Skip to main content
Log in

Political entrepreneurship and the formation of special districts

  • Published:
European Journal of Law and Economics Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

Where general purpose governments provide a bundle of services within their boundaries, special district governments provide specific services inside the boundaries of general purpose governments. The alternative to forming a special purpose government is providing the service within a general purpose government. Formation of a special district represents the establishment of a new political enterprise, in contrast to the addition of a new product line to an existing government. We explore the formation of special districts as a particular form of the universal entrepreneurial search for gain or profit from exchange. Political entrepreneurship, like market entrepreneurship, operates inside some framework of rules, and the formation of special districts reflects the search for political gain within that framework of rules. We use an entrepreneurial framework to formulate several hypotheses concerning the formation and organization of special districts.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. There were also 14,561 school districts, which is also a type of special purpose government though this type is usually placed in a distinct category of government.

  2. As based on our calculations from data in US Bureau of the Census (2007).

References

  • Austin, A. D. (1998). A positive model of special district formation. Regional Science and Urban Economics, 28, 103–122.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Auteri, M., & Wagner, R. E. (2007). The organizational architecture of nonprofit governance. Public Organization Review, 7, 57–68.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Axelrod, D. (1992). Shadow government: The hidden world of public authorities. New York: Wiley.

    Google Scholar 

  • Backhaus, J. G. (1994). Assessing the performance of public enterprises: A public-choice approach. European Journal of Law and Economics, 1, 275–287.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bollens, S. A. (1986). Examining the link between state policy and the creation of local special districts. State and Local Government Review, 18, 117–124.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bowler, S., & Donovan, T. (2004). Evolution in state governance structures: Unintended consequences of state tax and expenditure limitations. Political Research Quarterly, 59, 189–196.

    Google Scholar 

  • Buchanan, J. M. (1963). The economics of earmarked taxes. Journal of Political Economy, 71, 457–469.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Carr, J. B. (2006). Local government autonomy and state reliance on special district governments: A reassessment. Political Research Quarterly, 59, 481–492.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • DiLorenzo, T. J. (1981). The expenditure effects of restricting competition in local public service industries: The case of special districts. Public Choice, 37, 569–578.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Epstein, R. A. (1995). Simple rules for a complex world. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Feiock, R. C., & Carr, J. B. (2001). Incentives, entrepreneurs, and boundary change: A collective action framework. Urban Affairs Review, 36, 382–405.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Foster, K. A. (1997). The political economy of special-purpose government. Washington D.C.: Georgetown University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Frey, B. S., & Eichenberger, R. (1996). FOCJ: Competitive governments for Europe. International Review of Law and Economics, 16, 315–327.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Garrido, E. N. (2007). Inter-municipal cooperation in Spain: Dealing with microscopic local government. In R. Hulst & A. van Montfort (Eds.), Inter-municipal cooperation in Europe (pp. 169–192). Dordrecht: Springer.

    Chapter  Google Scholar 

  • Goetz, C. J. (1968). Earmarked taxes and majority rule budgetary processes. American Economic Review, 58, 128–136.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hooghe, L., & Marks, G. (2003). Unraveling the central state, but how? Types of multi-level governance. The American Political Science Review, 97, 233–243.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hulst, R., & van Montfort, A. (2007). Inter-municipal cooperation in Europe. Dordrecht: Springer.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Kirzner, I. (1979). Perception, opportunity, and profit. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Kornai, J. (1986). The soft budget constraint. Kyklos, 39, 3–30.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kornai, J. (1998). The place of the soft budget constraint syndrome in economic theory. Journal of Comparative Economics, 26, 11–17.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lewis, E. (1980). Public entrepreneurship: Toward a theory of bureaucratic power. Bloomington: Indiana University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Lewis, P. G. (2000). The durability of local government structure: Evidence from California. State and Local Government Review, 32, 34–48.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • MacManus, S. A. (1981). Special district governments: A note on their use as property tax relief mechanisms in the 1970s. Journal of Politics, 43, 1206–1214.

    Google Scholar 

  • McCabe, B. C. (2000). Special-district formation among states. State and Local Government Review, 32, 121–131.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mullins, D. R. (2004). Tax and expenditure limitations and the fiscal response of local government: Asymmetric intra-local fiscal effects. Public Budgeting & Finance, 24, 111–147.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Nelson, R. H., McKenzie, K. R., & Norcross, E. (2008). Lessons from business improvement districts. Arlington, Va: Mercatus Center, Policy Primer No. 5.

  • Niskanen, W. A. (1971). Bureaucracy and representative government. Chicago: Aldine.

    Google Scholar 

  • Osborne, D., & Gaebler, T. (1992). Reinventing government: How the entrepreneurial spirit is transforming the public sector. Reading, MA: Addison-Wesley.

    Google Scholar 

  • Ostrom, V., Tiebout, C. M., & Warren, R. (1961). The organization of government in metropolitan areas: A theoretical inquiry. The American Political Science Review, 55, 831–842.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Pauly, M. V., & Redisch, M. R. (1973). The not-for-profit hospital as a physicians’ cooperative. American Economic Review, 63, 87–99.

    Google Scholar 

  • Riker, W. (1962). The theory of political coalitions. New Haven, CT: Yale University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Romano, R. (1985). Law as a product: Some pieces of the incorporation puzzle. Journal of Law, Economics, and Organization, 1, 225–283.

    Google Scholar 

  • Ruiter, D. W. P. (2005). Is transaction cost economics applicable to public governance? European Journal of Law and Economics, 29, 287–303.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Schelling, T. C. (1978). Micromotives and macrobehavior. New York: Norton.

    Google Scholar 

  • Schneider, M., & Teske, P. (1995). Public entrepreneurs: Agents for change in American Government. Princeton: Princeton University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Shadbegian, R. (1999). The effect of tax and expenditure limitations on the revenue structure of local government, 1862–1987. National Tax Journal, 52, 221–237.

    Google Scholar 

  • US Bureau of the Census. (1992). Census of Governments (Vol. 1, No. 1).

  • US Bureau of the Census. (2002). Census of Governments (Vol. 1, No. 1).

  • US Bureau of the Census. (2007). Census of Governments. http://www.census.gov/govs/cog/GovOrgTab03ss.html, Accessed March 28, 2010.

  • Wagner, R. E. (2007). Fiscal sociology and the theory of public finance. Cheltenham, UK: Edward Elgar.

    Google Scholar 

  • Wagner, R. E., & Weber, W. E. (1975). Competition, monopoly, and the organization of government in metropolitan areas. Journal of Law and Economics, 18(3), 661–684.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Wald, J. K., & Long, M. S. (2007). The effect of state laws on capital structure. Journal of Financial Economics, 83, 297–319.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Williamson, O. E. (1985). The economic institutions of capitalism. New York: Free Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Williamson, O. E. (1996). The mechanisms of governance. New York: Oxford University Press.

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgments

We are grateful to the participants of the Public Choice Society Meetings 2010 in Monterey, CA, and two anonymous referees for helpful suggestions.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Richard E. Wagner.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Cite this article

Fink, A., Wagner, R.E. Political entrepreneurship and the formation of special districts. Eur J Law Econ 35, 427–439 (2013). https://doi.org/10.1007/s10657-010-9216-5

Download citation

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s10657-010-9216-5

Keywords

JEL Classification

Navigation