Skip to main content

Advertisement

Log in

Deterrence works for criminals

  • Published:
European Journal of Law and Economics Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

Criminal law and economics rests on the expectation that deterrence incentives can be employed to reduce crime. Prison survey evidence however suggests that a majority of criminals are biased and may not react to deterrence incentives. This study employs an extra-laboratory experiment with criminals in a German prison to test the effectiveness of deterrence and compares it with data of student subjects. Subjects either face potential punishment when stealing, or they can steal without deterrence. We confirm Gary Becker’s deterrence hypothesis that deterrence works for criminals (and similarly for students). We observe significantly more risk-seeking criminals than students, although the vast majority (80.77 %) of criminals behaves risk-neutral or risk-averse.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1
Fig. 2
Fig. 3
Fig. 4
Fig. 5

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. In this paper we use the terms ‘inmate’, ‘prisoner’, and ‘criminal’ synonymously to describe the subjects drawn from the prison population of our study, assuming that the vast majority of prisoners were convicted rightfully. Cases of wrongfully convicted individuals nevertheless occur periodically, so that we do not intend to make any judgments about the guilt of any specific prisoner in our study.

  2. We acknowledge that men account for the majority of prisoners. Still current statistics report more than 625,000 female prisoners worldwide (Walmsley 2012). We therefore see no reason to disregard studies with prisoners on the grounds that the subjects are female.

  3. Note that Block and Gerety (1995) also analyze decision making under risk of prison inmates. Their auction experiment does not involve stealing.

  4. Note that either p or f needs to be increasing in h to avoid marginal deterrence issues (see Stigler 1970).

  5. Additionally, both players were endowed with 7 Taler (which were needed to rule out negative payoffs).

  6. In our experiment we observe decision making in a one-shot stealing game with only player 1, the criminal, making an active decision. Hence, we concentrate on distributional preferences and can neglect intention-based models, for instance on reciprocity (e.g. Dufwenberg and Kirchsteiger 2004).

  7. See Fig. 6 in Appendix 1 for point predictions of optimal stealing in DeterFine for a number of simple risk parameters using u α.

  8. Further information (in German) on the JVA für Frauen in Vechta: www.jva-fuer-frauen.niedersachsen.de.

  9. Despite our efforts to ensure credible anonymity, one may argue that some inmates may have acted in response to a demand effect. That is, some inmates may abstain from stealing as they believe that their actions will be traced. If this effect was present, it would work against finding a difference between NoDeter and DeterFine. Note that a decrease in stealing from NoDeter to DeterFine of the same subject cannot occur in our between-subject design.

  10. Figures 7, and 8 in Appendix 1 display the monitors used for the two treatments.

References

  • Abbink, K., Irlenbusch, B., & Renner, E. (2002). An experimental bribery game. Journal of Law Economics and Organization, 18, 428–454.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Anderson, D. A. (2002). The deterrence hypothesis and picking pockets at the pickpocket’s hanging. American Law and Economics Review, 4, 295–313.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bardsley, N. (2008). Dictator game giving: Altruism or artifact? Experimental Economics, 11, 122–133.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Becker, G. S. (1968). Crime and punishment: An economic approach. The Journal of Political Economy, 76, 169–217.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Birkeland, S., Cappelen, A. W., Sørensen, E. Ø., & Tungodden, B. (2014). An experimental study of prosocial motivation among criminals. Experimental Economics, 17, 501–511.

  • Block, M. K., & Gerety, V. E. (1995). Some experimental evidence on differences between student and prisoner reactions to monetary penalties and risk. Journal of Legal Studies, 24, 123–138.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bolton, G. E., & Ockenfels, A. (2000). ERC: A theory of equity, reciprocity, and competition. American Economic Review, 90, 166–193.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Brock, J. M., Lange, A., & Ozbay, E. Y. (2013). Dictating the risk: experimental evidence on giving in risky environments. American Economic Review, 103, 415–437.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cappelen, A., Konow, J., Sørensen, E. Ø., & Tungodden, B. (2013). Just luck: An experimental study of risk-taking and fairness. American Economic Review, 103, 1398–1413.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Chmura, T., Engel, C., Englerth, M., & Pitz, T. (2010). “At the mercy of the prisoner next door—using an experimental measure of selfishness as a criminological tool”. MPI Bonn 2010/27.

  • Cohn, A., Maréchal, M. A., & Noll, T. (2013). “Bad boys: The effect of criminal identity on dishonesty”. University of Zürich, Working Paper No. 132.

  • Corman, H., & Mocan, H. N. (2000). A time-series analysis of crime, deterrence, and drug abuse in New York City. The American Economic Review, 90, 584–604.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • DeAngelo, G., & Charness, G. (2012). Deterrence, expected cost, uncertainty and voting: Experimental evidence. Journal of Risk and Uncertainty, 44, 73–100.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dufwenberg, M., & Kirchsteiger, G. (2004). A theory of sequential reciprocity. Games and Economic Behavior, 47, 268–298.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fehr, E., & Schmidt, K. M. (1999). A theory of fairness, competition, and cooperation. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 114, 817–868.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fischbacher, U. (2007). Z-Tree: Zurich toolbox for ready-made economic experiments. Experimental Economics, 10, 171–178.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fisman, R., & Miguel, E. (2007). Corruption, norms, and legal enforcement: Evidence from diplomatic parking tickets. Journal of Political Economy, 115, 1020–1048.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gottfredson, M. R., & Hirschi, T. (1990). A general theory of crime. Stanford: Stanford University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Greiner, B. (2004). “An online recruitment system for economic experiments”. In K. Kremer and V. Macho (Eds.), Forschung und wissenschaftliches Rechnen 2003. GWDG Bericht 63, Göttingen: Ges. für Wiss. Datenverarbeitung, pp. 79–93.

  • Khadjavi, M. (forthcoming). “On the interaction of deterrence and emotions”. Journal of Law, Economics, and Organization.

  • Khadjavi, M., & Lange, A. (2013). Prisoners and their dilemma. Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization, 92, 163–175.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Levitt, S. D. (1997). Using electoral cycles and police hiring to estimate the effect of police on crime. The American Economic Review, 87, 270–290.

    Google Scholar 

  • Levitt, S. D. & Miles, T. J. (2007). “Empirical study of criminal punishment”. In A. M Polinsky and S. Shavell (Eds.), Handbook of Law and Economics (Vol. 1, Chap. 7) Amsterdam: Elsevier.

  • List, J. A. (2007). On the interpretation of giving in dictator games. Journal of Political Economy, 115, 482–493.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Nagin, D. S., & Pogarsky, G. (2003). An experimental investigation of deterrence: Cheating, self-serving bias, and impulsivity. Criminology, 41, 167–194.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Rizzolli, M., & Stanca, L. (2012). Judicial errors and crime deterrence: Theory and experimental evidence. Journal of Law and Economics, 55, 311–338.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Schildberg-Hörisch, H., & Strassmair, C. (2012). An experimental test of the deterrence hypothesis. Journal of Law Economics and Organization, 28, 447–459.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Stigler, G. J. (1970). The optimum enfocement of laws. Journal of Political Economy, 78, 526–536.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Walmsley, R. (2012). World female imprisonment list (2nd ed.). International Centre for Prison Studies, University of Essex.

Download references

Acknowledgments

I am grateful to the JVA für Frauen in Vechta and especially Petra Huckemeyer and Elsbeth Lübbe for their dedicated cooperation and to the Kriminologischer Dienst in Lower Saxony for its permission to conduct this study. Funding and guidance for this experiment was provided by the chair of Andreas Lange at the University of Hamburg. Sarah Mörtenhuber and Jan Papmeier provided excellent research assistance. I thank an anonymous referee for very helpful comments.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Menusch Khadjavi.

Appendices

Appendix 1: Complementary figures

See Figs. 6, 7, and 8.

Fig. 6
figure 6

Point predictions of optimal stealing (h) depending on risk preferences in DeterFine. Note the results were obtained by using mathematical software to solve our model with different alpha parameters of u α

Fig. 7
figure 7

Z-tree monitor in NoDeter (translated from German into English)

Fig. 8
figure 8

Z-tree monitor in DeterFine (translated from German into English)

Appendix 2: English translations of the instructions

General instructions for participants

Welcome to the study!

Thank you for participating in our study today. You will be able to earn a considerable amount of money. It is therefore important that you read these instructions carefully.

It is prohibited to communicate with other participants during the study. Should you have any questions please raise your hand and an instructor will come to answer them. If you violate this rule, we will have to exclude you from the study and from all payments.

During the experiment you will make decisions anonymously, other participants will not learn about your decisions.

In any case you will earn [Field: a pack of coffee or a pack of tobacco; Lab: 5 Euros] for participation in this experiment. The additional earnings depend on your decisions [Field: and will be paid to your phone account]. During the study your earnings will be calculated in Taler. At the end of the experiment your earned Taler will be converted into Euros at the following exchange rate:

$${\mathbf{1}} \, {\mathbf{Taler}} = {\mathbf{0}},{\mathbf{20}} \, {\mathbf{EUR}}.$$

The study consists of five independent tasks. Your decision in a task does not have any impact on the other tasks.

The instructions for the five tasks will be handed out one after another. You will first receive instructions for task 1 and then make your decision at the computer terminal. After this task 1 is done.

Thereafter you will receive instructions for task 2 and again make your decision at the computer terminal. This procedure continues until the end of the study. In the end we will also ask you to answer some general questions.

At the end of the study you will receive your payment. Your payment is the sum of payments from all five tasks. All earned Taler will be converted to Euros and paid to you [Field: in addition to a pack of coffee or tobacco]. Hence you will get.

$$\begin{gathered} {\text{Your total payment}} = \hfill \\ {\text{Your payment from task 1}},{ 2},{ 3},{\text{ 4 and 5}} + [Field: \, a \, pack \, of \, coffee \, or \, tobacco, \, Lab: \, 5 \, EUR] \hfill \\ \end{gathered}$$

All payments will be done separately, without any other participant being able to see what you have earned. Apart from the instructor nobody will know what you have earned.

Instructions for Task 1

[The Stealing Game, NoDeter Treatment:]

In task 1 you need to decide how many Taler to transfer between your account and the account of another participant who is randomly matched with you. You will not receive information on the identity of the other participant. Neither will the other participant receive information on your identity.

At the end of the experiment one half of the participants will be randomly selected to be person 1, the other half will be person 2. Your own decision will count if you are selected as person 1. If you are selected as person 2, you will receive your payment in accordance with the decision of a person 1 who is matched with you.

There are 9 Taler in your account while the account of the other person holds 17 Taler.

You are able to decide freely how many Taler you would like to transfer between the account of the other person and your own account. That is, you are able to transfer up to 2 Taler from your account to the account of the other person (transfer “-2″) or up to 10 Taler from the account of the other person to your account (transfer “10”).

For example, if you decide to transfer -2 Taler, you will receive 7 Taler in this task while the person who is matched with you will receive 19 Taler. If you decide to transfer 7 Taler, then you will receive 16 Taler in this task and the matched person will receive 10 Taler.

In summary, your transfer between the account of the other person and your own account may be between “-2” and “10”.

Please make a decision on the screen to decide how many Taler to transfer to your account from the account of person 2.

Instructions for Task 1

[The Stealing Game, DeterFine Treatment:]

In task 1 you need to decide how many Taler to transfer between your account and the account of another participant who is randomly matched with you. You will not receive information on the identity of the other participant. Neither will the other participant receive information on your identity.

At the end of the experiment one half of the participants will be randomly selected to be person 1, the other half will be person 2. Your own decision will count if you are selected as person 1. If you are selected as person 2, you will receive your payment in accordance with the decision of a person 1 who is matched with you.

There are 9 Taler in your account while the account of the other person holds 17 Taler.

You are able to decide freely how many Taler you would like to transfer between the account of the other person and your own account. That is, you are able to transfer up to 2 Taler from your account to the account of the other person (transfer “-2”) or up to 10 Taler from the account of the other person to your account (transfer “10”).

If you decide to transfer Taler from the account of the other person to your own account, this transfer will only be successful half of the times, i.e. the probability of success is 50 %. If the transfer is not successful, you will have to pay a fee that is shown on your screen.

For example, if you decide to transfer -2 Taler, you will receive 7 Taler in this task while the person who is matched with you will receive 19 Taler. If you decide to transfer 7 Taler and your transfer is successful, then you will receive 16 Taler in this task and the matched person will receive 10 Taler. If your transfer is not successful, then you will receive the initial 9 Taler minus the fee and the person who is matched with you keeps 17 Taler.

In summary, your transfer between the account of the other person and your own account may be between “-2” and “10”.

Please make a decision on the screen to decide how many Taler to transfer to your account from the account of person 2. Mind the respective fee in case your transfer is not successful.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Khadjavi, M. Deterrence works for criminals. Eur J Law Econ 46, 165–178 (2018). https://doi.org/10.1007/s10657-015-9483-2

Download citation

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s10657-015-9483-2

Keywords

JEL Classification

Navigation