270–287

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kremer J, Stegarescu D (2008) Eine strenge und mittelfristig stabilisierende Haushaltsregel. Wirtschaftsdienst 88(3):181–187

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Leith C, Wren-Lewis S (2007) Countercyclical fiscal policy: which instrument is best? Working paper, University of Glasgow, Department Working Papers, no. 2005/03, extended version of The Cost of Fiscal Inflexibility

  • Mayer E, Grimm O (2008) Countercyclical taxation and price dispersion. Würzburg economic papers no. 78, University of Würzburg, Würzburg

  • Mayer E, Stähler N (2009) The debt brake: business cycle and welfare consequences of Germany’s new fiscal policy rule. Deutsche Bundesbank discussion paper series 1: economic studies no. 24/2009, Deutsche Bundesbank

  • Müller C (2006) The Swiss Debt Brake—Lessons for EMU? Working Paper, ETH Zürich, Zürich

  • Orphanides A (2004) Monetary policy rules. Macroeconomic stability and inflation: a view from the trenches. J Money Credit Bank 36:151–157

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Perotti R (2005) Estimating the effects of fiscal policy in OECD Countries. CEPR discussion paper, no. 4842

  • Ragnitz J (2010) Föderalismusreform II: Zur Frage des Controlling der Konsolidierungshilfen. Perspektiven der Wirtschaftspolitik 11:260–269

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Renzsch W (2010) Kontinuitäten und Diskontinuitäten in Entscheidungs- prozessen über föderale Finanzbeziehungen oder: Die ewig Unvollendete. Perspektiven der Wirtschaftspolitik 11:288–306

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Rodriguez-Tejedo I (2006) Requirements and limits on state budgets. University of Maryland, Mimeo

    Google Scholar 

  • Schmitt-Grohé S, Uribe M (2003) Closing small open economy models. J Int Econ 61:163–185

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Schmitt-Grohé S, Uribe M (2007) Optimal simple and implementable monetary and fiscal rules. J Monet Econ 54:1702–1725

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Smets F, Wouters R (2003) An estimated stochastic dynamic general equilibrium model of the Euro area. J Eur Econ Assoc 1(5):1123–1175

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Smets F, Wouters R (2007) Shocks and frictions in US business cycles: a Bayesian DSGE approach. Am Econ Rev 97(3):586–606

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Solow RM (2005) Rethinking fiscal policy. Oxf Rev Econ Policy 21:509–514

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Straub R, Tchakarov I (2007) Assessing the impact of a change in the composition of public spending: a DSGE approach ECB, Working Paper No. 891

  • Stähler N (2009) Taxing deficits to restrain government spending. J Public Econ Theory 11:159–176

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Taylor JB (1993) Discretion versus policy rules in practice. In: Carnegie-Rochester conference series on public policy fiscal policy, vol 39, 14, pp 195–214

  • Taylor JB (2000) Reassessing discretionary fiscal policy. J Econ Perspect 14:21–36

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Velasco A (1999) A model of endogenous fiscal deficits and delayed fiscal reforms. In: Poterba J, Hagen J (eds) Fiscal institutions and fiscal performance. The University of Chicago Press, Chicago, pp 37–57

    Google Scholar 

  • Velasco A (2000) Debts and deficits with fragmented fiscal policy-making. J Public Econ 76:105–125

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Von Hagen J (1992) Budgeting procedures and fiscal performance in the European communities. economic papers, 96, European Commission, Brussels

  • Woo J (2005) Social polarization, fiscal instability and growth. Eur Econ Rev 49:1451–1477

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Woodford M (2003) Interest and prices: foundations of a theory of monetary policy. Princeton University Press, Princeton and Oxford

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgments

We would like to thank Antonio Afonso, Peter Bofinger, Johannes Clemens, Christina Gerberding, Jürgen Hamker, Heinz Herrmann, Jana Kremer, Thomas Laubach, David Schindler, Dan Stegarescu, Jürgen von Hagen, Karsten Wendorff, participants of the 9th Symposium on Public Economics in Granada, participants of the 9th Annual Meeting of the European Public Choice Society in Athens, participants of the 24th Congress of the European Economics Association in Barcelona as well as two anonymous referees for their helpful comments.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Nikolai Stähler.

Additional information

The opinions expressed in this paper do not necessarily reflect the opinions of the Deutsche Bundesbank or of its staff.

Electronic supplementary material

Below is the link to the electronic supplementary material.

PDF (100 KB)

Appendices

Appendix 1: How to set the feedback of the adjustment account

Assuming that the fundamental shocks (technology shocks (TS), shocks to consumer preferences (CPS), price mark-up shocks (PMS), monetary shocks (MS) and fiscal spending shocks (FS)) are orthogonal as standard in the literature, we can decompose the welfare loss function as a linear combination of the structural shocks, i.e \({{\mathbb{W}}_0(\rho)={\mathbb{W}}_0^{TS}(\rho)+ {\mathbb{W}}_0^{CPS}(\rho) +{\mathbb{W}}_0^{PMS}(\rho) +{\mathbb{W}}_0^{MS}(\rho)+{\mathbb{W}}_0^{FS}(\rho)}\), where all parameters are fixed at their baseline value except ρ. Then, we continue by calculating \({\mathbb{W}_0(\rho)}\), where ρ is defined over the following tuple [0.00, 0.05, 0.10, 0.15, 0.20]. While conducting this exercise we find that the welfare loss metric \({\mathbb{W}_0(\rho)}\) takes its lowest value for ρ = 0.05, which we take as our baseline value. A more sophisticated approach would be to find the globally optimal value for each fundamental shock by, for example, the MATLAB routine fmincon, which finds a constrained minimum of a scalar function, starting from an initial estimate. In Fig. 12, we report the outcome of such an exercise graphically. It suggests that, if ρ could be fine-tuned towards a specific shock, the value optimally differed with the shock. If movements in the adjustment account can be traced back to technology or price mark-up shocks, fiscal authorities are well advised not to correct fiscal expenditures to sharply in the following period. For the case of fiscal, monetary and consumer preference shocks, the recommendation is somewhat reversed. If fiscal authorities are the source of economic disturbance, the welfare metric reports evidence that a sharper correction in the following period is appropriate as the relative damage imposed on the consumer can be reduced by a factor of four compared to the case in which fiscal authorities only moderately respond to past lapses in expenditures. For the case of consumer preference and monetary shocks, the welfare metric can be reduced by 10% if fiscal authorities move from a very low feedback (ρ = 0.01) to a somewhat higher feedback (ρ = 0.05). To be in line with debt brakes actually implemented in Switzerland or which are planed to be implemented in Germany, we assume that the government has no technology at hand to find-tune the response of the adjustment account towards the specific shock and thus set to ρ = 0.05 for all shocks, which is—on average—the best response to movements in the adjustment account.

Fig. 12
figure 12

Optimal feedback coefficient for each shock

Appendix 2: Welfare approximation

We know that per-period utility of household j of type i is given by

$$ \left\{\underbrace{\zeta_t\left[(1-\chi)log\left(C_t^i(j)\right)+\chi log(G_t)\right]}_{=u^{i}}+\underbrace{\zeta_t\upsilon_t log\left(L_t^i(j)\right)}_{=V^{i}}\right\}, $$
(30)

where i = or (see also Eq. 6). In what follows, we will derive the second-order Taylor approximation of the consumption part of this equation (indicated by u i) and the leisure part (indicated by V i) separately for convenience. For consumption, we then get

$$ \begin{aligned} u^{i}_t&\approx\bar{u}^i+\bar{u}^i_{C^i}\left(C_t^i-\bar{C}^i\right) +{{1}\over {2}}\bar{u}^i_{C^iC^i}\left(C_t^i-\bar{C}^i\right)^2+ \bar{u}^i_{G}\left(G_t-\bar{G}\right) +{{1}\over {2}}\bar{u}^i_{GG}\left(G_t-\bar{G}\right)^2 \\ &\quad+\bar{u}^i_{C^i\zeta}\left(C_t^i-\bar{C}^i\right)\left(\zeta_t-\bar{\zeta}\right)+ \bar{u}^i_{G\zeta}\left(G_t-\bar{G}\right)\left(\zeta_t-\bar{\zeta}\right) \\ &=\bar{u}^i +(1-\chi)\frac{\left(C_t^i-\bar{C}^i\right)} {\bar{C}^i}-(1-\chi)\frac{1} {2}\frac{\left(C_t^i-\bar{C}^i\right)^2}{(\bar{C}^i)^2} +\chi\frac{\left(G_t-\bar{G}\right)}{\bar{G}}-\chi\frac{1} {2}\frac{\left(G_t-\bar{G}\right)^2}{\bar{G}^2}\\ &\quad+\frac{\left(\zeta_t-\bar{\zeta}\right)}{\bar{\zeta}} \left[(1+\chi)\frac{\left(C_t^i-\bar{C}^i\right)}{\bar{C}^i} +\chi\frac{\left(G_t-\bar{G}\right)}{\bar{G}}\right] \\ &=\bar{u}^i+(1+\hat{\zeta}_t)\left\{(1-\chi)\left[\frac{\hat{C}^i_t} {\gamma_i}-\frac{1}{2}\frac{(\hat{C}^i_t)^2}{\gamma_i^2}+ \frac{1}{2}\frac{(\hat{C}^i_t)^2}{\gamma_i^2}\right]+ \chi\left[\hat{G}_t-\frac{1}{2}(\hat{G}_t)^2+ \frac{1}{2}(\hat{G}_t)^2\right]\right\} \\ &=\bar{u}^i+(1+\hat{\zeta}_t)\left\{(1-\chi)\frac{\hat{C}^i_t}{\gamma_i}+ \chi\hat{G}_t\right\}, \end{aligned} $$
(31)

where we have used the fact that we defined \(\hat{C}^i_t=\frac{\left(C_t^i-\bar{C}^i\right)}{\bar{C}}\) earlier, used the definitions for \(\gamma_r=\frac{\upsilon}{1-\chi+\upsilon}\frac{1}{1-\bar{N}}\) and \(\gamma_o=\frac{1-\gamma_r\lambda}{1-\lambda}\), respectively, and made use of the commonly known fact that, for any variable X, it holds that \((X_t-\bar{X})\approx\bar{X}\left[\hat{X}_t+\frac{1} {2}\hat{X}_t^2\right]\) and \((X_t-\bar{X})^2\approx\frac{1}{2}\hat{X}_t^2\) when approximating second order. Furthermore, we have neglected the individual household parameter j for notational convenience and remembered that \(\bar{\zeta}=1\). In an analogous proceeding as before, for the disutility of labor (utility of leisure) this yields

$$ \begin{aligned} V^{i}_t&\approx\bar{V}^i+\bar{V}^i_{L^i} \left(L_t^i-\bar{L}^i\right)+\frac{1}{2}\bar{V}^i_{L^iL^i} \left(L_t^i-\bar{L}^i\right)^2 +\bar{V}^i_{L^i\zeta} \left(L_t^i-\bar{L}^i\right)\left(\zeta_t-\bar{\zeta}\right) \\ &=\bar{V}^i +\upsilon\frac{\left(L_t^i-\bar{L}^i\right)} {\bar{L}^i}-\upsilon\frac{1}{2}\frac{\left(L_t^i-\bar{L}^i\right)^2}{(\bar{L}^i)^2} +\upsilon\frac{\left(L_t^i-\bar{L}^i\right)\left(\zeta_t-1\right)} {\bar{L}^i}\\ &=\bar{V}^i+\upsilon\left\{ \left[\frac{\hat{L}^i_t}{\gamma_i}- \frac{1}{2}\frac{\left(\hat{L}^i_t\right)^2}{\gamma_i^2}+\frac{1}{2} \frac{\left(\hat{L}^i_t\right)^2}{\gamma_i}\right]\right\}+ \frac{\hat{L}^i_t}{\gamma_i}\left(\upsilon\hat{\zeta}_t\right) \\ &=\bar{V}^i+\left(1+\hat{\zeta}_t\right)\upsilon\frac{\hat{L}^i_t}{\gamma_i} =\bar{V}^i +(1+\hat{\zeta}_t)\upsilon\frac{\hat{L}^i_t}{\gamma_i}. \end{aligned} $$
(32)

Combining the utility of consumption and disutility of labor, we get for household j of type i = or that

$$ U^i_t(j)=\underbrace{\bar{u}^i(j)+\bar{V}^i(j)}_{\bar{U}^i}+ (1+\hat{\zeta}_t)\left\{(1-\chi)\frac{\hat{C}^i_t(j)}{\gamma_i}+ \chi\hat{G}_t\right\}+(1+\hat{\zeta}_t)\upsilon\frac{\hat{L}^i_t(j)}{\gamma_i}. $$
(33)

Noting that individuals of type r have a constant consumption pattern due to constant labor supply (see Eqs. 12 and 13), we know that \(\hat{C}^r_t(j)=\hat{C}^r_t\), where the latter is given by \(\hat{C}^r_t=\gamma_r\hat{C}_t+\varphi\gamma_r\hat{N}_t\). Due to the assumption of complete markets and state-contingent claims that can be purchased by households of type o, we know that \(\hat{C}^o_t(j)=\hat{C}^o_t\) (see Woodford 2003, chapter 2 for more details), where the latter is given by \(\hat{C}_t^o=\gamma_o\hat{C}_t- \frac{\lambda\gamma_r\varphi}{1-\lambda}\hat{N}_t.\) Unfortunately, this does not hold for the labor supply (i.e. leisure) except for households of type r. We will come back to this in a second. As we further know that a share λ of households is of type r, while the remainder, i.e. (1 − λ), is of type o, aggregate per-period utility can be expressed through the second-order Taylor approximation

$$ \begin{aligned} U_t&=\underbrace{\lambda\bar{U}^r+(1-\lambda)\bar{U}^o}_{=\bar{U}}+ (1+\hat{\zeta}_t)\left\{(1-\chi)\left[\lambda\frac{\hat{C}^r_t}{\gamma_r} +(1-\lambda)\frac{\hat{C}^o_t}{\gamma_o}\right] +\chi\hat{G}_t\right\} \\ & \quad +(1+\hat{\zeta}_t)\upsilon\left[\lambda \frac{\frac{1}{\lambda} \int_0^{\lambda}\hat{L}^r_t(j)dj}{\gamma_r} +(1-\lambda)\frac{\frac{1}{(1-\lambda)}\int_{\lambda}^1 \hat{L}^o_t(j)dj}{\gamma_o}\right] \end{aligned} $$
(34)

We can use the definition of the consumption aggregate and the labor aggregate, where it holds that

$$ \hat{L}_t=\lambda \frac{1}{\gamma_r}\hat{L}_t^r+(1-\lambda)\frac{1}{\gamma_o} \hat{L}_t^o\quad {\rm and} \quad\hat{C}_t=\lambda\frac{1}{\gamma_r} \hat{C}_t^r+(1-\lambda)\frac{1}{\gamma_o}\hat{C}_t^o, $$

where \(\hat{L}_t^i\) and \(\hat{C}_t^i\) denote the per capita log-deviations in the respective household segment. By definition, we know that \(C_t^r=\frac{1}{\lambda}\int_{0}^{\lambda}C_t^r(j)dj\) and, henceforth, \(\frac{1}{\gamma_r}\hat{C}_t^r=\frac{1}{\gamma_r} \frac{1}{\lambda} \int_{0}^{\lambda}\hat{C}_t^r(j)dj\). In complete analogy, we get \(\frac{1}{\gamma_r}\hat{L}_t^r=\frac{1}{\gamma_r} \frac{1}{\lambda} \int_{0}^{\lambda}\hat{L}_t^r(j)dj,\,\frac{1}{\gamma_o} \hat{C}_t^o= \frac{1}{\gamma_o} \frac{1}{(1-\lambda)} \int_{\lambda}^{1}\hat{C}_t^o(j)dj\) and \(\frac{1}{\gamma_o} \hat{L}_t^o=\frac{1}{\gamma_o} \frac{1}{(1-\lambda)} \int_{\lambda}^{1}\hat{L}_t^o(j)dj\). Substitution into Eq. 34 and rearranging gives

$$ U_t=\bar{U}+(1+\hat{\zeta}_t)\left[(1-\chi)\hat{C}_t+\chi\hat{G}_t\right] -(1+\hat{\zeta}_t)\upsilon \varphi\hat{N}_t, $$

where we have substituted leisure for labor through \(\hat{L}_t=-\frac{\bar{N}}{\bar{L}}\hat{N}_t =-\frac{\bar{N}}{1-\bar{N}}\hat{N}_t=-\varphi\hat{N}_t\). Further, we can use

$$ N_t=\int\limits_0^1N_t(j)dj=\int\limits_o^1\frac{Y_t(j)}{A_t}dj=\frac{Y_t}{A_t} \int\limits_0^1\frac{Y_t(j)}{Y_t}dj =\frac{Y_t}{A_t} \int\limits_0^1\left(\frac{P_t(j)}{P_t}\right)^{-\epsilon}dj $$

and log-linearize, which yields \(\hat{N}_t=\hat{Y}_t-\hat{A}_t+\hat{q}_t\), where \(\hat{q}_t={\rm log}\left(\int_0^1\left(\frac{P_t(j)}{P_t}\right)^{-\epsilon}dj\right)\). Using standard results as in Woodford (2003), we know that \(q_t=\left(\epsilon/2\right)\sigma^2_t\), where \(\sigma^2_t=\int_0^1\left[p_t(j)-p_t\right]^2dj\), in which the lower case letters p denote second-order log deviations. Substituting into the latest equation for the second-order Taylor approximation, we get

$$ U_t=\bar{U}+(1+\hat{\zeta}_t)\left[(1-\chi)\hat{C}_t+\chi\hat{G}_t\right] -(1+\hat{\zeta}_t)\upsilon \varphi\left[\hat{Y}_t-\hat{A}_t+\frac{\epsilon}{2}\sigma^2_t\right], $$

which can be simplified to

$$ U_t=\bar{U}+(1+\hat{\zeta}_t)\left[(1-\chi)\hat{C}_t+\chi\hat{G}_t\right] -(1+\hat{\zeta}_t)\upsilon \varphi\hat{Y}_t-\upsilon\varphi\frac{\epsilon}{2} \sigma^2_t+o\left(||a^3||\right)+t.i.p., $$
(35)

where terms of order three (such as \(\sigma_t^2\zeta_t^2\)) are collected in \(o\left(||a^3||\right)\), while terms independent of policy (such as \((1+\hat{\zeta}_t)\upsilon \varphi\hat{A}_t\)) have been put into t.i.p. Using the income identity \(\hat{Y}_t=\gamma_C\hat{C}_t+\gamma_G\hat{G}_t\) and the fact that χ = γ G  = (1 − γ C ) in the efficient steady state, we get

$$ U_t=\bar{U}+\left[1-\upsilon \varphi\right](1+\hat{\zeta}_t)\hat{Y}_t-\upsilon\varphi\frac{\epsilon}{2} \sigma^2_t+o\left(||a^3||\right)+t.i.p., $$
(36)

Noting that \(\hat{\zeta}_t\hat{Y}_t={{1}\over {2}}\left[\hat{\zeta}_t^2+\hat{Y}_t^2-(\hat{Y}_t-\hat{\zeta}_t)^2\right]\), we are able to rearrange this to

$$ U_t=\frac{(1-\upsilon\varphi)}{2}\left[(1+\hat{Y}_t)^2-(\hat{Y}_t- \hat{\zeta}_t)^2\right] -\upsilon\varphi\frac{\epsilon}{2} \sigma^2_t+o\left(||a^3||\right)+\overline{t.i.p.}, $$
(37)

where

$$ \overline{t.i.p.}=t.i.p.+\hat{\zeta}_t^2\frac{(1-\upsilon\varphi)}{2}- \frac{(1-\upsilon\varphi)}{2} $$

is the full set of variables independent of policy. Noting that \(\frac{1}{2}\sum\nolimits_{t=0}^{\infty}\beta^t\sigma_t^2=\frac{\epsilon}{\kappa} \sum\nolimits_{t=0}^{\infty}\beta^t\hat{\pi}_t^2\) (see Woodford 2003) and taking conditional expectations at date zero and neglecting al terms higher than second order, the discounted sum of utility streams can be written as Eq. 28.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Cite this article

Mayer, E., Stähler, N. The debt brake: business cycle and welfare consequences of Germany’s new fiscal policy rule. Empirica 40, 39–74 (2013). https://doi.org/10.1007/s10663-011-9177-0

Download citation

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s10663-011-9177-0

Keywords

JEL Classification

Navigation