Skip to main content

Advertisement

Log in

Optimal environment-friendly economic restructuring: the United States–China cooperation case study

  • Published:
Economic Change and Restructuring Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

This paper discusses a model for the restructuring of national economies for the purpose of achieving optimal growth under conditions of decreased energy consumption and greenhouse gas emissions. The discussion combines input–output and factorial-decomposition models, and applies projected gradient and factor analysis to find the optimal structural changes that serve all three goals. A comparative analysis of the economies of the United States and China, including opportunities for cooperative restructuring, serves as a case study.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1

Similar content being viewed by others

References

  • Albert A (1972) Regression and Moore–Penrose pseudoinverse. Academic Press, New York

    Google Scholar 

  • Albiman M, Suleiman N, Baka H (2015) The relationship between energy consumption, CO2 emissions and economic growth in Tanzania. Int J Energy Sect Manag 9(3):361–375

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Arazmuradov A (2016) Economic prospect on carbon emissions in Commonwealth of Independent States. Econ Change Restruct 49(4):395–427

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Asif M, Sharma RB, Adow AHE (2015) An empirical investigation of the relationship between economic growth, urbanization, energy consumption, and CO2 emission in GCC countries: a panel data analysis. Asian Soc Sci 11(21):270–284

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ayres R, Kneese A (1969) Production, consumption and externalities. Am Econ Rev 59(3):282–297

    Google Scholar 

  • Bastola U, Sapkota P (2015) Relationships among energy consumption, pollution emission, and economic growth in Nepal. Energy 80:254–262

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bertsekas D (1976) On the Goldstein–Levitin–Polyak gradient projection method. IEEE Trans Autom Control 21(2):174–184

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Brissimis S, Hondroyiannis G, Papazoglou C, Tsaveas N, Vasardani M (2012) Current account determinants and external sustainability in periods of structural change. Econ Change Restruct 45(2):71–95

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Brizga J, Feng K, Hubacek K (2014) Drivers of greenhouse gas emissions in the Baltic States: a structural decomposition analysis. Ecol Econ 98:22–28

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Brown M, Cohen M, Sweeney S (2009) Predicting national sustainability: the convergence of energetic, economic and environmental realities. Ecol Model 220:3424–3438

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bullard C, Penner P, Pilati D (1978) Energy analysis handbook. Resour Energy 1:267–313

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Butnar I, Llop M (2011) Structural decomposition analysis and input-output subsystems: changes in CO2 emissions of Spanish service sectors (2000–2005). Ecol Econ 70(11):2012–2019

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Calamai P, More J (1987) Projected gradient methods for linearly constrained problems. Math Program 39:93–116

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cellura M, Di Gangi A, Longo S, Orioli A (2013) An Italian input–output model for the assessment of energy and environmental benefits arising from retrofit actions of buildings. Energy Build 62:97–106

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Chang C (2010) A multivariate causality test of carbon dioxide emissions, energy consumption and economic growth in China. Appl Energy 87:3533–3537

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Chontanawat J, Hunt LC, Pierse R (2008) Does energy consumption cause economic growth?: evidence from a systematic study of over 100 countries. J Policy Model 30:209–220

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Diewert W, Nakamura A (eds) (1993) Essays in index number theory. Elsevier Science Publishers, New York

    Google Scholar 

  • Divisia F (1925) L’indice Monetaire et la Theorie de la Monnaie. Revue d’Economic Politique 39(5):980–1020 (In French)

    Google Scholar 

  • Duan H-B, Zhu L, Fan Y (2014) Optimal carbon taxes in carbon-constrained China: a logistic-induced energy economic hybrid model. Energy 69:345–356

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Eckelman M, Ciacci L, Kavlak G, Nuss P, Reck B, Graedel T (2014) Life cycle carbon benefits of aerospace alloy recycling. J Clean Prod 80:38–45

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fan G, He L, Wei X, Han L (2013) China’s growth adjustment: moderation and structural changes. Econ Change Restruct 46(1):9–24

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fan J, Wang Q, Sun W (2015) The failure of China’s energy development strategy 2050 and its impact on carbon emissions. Renew Sustain Energy Rev 49(4351):1160–1170

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Flaschel P (1982) Input–output technology assumptions and the energy requirements of commodities. Resour Energy 4:359–389

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ghosh A (1964) Experiments with input–output models. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge

    Google Scholar 

  • Gokhberg L, Roud V (2016) Structural changes in the national innovation system: longitudinal study of innovation modes in the Russian industry. Econ Change Restruct 49(2–3):269–288

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Goldstein A (1964) Convex programming in Hilbert space. Bull Am Math Soc 70:709–710

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gossling S, Scott D, Hall CM (2015) Inter-market variability in CO2 emission-intensities in tourism: implications for destination marketing and carbon management. Tour Manag 46:203–212

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Grana Drummond L, Iusem A (2004) A projected gradient method for vector optimization problems. Comput Optim Appl 28:5–29

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Griffin J (1976) Energy input–output modeling. Electric power research institute, Palo Alto

    Google Scholar 

  • Guan D, Hubacek K, Weber C, Peters G, Reiner D (2008) The drivers of Chinese CO2 emissions from 1980 to 2030. Glob Environ Change 18:626–634

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hanak D, Anthony E, Manovic V (2015) A review of developments in pilot-plant testing and modelling of calcium looping process for CO2 capture from power generation systems. Energy Environ Sci 8(8):2199–2249

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Haseeb M, Azam M (2015) Energy consumption, economic growth and CO2 emission nexus in Pakistan. Asian J Appl Sci 8(1):27–36

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hu H, Zhang X, Lin L (2014) The interactions between China’s economic growth, energy production and consumption and the related air emissions during 2000–2011. Ecol Ind 46:38–51

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • IEA (2014) World Energy Outlook 2014. International Energy Agency. Available at http://www.worldenergyoutlook.org/publications/weo-2014/

  • IPCC (2014) Summary for policymakers. In: Edenhofer O, Pichs-Madruga R, Sokona Y, Farahani E, Kadner S, Seyboth K, Adler A, Baum I, Brunner S, Eickemeier P, Kriemann B, Savolainen J, Schlomer S, von Stechow C, Zwickel T, Minx JC (eds) Climate change 2014: mitigation of climate change. Contribution of working group III to the fifth assessment report of the intergovernmental panel on climate change. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge

    Google Scholar 

  • Isa Z, Al Sayed A, Kun S (2015) Detect the relationship among energy consumption, economic growth and greenhouse gases by panel data approach. Appl Math Sci 9(53–56):2645–2656

    Google Scholar 

  • Jammazi R, Aloui C (2015) On the interplay between energy consumption, economic growth and CO2 emission nexus in the GCC countries: a comparative analysis through wavelet approaches. Renew Sustain Energy Rev 51(4676):1737–1751

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Jebli MB, Youssef SB (2015) Output, renewable and non-renewable energy consumption and international trade: evidence from a panel of 69 countries. Renew Energy 83:799–808

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Joo Y-J, Kim CS, Yoo S-H (2015) Energy consumption, CO2 emission, and economic growth: evidence from Chile. Int J Green Energy 12(5):543–550

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kaplan W (1993) Advanced calculus, 4th edn. Addison-Wesley, New York

    Google Scholar 

  • Kasman A, Duman Y (2015) CO2 emissions, economic growth, energy consumption, trade and urbanization in new EU member and candidate countries: a panel data analysis. Econ Model 44:97–103

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kaya Y (1990) Impact of carbon dioxide emission control on GNP growth: interpretation of proposed scenarios. Paper presented to the IPCC Energy and Industry Subgroup, Response Strategies Working Group, Paris, mimeo

  • Kumar R, Stauvermann P, Patel A (2015) Nexus between electricity consumption and economic growth: a study of Gibraltar. Econ Change Restruct 48(2):119–135

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Laspeyres E (1871) Die Berechnung einer mittleren Waarenpreissteigerung. Jahrbücher für Nationalökonomie und Statistik 16:296–315 (In German)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Leontief W (1941) The structure of the American economy, 1919–1939: an empirical application of equilibrium analysis. Harvard University Press, Cambridge

    Google Scholar 

  • Leontief W (1986) Input–output economics, 2nd edn. Oxford University Press, New York

    Google Scholar 

  • Levitin E, Polyak B (1966) Constrained minimization methods. USSR Comput Math Math Phys 6:1–50

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lin B, Liu X (2012) Dilemma between economic development and energy, conservation: energy rebound effect in China. Energy 45:867–873

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lin B, Liu H (2015) CO2 emissions of China’s commercial and residential buildings: evidence and reduction policy. Build Environ 92:418–431

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Liu Y, Zhou Y, Wu W (2015) Assessing the impact of population, income and technology on energy consumption and industrial pollutant emissions in China. Appl Energy 155:904–917

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Long X, Naminse EY, Du J, Zhuang J (2015) Nonrenewable energy, renewable energy, carbon dioxide emissions and economic growth in China from 1952 to 2012. Renew Sustain Energy Rev 52:680–688

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lozano S, Gutierez E (2008) Non-parametric frontier approach to modelling the relationships among population, GDP, energy consumption and CO2 emissions. Ecol Econ 66:687–699

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Madsen H, Sogaard E, Muff J (2015) Reduction in energy consumption of electrochemical pesticide degradation through combination with membrane filtration. Chem Eng J 276:358–364

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Maital S, Vaninsky A (1999) Data envelopment analysis with a single DMU: a graphic projected-gradient approach. Eur J Oper Res 115(3):518–528

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Maital S, Vaninsky A (2000) Productivity paradoxes and their resolution. J Prod Anal 14(3):191–207

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mallol-Poyato R, Salcedo-Sanz S, Jimenez-Fernandez S, Diaz-Villar P (2015) Optimal discharge scheduling of energy storage systems in MicroGrids based on hyper-heuristics. Renew Energy 83:13–24

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Meerovich V (1974) Turnover of financial funds and efficiency of production (Oborot Sredstv i Effektivnost’ Proizvodstva). Financy, Moscow (In Russian)

    Google Scholar 

  • Miller R, Blair P (2009) Input–output analysis: foundations and extensions. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Mudakkar S, Zaman K, Khan M, Ahmad M (2013) Energy for economic growth, industrialization, environment, and natural resources: living with just enough. Renew Sustain Energy Rev 25:580–595

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Oliveira C, Antunes C (2004) A multiple objective model to deal with economy–energy–environment interactions. Eur J Oper Res 153(2):370–385

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Paasche H (1874) Über die Preisentwicklung der letzten Jahre nach den Hamburger Börsennotirungen. Jahrbücher für Nationalökonomie und Statistik 23:168–178 (In German)

    Google Scholar 

  • Perez-Suarez R, Lopez-Menendez A (2015) Growing green? Forecasting CO2 emissions with environmental Kuznets curves and logistic growth models. Environ Sci Policy 54:428–437

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Polak E (1997) Optimization: algorithms and consistent approximations. Springer, New York

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Rosen J (1960) The gradient projection method for nonlinear programming. Part 1. Linear constraints. J Soc Ind Appl Math 8(1):181–217

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Rosen J (1961) The gradient projection method for nonlinear programming. Part II. Nonlinear constraints. J Soc Ind Appl Math 9(4):514–532

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Shahbaz M, Khan S, Tahir M (2013) The dynamic links between energy consumption, economic growth, financial development and trade in China: fresh evidence from multivariate framework analysis. Energy Econ 40:8–21

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Sheremet A (ed) (1979) Economic analysis of business activity (Ekonomicheskii analiz khozyaistvennoi deyatel’nosti). Economika, Moscow (In Russian)

    Google Scholar 

  • Sheremet A, Dei G, Shapovalov V (1971) The method of the chain substitutions and development of the factorial analysis of the economic indicators (Metod tsepnykh podstanovok i sovershenstvovanie faktornogo analiza ekonomicheskikh pokazatelei). Vestnik Moskovskogo Universiteta, Ser. Ekonomika 4:62–69 (In Russian)

    Google Scholar 

  • Smith A, Brown M (2015) Demand response: a carbon-neutral resource? Energy 85:10–22

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Solomon S, Qin D, Manning M, Chen Z, Marquis M, Averyt K, Tignor M, Miller H (eds) (2007) Contribution of working group I to the fourth assessment report of the intergovernmental panel on climate change, Cambridge, United Kingdom and New York, NY, USA

  • Song M, Wang S, Yu H, Yang L, Wu J (2011) To reduce energy consumption and to maintain rapid economic growth: analysis of the condition in China based on expended IPAT model. Renew Sustain Energy Rev 15:5129–5134

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Spiegel M, Stephens L (2014) Statistics Schaum’s outline series, 5th edn. McGraw-Hill, New York

    Google Scholar 

  • Spiegel M, Lipschutz S, Spellman D (2009) Vector analysis and an introduction to tensor analysis. Schaum’s outline series, 2nd edn. McGraw-Hill, New York

    Google Scholar 

  • Springmann M, Zhang D, Karplus V (2015) Consumption-based adjustment of emissions-intensity targets: an economic analysis for China’s provinces. Environ Resour Econ 61(4):615–640

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Su B, Ang B (2013) Input–output analysis of CO2 emissions embodied in trade: competitive versus noncompetitive imports. Energy Policy 56:83–87

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Suh S (ed) (2009) Handbook of input–output economics in industrial ecology. Springer, Dordrecht

    Google Scholar 

  • Thompson B (2004) Exploratory and confirmatory factor analysis: understanding concepts and applications. American Psychological Association, Washington

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Thornley P, Gilbert P, Shackley S, Hammond J (2015) Maximizing the greenhouse gas reductions from biomass: the role of life cycle assessment. Biomass Bioenergy 81:35–43

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Timmer M (ed) (2012) The world input–output database (WIOD): contents, sources and methods. WIOD Working Paper Number 10. Available at http://www.wiod.org/publications/papers/wiod10.pdf

  • Trzaski A, Rucinska J (2015) Energy labeling of windows—possibilities and limitations. Sol Energy 120:158–174

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ukidwe N, Bakshi B (2007) Industrial and ecological cumulative energy consumption of the United States via the 1997 input–output benchmark model. Energy 32(9):1560–1592

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Vaninsky A (1983) An extension of the integral method of economic analysis to the analysis of interrelated and derivative factors. Avtomatika i Telemekhanika 8:130–141. Available at http://www.mathnet.ru/php/archive.phtml?wshow=paper&jrnid=at&paperid=5200&option_lang=eng (In Russian). English translation is available in Automation and Remote Control, 1984, 44, 8(2), 1074–1083

  • Vaninsky A (1987) Factorial analysis of economic activity (Factornyi Analiz Khozyaistvennoi Deyatel’nosti). Financy i Statistika, Moskva (In Russian)

    Google Scholar 

  • Vaninsky A (2006) Computational method of finding optimal structural change in economic systems: an input–output projected-gradient approach. J Interdiscip Math 9(1):61–76

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Vaninsky A (2009) Structural change optimization in input–output models. J Interdiscip Math 12(6):839–861

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Vaninsky A (2014a) Factorial decomposition of CO2 emissions: a generalized Divisia index approach. Energy Econ 45:389–400

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Vaninsky A (2014b) Optimal economic restructuring aimed at an optimal increase in GDP constrained by a decrease in energy consumption and CO2 emissions. World Academy of Science, Engineering and Technology: International Science Index, 8(6), paper 18. Available at http://www.waset.org/Publications/?path=Publications

  • Vaninsky A, Meerovich V (1978) Problems of the methodology of analysis of the impact of structural change on the indicators of production efficiency (Voprosy metodologii analiza vliyaniya strukturnykh sdvigov na pokazateli effectivnosti proizvodstva). In: Proceedings of the national scientific conference “Economic leverages of the efficiency of using material, labor, finance, and natural resources”, vol 2. Central Economic—Mathematical Institute, Moskva, pp 105–107. (In Russian)

  • Wang Y, Zhao H, Li L, Liu Z, Liang S (2013) Carbon dioxide emission drivers for a typical metropolis using input–output structural decomposition analysis. Energy Policy 58:312–318

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Whittle R, Ellis R, Marshall I, Alcock P, Hutchison D, Mauthe A (2015) From responsibility to accountability: working creatively with distributed agency in office energy metering and management. Energy Res Soc Sci 10:240–249

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Yuan X, Li L, Gou H, Dong T (2015) Energy and environmental impact of battery electric vehicle range in China. Appl Energy 157:75–84

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Zhang H, Lahr M (2014) Can the carbonizing dragon be domesticated? Insights from a decomposition of energy consumption and intensity in china, 1987–2007. Econ Syst Res 26(2):119–140

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Zhang X, Hu H, Zhang R, Deng S (2014) Interactions between China’s economy, energy and the air emissions and their policy implications. Renew Sustain Energy Rev 38:624–638

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Zhang Z, Chen X, Heck P, Xue B, Liu Y (2015) Empirical study on the environmental pressure versus economic growth in China during 1991–2012. Resour Conserv Recycl 101:182–193

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Alexander Vaninsky.

Appendix

Appendix

In this section, we briefly describe the mathematical tools used to construct the model presented in this paper.

1.1 Factorial decomposition

The technique of factorial decomposition may be traced back to the works of Divisia (1925), Laspeyres (1871), Meerovich (1974), Paasche (1874), Sheremet (1979), and Sheremet et al. (1971).

Laspeyres (1871) and Paasche (1874) introduced a method of estimating the impacts of the factors on the change in the value of the resultant economic indicator. They assumed that a resultant indicator z is a product of the ordered set of factorial indicators x 1 , x 2 , …, x n :

$$ z = x_{1} x_{2} \ldots x_{n} $$
(21)

and suggested decomposing the change in the value of z by the factors x i by changing the factors in the order of their lower indexes:

$$ \begin{aligned} & \Delta z = \Delta z\left[ {x_{1} } \right] + \Delta z\left[ {x_{2} } \right] + \cdots + \Delta z\left[ {x_{n} } \right], \\ & \Delta z\left[ {x_{i} } \right] = (x_{11} x_{21} \ldots x_{i1} x_{{\left( {i + 1} \right)0}} , \ldots ,x_{n0} ) - (x_{11} x_{21} \ldots ,x_{i1} x_{{\left( {i + 1} \right)0}} , \ldots ,x_{n0} ) \\ \end{aligned} $$
(22)

where ∆z and ∆z[x i ] stand for the change in the resultant indicator z and its components caused by the change in the factorial indicators x i , respectively, and x i0 and x i1 are the values of the indicator x i in the base and current periods, correspondingly. As follows from the formula (22), at each step only one factor x i changes. This approach was further developed in the Index Number Theory (see, for example, Diewert and Nakamura 1993).

Divisia (1925) assumed continuous change in the factorial indicators in time: x i  = x i (t), thus avoiding the necessity of ordering them. The following factorial decomposition was obtained:

$$ \Delta z = \varSigma \Delta z[x_{i} ] = {\varvec{\Sigma}}\smallint x_{1} x_{2} \ldots x_{i - 1} x_{i} ' x_{i + 1} \ldots x_{n} dt, $$
(23)

where the symbol Σ stands for the summation, the symbol stands for the integration, and the factors x i in the integrand of the formula (23) are substituted term wise for their derivatives x i . Integration is done with respect to the model time t over the interval [0, 1]. Each additive term in the formula (23) is attributed to a factor x i , correspondingly:

$$ \Delta x\left[ {x_{i} } \right] \, = \smallint x_{1} x_{2} \ldots x_{i - 1} x_{i} ' x_{i + 1} \ldots x_{n} dt \, \quad i \, = \, 1, \ldots ,n $$
(24)

Factor models similar to (21) have been studied intensively by Sheremet (1979) and his school of economic analysis. The work of Sheremet et al. (1971) extended the Divisia formula (23) from a product of factorial indicators to arbitrary continuously differential functions. Assuming

$$ z = f\left( x \right) = f\left( {x_{1} , \ldots ,x_{n} } \right) $$
(25)

the authors obtained the factorial decomposition as

$$ \varDelta z = z_{1} - z_{0} = \int\limits_{L} {dz} = \int\limits_{L} {f_{1}^{'} dx_{1} } + \int\limits_{L} {f_{2}^{'} dx_{2} + \cdots } + \int\limits_{L} {f_{n}^{'} dx_{n} } $$
(26)

where

$$ \varDelta z[x_{i} ] = \int\limits_{L} {f_{i}^{'} dx_{i} } = \int\limits_{{t_{0} }}^{{t_{1} }} {f_{i}^{'} } x_{i}^{'} \,dt, $$
(27)

f i is a partial derivative of the function f(x 1,,x n ) with respect to the i-th argument, and x i  = dx i /dt.

Formula (26) may be rewritten in the vector form as

$$ \varDelta \varvec{z} = \int\limits_{L} {\nabla \varvec{z}^{T} d\varvec{X}} , $$
(28)

where ∆z is a row vector of factorial decomposition with components ∆z[x i ], vector

$$ \nabla z = \; < f_{1}^{'} , \ldots ,f_{n}^{'} > $$
(29)

is the gradient column vector of the function f(x 1 , …, x n ), upper index T stands for the transposition, and d X is a diagonal matrix with elements dx 1 , dx 2 ,…,dx n .

Meerovich (1974) demonstrated, however, that when structural change is analyzed, the Laspeyres-Paasche approach may lead to results that contradict economic common sense. An example borrowed from that publication may be found in Vaninsky (2014a). Vaninsky and Meerovich (1978) revealed further that the same effect is observed when the Divisia approach is used. That publication also revealed, at the empirical level, how this contradiction may be overcome by using the projected gradient. An axiomatic theory was developed in Vaninsky (1983, 1987). Its brief description may be found in Maital and Vaninsky (2000). This paper applies that theory to the factorial decomposition of energy consumption and CO2 emissions.

1.2 Projected gradient

In the discussion above, we used the projected-gradient method to find a vector of optimal restructuring. It is known, see, for example, Kaplan (1993), that for a continuously differentiable function of several variables f (x), the gradient vector

$$ \nabla \varvec{f} = \, < f_{1}^{'} , \ldots ,f_{n}^{'} > , $$
(30)

where f i is the partial derivative with respect to the i-th argument, provides both the direction and the magnitude of steepest increase in the value of the function. The antigradient vector points in the opposite direction and determines the magnitude of steepest decrease. Optimization algorithms use this property by making steps in the direction of the gradient or antigradient for maximization or minimization, respectively (see, for example, Polak 1997). However, if the variables x = < x 1 ,…,x n  > were bound by the equations of interconnections—i.e., in the problems of constrained optimization—the endpoint of the gradient vector might leave the surface defined by these equations. In that case, the gradient vector becomes unfeasible. To avoid the infeasibility, Rosen (1960, 1961) suggested projecting the gradient vector on a plane tangent to the surface defined by the equations of interconnection. This projected-gradient method was developed further in Bertsekas (1976), Calamai and More (1987), Grana Drummond and Iusem (2004), Goldstein (1964), and Levitin and Polyak (1966), among others. In applications, one advantage of the projected-gradient method is the ability to set up optimization problems in terms of a complete set of convenient variables, rather than their contraction to the subset of functionally independent variables.

For the purposes of our discussion here, we use a particular property of the projected gradient, proved in Maital and Vaninsky (1999). That property indicates that the projected gradient provides both the direction and the magnitude of steepest increase in the value of the function limited to the surface of the interconnection of the variables. We use this theorem to find the optimal direction in the presence of the equations of the interconnections between the arguments of the objective function. It is known, for example, from Albert (1972), that if the arguments of a function f(x) are interconnected by a system of equations Φ ( x ) = 0, then the projected gradient may be found as

$$ Proj_{H} \nabla \varvec{f} = \nabla \varvec{f}^{T} \left( {\varvec{I} - \varvec{HH}^{ + } } \right), $$
(31)

where

$$ \varvec{H} = \left( {h_{ik} } \right) = \left( {\partial \varPhi_{k} /\partial x_{i} } \right), \, i = 1, \ldots ,p; \, k = 1, \ldots ,q, $$
(32)

p is the number of variables, q is the number of the equations of the interconnection, I is the identity matrix, H is the Jacobian matrix, and H + is the general inverse of the matrix H. If the columns of the matrix H are linearly independent, then

$$ \varvec{H}^{ + } = \, \left( {\varvec{H}^{{\varvec{T}}} \varvec{H}} \right)^{ - 1} \varvec{H}^{{\varvec{T}}} $$
(33)

(see Kaplan 1993, for details).

In the factorial models for energy consumption and CO2 emissions the Eq. (4) is the only one in the system of the equations of interconnections Φ ( x ) = 0. In this case, the Jacobian matrix H in formula (32) becomes a one-column matrix

$$ \varvec{H} = < 1,1, \ldots ,1 >^{T} . $$
(34)

As shown in Vaninsky and Meerovich (1978) and Vaninsky (1983, 1987), the projected gradient on the hyperplane defined by the Eq. (4) for the CO2 emissions turns out to be (14), and the projected antigradient becomes (15). Similar expressions were obtained for the energy consumption indicator, as given by formula (18).

1.3 Relationship between the coefficient of correlation and cosine of an angle

The following comment is useful for the development of the computational procedure and the interpretation of the results obtained thereby: An ordered set of observations may be viewed from two perspectives. The first is a geometric approach that treats each set as a multidimensional vector. The measure of the closeness of two vectors is a cosine of the angle between them. The second approach considers the sets of observations as the occurrences of two random variables. In this case, the closeness of a pair of sets is measured by a coefficient of correlation. From the vector perspective, a cosine of the angle between two vectors u = < u 1u 2…, u n  > and v = <v 1v 2…, v n  > is as follows:

$$ cos\,\theta = \frac{{\varvec{u} \cdot \varvec{v}}}{{\left\| \varvec{u} \right\|\,\left\| \varvec{v} \right\|}} = \frac{{u_{1} v_{1} + \cdots + u_{n} v_{n} }}{{\sqrt {u_{1}^{2} + \cdots + u_{n}^{2} } \,\sqrt {v_{1}^{2} + \cdots + v_{n}^{2} } }} $$
(35)

where the symbols “·” and || || stand for the dot product and the norm of a vector, respectively (see Spiegel et al. 2009, for details). On the other hand, if two ordered sets of observations are considered as the occurrences of two random variables, their closeness is measured by a coefficient of correlation r, equal to

$$ r = \frac{{\sum {\left( {u_{i} - \bar{u}} \right)} \left( {v_{i} - \bar{v}} \right)}}{{\sqrt {\sum {\left( {u_{i} - \bar{u}} \right)^{2} \left( {v_{i} - \bar{v}} \right)^{2} } } }}, $$
(36)

where the upper bar symbol “\(\bar{\,}\)” stands for the average value (see, for example, Spiegel and Stephens 2014). The value of r 2 is referred to in statistical literature as a coefficient of determination. It defines a share of the variance of one random variable that may be explained by another random variable. Both measures of closeness—cos θ and r—vary in the same range from −1 to 1, and the greater any of them, the closer the two sets of observations are to each other. In our case, as follows from Eqs. (9), (15), and (18), the average values in formula (36) are equal to zero. This means that, for the purposes of this paper, we can use the geometric or the statistical interpretation interchangeably, as appropriate.

The problem of finding a vector closest to each of the vectors in a set is typical of factor analysis (see Thompson 2004, for details). In this discussion we use a simple version of this technique, with three vectors in a set and one factor vector. Mathematically, we are seeking a vector d as a convex combination of the normalized gradient/antigradients direction vectors

$$ \hat{\varvec{d}}_{GDP} = \varvec{d}_{GDP} /\left\| {\varvec{d}_{GDP} } \right\|,\;\,\hat{\varvec{d}}_{e} = \varvec{d}_{e} /\left\| {\varvec{d}_{e} } \right\|,\;\;\hat{\varvec{d}}_{c} = \varvec{d}_{c} /\left\| {\varvec{d}_{c} } \right\|. $$
(37)

The optimal factor vector d maximizes the sum of squares of the pairwise coefficients of correlation or, in the geometric terms, the sum of squares of the cosines of the angles formed with each gradient or antigradient. Mathematical statement of the problem is given by formulas (19) and (20).

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Vaninsky, A. Optimal environment-friendly economic restructuring: the United States–China cooperation case study. Econ Change Restruct 51, 189–220 (2018). https://doi.org/10.1007/s10644-017-9202-9

Download citation

  • Received:

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s10644-017-9202-9

Keywords

Navigation