Skip to main content

Advertisement

Log in

Energy Transition Under Irreversibility: A Two-Sector Approach

  • Published:
Environmental and Resource Economics Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

This paper analyses the optimal energy transition of a two-sector economy (energy and final goods) under irreversible environmental catastrophe. First, it proposes a general appraisal of optimal switching problems related to energy transition showing: (1) the possibility of a catastrophe due to accumulation of pollution; and (2) technological regimes with the adoption of renewable energy. Second, it numerically shows that for given baseline parameter values, the most profitable energy transition path may correspond to the one in which the economy starts using both resources, crosses the pollution threshold by losing a part of its capital, and never adopts only clean energy. Third, it extends the model to allow for additional investment in energy saving technologies. We then find that this additional investment favours full transition to the sole use of renewable energy. It is then profitable to take advantage of these synergies by jointly promoting deployment of clean energy and providing incentives for investment in energy saving technologies.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. There are various types of irreversibility. It could be exhaustion of the natural regeneration capacity (Tsur and Withagen 2013), an irreversibility in the decision process (Pommeret and Prieur 2009; Ayong Le Kama et al. 2014) or a ceiling on the pollution stock (Lafforgue et al. 2008; Chakravorty et al. 2012).

  2. A non-separable utility function (Cobb–Douglas or Constant Elasticity of Substitution) would capture crossing effects arising from a strong relationship between the use of dirty energy, clean energy and the level of consumption. To avoid such effects, we focus on non-durable goods.

  3. An alternative model in which households consume final goods combined with home-based services produced from capital and energy consumption would lead to similar results in the sense that our definition of energy services (mainly clean energy) implicitly incorporates capital. However, we only consider investments in productive sectors (i.e. the final goods sector and the energy sector) for simplicity. As stated in footnote 2, such an alternative model would capture crossing effects arising from strong Leontief relationships.

  4. This is a strong assumption but it is consistent with the complementarity assumption considered in the final goods sector (see Sect. 2.3). If there were an available technology in the final goods sector that allows for substitution between fossil fuel and renewable energy, this technology could be used by households as well.

  5. For simplicity and analytical tractability, we consider the particular case of no capital depreciation without loss of generality. The absence of capital depreciation, will simply induce a lower optimal level of investment.

  6. Note that by assumption, the initial stock of the dirty source of energy \(S_0\) is used in the first regime (\(\overline{Z}\)) and the remaining is used in the second regime (\(S_0-\overline{Z}\)). Thus, any energy transition path that includes only the first regime or its combination with the third regime is characterized by \(S_{T_2}\) that goes to \(S_0-\overline{Z}\), while it goes to 0 for any energy transition path that includes both first and second regimes. When the energy transition path does not include either of the first two regimes, \(S_{T_2}=S_0\).

  7. One should also consider that the investment \(q_{t}\) induces a scale effect. The scale effect is characterized by an energy saving which is proportional to the amount of energy use. This would make the present model very complex and unsolvable because of the interaction that may appear between \(q_{t}\) and all the preceding control variables such as energy services.

  8. For more details see https://ec.europa.eu/energy/sites/ener/files/documents/ee_and_res_scenarios.

References

  • Acemoglu D, Akcigit U, Hanley D, Kerr W (2014) Transition to clean technology (No. w20743). National Bureau of Economic Research, UK

    Google Scholar 

  • Amigues JP, Ayong Le Kama A, Moreaux M (2015) Equilibrium transitions from non-renewable energy to renewable energy under capacity constraints. J Econ Dyn Control 55:89–112

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ayong Le Kama A, Pommeret A, Prieur F (2014) Optimal emission policy under the risk of irreversible pollution. J Public Econ Theory 16(6):959–980

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ayres RU (2007) On the practical limits to substitution. Ecol Econ 61(1):115–128

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Berndt ER, Wood DO (1975) Technology, prices, and the derived demand for energy. Rev Econ Stat 57(3):259–268

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Boucekkine R, Pommeret A, Prieur F (2013) Optimal regime switching and threshold effects. J Econ Dyn Control 37(12):2979–2997

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Boucekkine R, Pommeret A (2004) Energy saving technical progress and optimal capital stock: the role of embodiment. Econ Model 21(3):429–444

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Chakravorty U, Roumasset J, Tse K (1997) Endogenous substitution among energy resources and global warming. J Polit Econ 105(6):1201–1234

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Chakravorty U, Leach A, Moreaux M (2012) Cycles in non renewable resource prices with pollution and learning-by-doing. J Econ Dyn Control 36(10):1448–1461

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Charlier D, Mosino A, Pommeret A (2011) Energy-saving technology adoption under uncertainty in the residential sector. Ann Econ Stat 103/104:43–70

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dasgupta P, Heal G (1974) The optimal depletion of exhaustible resource. Rev Econ Stud 41:3–28

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dasgupta P, Heal G (1979) Economic theory and exhaustible resources. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge

    Google Scholar 

  • Dasgupta P, Stiglitz J (1981) Resource depletion under technological uncertainty. Econom J Econom Soc 49(1):85–104

    Google Scholar 

  • De Castro C, Mediavilla M, Miguel LJ, Frechoso F (2011) Global wind power potential: physical and technological limits. Energy Policy 39(10):6677–6682

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • De Castro C, Mediavilla M, Miguel LJ, Frechoso F (2013) Global solar electric potential: a review of their technical and sustainable limits. Renew Sustain Energy Rev 28:824–835

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • De Groot HL, Verhoef ET, Nijkamp P (2001) Energy saving by firms: decision-making, barriers and policies. Energy Econ 23(6):717–740

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Díaz A, Puch LA (2013) A theory of vintage capital investment and energy use. Working paper, Documentos de Trabajo del Instituto Complutense de Análisis Económico (ICAE) 35,23330

  • Forster BA (1975) Optimal pollution control with a nonconstant exponential rate of decay. J Environ Econ Manag 2(1):1–6

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fouquet R (2010) The slow search for solutions: lessons from historical energy transitions by sector and service. Energy Policy 38(11):6586–6596

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • GEA (2012) Global energy assessment: toward a sustainable future. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge and the International Institute for Applied Systems Analysis, Laxenburg, Austria

  • Golosov M, Hassler J, Krusell P, Tsyvinski A (2014) Optimal taxes on fossil fuel in general equilibrium. Econometrica 82(1):41–88

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Horii R, Ikefuji M (2012) Natural disasters in a two-sector model of endogenous growth. J Public Econ 96(9):784–796

    Google Scholar 

  • IPCC (2007) Climate Change 2007. The physical science basis. In: Solomon S, Qin D, Manning M, Chen Z, Marquis M, Averyt KB, Tignor M, Miller HL (eds) Contribution of Working Group I to the Fourth Assessment Report of the Intergovernmental Panel on Climate Change. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge

  • Karp L, Tsur Y (2011) Time perspective and climate change policy. J Environ Econ Manag 62(1):1–14

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Karp L, Zhang J (2012) Taxes versus quantities for a stock pollutant with endogenous abatement costs and asymmetric information. Econ Theor 49(2):371–409

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Krautkraemer JA (1986) Optimal depletion with resource amenities and a backstop technology. Resour energy 8(2):133–149

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kollenbach G (2013) Endogenous growth with a ceiling on the stock of pollution. Environ Resour Econ 62(3):1–21

    Google Scholar 

  • Lafforgue G, Magné B, Moreaux M (2008) Optimal sequestration policy with a ceiling on the stock of carbon in the atmosphere. Working paper No. 401. Institut d’Économie Industrielle (IDEI), Toulouse

  • Michielsen TO (2014) Brown backstops versus the green paradox. J Environ Econ Manag 68(1):87–110

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Nævdal E (2006) Dynamic optimization in the presence of threshold effects when the location of the threshold is uncertain - with an application to a possible disintegration of the western antarctic ice sheet. J Econ Dyn Control 30:1131–1158

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Nordhaus WD (1994) Managing the global commons: the economics of climate change. MIT Press, Cambridge

    Google Scholar 

  • Pelli M (2012) The elasticity of substitution between clean and dirty inputs in the production of electricity. University of Alberta, Mimeo

    Google Scholar 

  • Pindyck RS, Rotemberg JJ (1983) Dynamic factor demands and the effects of energy price shocks. Am Econ Rev 73(5):1066–1079

    Google Scholar 

  • Pindyck RS (2002) Optimal timing problems in environmental economics. J Econ Dyn Control 26(9):1677–1697

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Pommeret A, Prieur F (2009) Double irreversibility and environmental policy design. Working paper, No. 2009.10

  • Prieur F, Tidball M, Withagen C (2013) Optimal emission–extraction policy in a world of scarcity and irreversibility. Resour Energy Econ 35(4):637–658

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Solomon BD, Krishna K (2011) The coming sustainable energy transition: history, strategies, and outlook. Energy Policy 39(11):7422–7431

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Tahvonen O (1996) Trade with polluting non renewable resources. J Environ Econ Manag 30:1–17

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Tahvonen O (1997) Fossil fuels, stock externalities, and backstop technology. Can J Econ 30:855–874

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Tahvonen O, Withagen C (1996) Optimality of irreversible pollution accumulation. J Econ Dyn Control 20(9):1775–1795

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Tsur Y, Withagen C (2013) Preparing for catastrophic climate change. J Econ 110(3):225–239

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Tsur Y, Zemel A (1996) Accounting for global warming risks: resource management under event uncertainty. J Econ Dyn Control 20(6):1289–1305

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Tsur Y, Zemel A (2003) Optimal transition to backstop substitutes for nonrenewable resources. J Econ Dyn Control 27(4):551–572

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Tsur Y, Zemel A (2005) Scarcity, growth and R&D. J Environ Econ Manag 49(3):484–499

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ulph A, Ulph D (1997) Global warming, irreversibility and learning. Econ J 107(442):636–650

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Van der Ploeg F, Withagen C (2012) Is there really a Green Paradox? J Environ Econ Manag 64(3):342–363

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Van der Ploeg F, Withagen C (2014) Growth, renewables, and the optimal carbon tax. Int Econ Rev 55(1):283–311

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgments

I am grateful to my PhD supervisor Aude Pommeret for her invaluable comments and helpful discussions on earlier drafts. I also thank the two anonymous referees, Linda Nøstbakken, Pascale Combes, Joëlle Noailly, an anonymous referee from FAERE and the participants at the FAERE workshop (Le Havre), the GGKP conference (Venice), the EAERE conference (Helsinki), the AFSE conference (Rennes) and the PSE Environmental Economics Lunch Seminar for their comments and suggestions.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Prudence Dato.

Electronic supplementary material

Below is the link to the electronic supplementary material.

Supplementary material 1 (pdf 146 KB)

Appendix

Appendix

1.1 Appendix \(A_0\)

See Table 4.

Table 4 Variables and parameters

1.2 Appendix \(A_1\)

Let us recall that the equation of capital accumulation is:

$$\begin{aligned} \dot{K}_{t}=Y{}_{t}-C_{t} . \end{aligned}$$
(23)

We also know that: \(Y_t=min\{\alpha _{2}K_{Yt},\beta _{2}E_{Yt}\}\), where, \(K_{t} = K_{Et} +K_{Yt}\) and \(E_{ct} = \eta K_{Et}\). \(E_{ct} = \eta K_{Et}\) implies that \( K_{Et}=\frac{E_{ct}}{\eta } \). Then,

$$\begin{aligned} K_{Yt} = K_{t}- K_{Et}=K_{t}-\frac{E_{ct}}{\eta } . \end{aligned}$$
(24)

From Leontief conditions in the final goods sector, we have:

$$\begin{aligned} Y_{t}=\alpha _{2}K_{Yt}=\beta _{2}E_{Yt} . \end{aligned}$$
(25)

During the third regime, only the clean source of energy is used so that we have the following equalities: \(E_{Yct}= E_{Yt}\), and \(E_{Cct}= E_{Ct}.\) By summing up the above two expressions and plugging this into successive Eqs. (24), (25) and into Eq. (23) gives \(\dot{K}_{t}=\alpha _{2}K_{t}-\alpha _{2}\frac{E_{Yt}+E_{Ct}}{\eta }-C_{t}.\)

1.3 Appendix \(A_2\)

To determine the expression of capital in the third regime, we need to solve the following equation of capital accumulation for the capital \(K_{t}\): \(\dot{K}_t=\Lambda K_t-\Theta \lambda _{T_{2}}^{-\frac{1}{\delta }}e^{(\frac{\alpha _{2}-\rho }{\delta })(t-T_{2})}\), where \(\Lambda =\frac{\alpha _{2}\beta _{2}\eta }{\alpha _{2}+\beta _{2}\eta }\) and \(\Theta =\frac{\alpha _{2}\beta _{2}}{\alpha _{2}+\beta _{2}\eta } (\frac{\alpha _{2}}{\eta })^{-\frac{1}{\delta }}+1.\) By making a change of variables \(x_t=K_t e^{-\Lambda (t-T_{2})}\) and using the following transversality conditions \(\underset{t\rightarrow \infty }{lim}\lambda _{t}K_{t}e^{-\rho (t-T_{2})}=0\), we get \(K_{t}=-\frac{\Theta \delta }{\alpha _{2}-\rho -\delta \Lambda } \lambda _{T_{2}}^{-\frac{1}{\delta }}e^{(\frac{\alpha _{2}-\rho }{\delta })(t-T_{2})},\) for \(\alpha _{2}(1-\delta )<\rho .\)

Finally, we need to impose the non-negativity condition on \(E_{Yt}\) so that:

$$\begin{aligned} E_{Yt}=\frac{\alpha _{2}}{\alpha _{2}+\eta \beta _{2}}(\eta K_t-E_{Ct})>0\Leftrightarrow -\frac{\Theta \delta \eta }{\alpha _{2}-\rho -\delta \Lambda } -\left( \frac{\alpha _{2}}{\eta }\right) ^{-\frac{1}{\delta }}>0. \end{aligned}$$

1.4 Appendix \(A_3\)

The expression of capital in the second regime is determined from FOCs as follows:

FOCs lead to: \(\mu _{t}=\mu _{T_{1}}e^{(\rho -\alpha _{2}(1-\phi ))(t-T_{1})}\), \(\nu _{t}=\nu _{T_{1}}e^{\rho (t-T_{1})}\), \(C_{t}=\mu _{T_{1}}^{-\frac{1}{\delta }}e^{(\frac{\alpha _{2}(1-\phi )-\rho }{\delta }) (t-T_{1})}\) and \(E_{Ct}=(\xi \nu _{T_{1}})^{-\frac{1}{\delta }}e^{-\frac{\rho }{\delta }(t-T_{1})}\). Using the above expression of C, the equation of capital accumulation becomes: \(\dot{K}-\alpha _{2}(1-\phi )K=-\mu _{T_{1}}^{ -\frac{1}{\delta }}e^{(\frac{\alpha _{2}(1-\phi )-\rho }{\delta })(t-T_{1})}.\) Using the same variable change as in Appendix B and taking \(K_{t}\) at \(\hbox {t}=T_{1},\) gives:

\(K_{t}=-(\overline{K_{2}}-K_{T_{1}})*e^{(\frac{\alpha _{2}(1-\phi )-\rho }{\delta })(t-T_{1})}+\overline{K_{2}},\) where \(\overline{K_{2}}\) is unknown and will be determined using boundary conditions in Sect. 3.1.4.

1.5 Appendix \(A_4\)

We assume that the dirty source of energy is exhaustible and that we have crossed the second regime after a period of time \(T_{1}\). Then, the initial stock of the dirty source of energy \(S_{0}\) is equal to the sum of the part of the dirty source of energy that is used during the first regime which corresponds to the total amount of pollution \(\overline{Z}\) and the part of the dirty source of energy that the economy uses during the second regime. We have: \(S_{0}=\underset{\overline{Z}}{\underbrace{\int _{0}^{T_{1}}\xi (E_{Yt}+E_{Ct})dt}}+\int _{T_{1}}^{T_{2}}\xi (E_{Yt}+E_{Ct})dt\). This implies that: \(S_{0}-\overline{Z}=\int _{T_{1}}^{T_{2}}\xi (E_{Yt}+E_{Ct})dt=\frac{\xi \alpha _{2}}{\beta _{2}}\int _{T_{1}}^{T_{2}}K_{t}dt+\xi \int _{T_{1}}^{T_{2}}E_{Ct}dt,\) with \(S_{0}>\overline{Z}\).

The above equation gives:

$$\begin{aligned} \frac{1}{\xi }(S_{0}-\overline{Z})= & {} -(\xi \nu _{T_{1}})^{-\frac{1}{\delta }}* \frac{\delta }{\rho }\left[ e^{-\frac{\rho }{\delta }(T_{2}-T_{1})}-1\right] +\frac{\alpha _{2}(1-\phi )}{\beta _{2}}\overline{K_{2}}\left[ (T_{2}-T_{1})\right] \\&-\,\frac{\delta \alpha _{2}}{\beta _{2}(\alpha _{2}(1-\phi )-\rho )}* (\overline{K_{2}}-K_{T_{1}})*\left[ e^{(\frac{\alpha _{2}(1-\phi )-\rho }{\delta }) (T_{2}-T_{1})}-1\right] . \end{aligned}$$

1.6 Appendix \(A_5\)

The level of capital at each time during the first regime is determined as follows:

FOCs give: \(\mu _{t}=\mu _{T_0}e^{(\rho -\alpha _{2}(1-\phi ))t},\) \(\nu _{t}=\nu _{T_0}e^{\rho t} ,\) \(C_{t}=\mu _{T_0}^{-\frac{1}{\delta }}e^{(\frac{\alpha _{2}(1-\phi )-\rho }{\delta })t}\) and \(E_{Ct}=(-\nu _{T_0}\xi )^{-\frac{1}{\delta }}e^{-\frac{\rho }{\delta }t}\). As before, we also replace the expression of \(C_t\) in the equation of capital accumulation to get: \(\dot{K}_t-\alpha _{2}(1-\phi )K_t=-\mu _{T_0}^{-\frac{1}{\delta }}e^{(\frac{\alpha _{2}(1-\phi )-\rho }{\delta })t}.\) Solving the above equation and taking \(K_{t}\) at \(t=0\) give \(K_{t}=-(\overline{K_{1}}-K_{0})e^{(\frac{\alpha _{2}(1-\phi )-\rho }{\delta })t}+\overline{K_{1}}\). Finally, at the end of the first regime, we cross the pollution threshold so that \(\overline{Z}=\int _{0}^{T_{1}}\xi (E_{Yt}+E_{Ct})dt\). This equation then implies that:

$$\begin{aligned} \nu _{T_0}= & {} -\frac{1}{\xi }\left[ \left( -\frac{\overline{Z}}{\xi }+\frac{\alpha _{2}(1-\phi )}{\beta _{2}} \overline{K_{1}}*T_{1}- \frac{\alpha _{2}(1-\phi )\delta }{\beta _{2}(\alpha _{2}(1-\phi ) -\rho )}(\overline{K_{1}}-K_{0})\right. \right. \\&\left. \left. \left[ e^{\left( \frac{\alpha _{2}(1-\phi )-\rho }{\delta }\right) *T_{1}}-1\right] \right) * \frac{\rho }{\delta \left[ e^{-\frac{\rho }{\delta }T_{1}}-1\right] }\right] ^{-\delta } \end{aligned}$$

where \(\nu _{T_0}\) and \(\overline{K_{1}}\) are unknown and will be determined in Sect. 3.1.4 using boundary conditions.

1.7 Appendix \(B_1\)

Equations (12), (9) and (11) become respectively:

$$\begin{aligned}&\dot{K}_{t}=Y{}_{t}-C_{t}-q_{t} ,\\&\left\{ \begin{array}{l@{\quad }l} E_{Yt} =min\{\frac{1}{\xi }E_{Ydt}, E_{Yct}\}+\varepsilon _{Y}(q_{t}), &{} t< T_{2}\\ E_{Yt} = E_{Yct}+ \varepsilon _{Y}(q_{t}), &{} t \ge T_{2} \\ \end{array}\right. \nonumber \end{aligned}$$
(26)

and

$$\begin{aligned} \left\{ \begin{array}{l@{\quad }l} E_{Ct} = min\{\frac{1}{\xi }E_{Cdt}, E_{Cct}\}+\varepsilon _{C}(q_{t}), &{} t< T_{2}\\ E_{Ct} = E_{Cct}+ \varepsilon _{C}(q_{t}), &{} t \ge T_{2} .\\ \end{array}\right. \end{aligned}$$

where \(t< T_{2}\) corresponds to the first two regimes, while \( t \ge T_{2}\) denotes the third regime.

Also, Eqs. (14), (19) and (20) become respectively:

$$\begin{aligned} \dot{K}_{t}= & {} \alpha _{2}K_{t}-\alpha _{2}\frac{(E_{Yt}+E_{Ct}) -(\varepsilon _{Y}(q_{t})+\varepsilon _{C}(q_{t}))}{\eta }-C_{t}-q_{t}.\\ \dot{S}_{t}= & {} -E_{dt}=- \xi (E_{Yt}+E_{Ct})+\xi (\varepsilon _{Y}(q_{t}) +\varepsilon _{C}(q_{t})) \end{aligned}$$

and

$$\begin{aligned} \dot{Z}_{t}=E_{dt}= \xi (E_{Yt}+E_{Ct})-\xi (\varepsilon _{Y}(q_{t})+\varepsilon _{C}(q_{t})). \end{aligned}$$

1.8 Appendix \(B_2\)

1.8.1 Second regime

As before, the only change is the FOC with respect to \(q_{t}\):

$$\begin{aligned} \varepsilon _{Y}^{\prime }(q_{t})+\varepsilon _{C}^{\prime }(q_{t})=\frac{\mu _{t}}{\xi \nu _{t}} . \end{aligned}$$
(27)

Using the same specifications as before, the solution of Eq. (27) is :

$$\begin{aligned} q^{*}=\left[ \frac{\mu _{t}}{2\sigma \xi \nu _{t}}\right] ^{\frac{1}{\sigma -1}} . \end{aligned}$$
(28)

Equation (28) helps to solve the model during the second regime as before. The expression of the capital during the second regime becomes:

$$\begin{aligned} K_{t}-\overline{K_{2}}= & {} -\mu _{T_{1}}^{-\frac{1}{\delta }}* \frac{\delta }{\alpha _{2}(1-\phi )(1-\delta ) -\rho }e^{\frac{\alpha _{2}(1-\phi )-\rho }{\delta }(t-T_{1})}\\&+\, \left[ \frac{\mu _{T_{1}}}{2\sigma \xi \nu _{T_{1}}}\right] ^{\frac{1}{\sigma -1}}\frac{\sigma -1}{\alpha _{2}(1-\phi )\sigma } e^{-\frac{\alpha _{2}(1-\phi )}{\sigma -1}(t-T_{1})}. \end{aligned}$$

We should also observe here that the level of capital at each period of time during the second regime has a second negative component. As the share of the income that goes to investment is reduced by investment in energy saving technologies, one should expect a decrease in capital.

As in the case without any investment in EST, all the dirty sources of energy are extracted during the first and the second regimes such that:

$$\begin{aligned} S_{0}-\overline{Z}=\int _{T_{1}}^{T_{2}}\xi (E_{Yt}+E_{Ct}-\varepsilon _{Y} -\varepsilon _{C})dt. \end{aligned}$$

Solving the above equation, we get:

where \(H_{0}=-\xi ^{\frac{\delta -1}{\delta }}\frac{\delta }{\rho }\), \(H_{1}=-\frac{\xi \delta ^{2} \alpha _{2}}{\beta _{2}[\alpha _{2}(1-\phi )(1-\delta )-\rho ][\alpha _{2}(1-\phi )-\rho ]}\), \(H_{2}=-\frac{\xi (\sigma -1)^{2} \alpha _{2}}{\beta _{2}(2\sigma \xi )^{\frac{1}{\sigma -1}}\sigma \alpha _{2}^{2}(1-\phi )^{2}}\) and \(H_{3}=\frac{2\xi (\sigma -1)}{\alpha _{2}(1-\phi )\sigma (2\sigma \xi )^{\frac{\sigma }{\sigma -1}}}.\)

1.8.2 First Regime

As in the second regime the optimal investment in EST is:

$$\begin{aligned} q^{*}=\left[ -\frac{\mu _{t}}{2\sigma \xi \nu _{t}}\right] ^{\frac{1}{\sigma -1}}. \end{aligned}$$
(29)

We then solve the equation of capital accumulation to get the following expression of capital during the first regime:

$$\begin{aligned} K_{t}-\overline{K_{1}}= & {} -\mu _{T_0}^{-\frac{1}{\delta }}\frac{\delta }{\alpha _{2}(1-\phi )(1-\delta )-\rho } e^{\frac{\alpha _{2}(1-\phi )-\rho }{\delta }t}\\&+ \left[ -\frac{\mu _{T_0}}{2\sigma \xi \nu _{T_0}}\right] ^{\frac{1}{\sigma -1}}\frac{\sigma -1}{\sigma \alpha _{2}(1-\phi )}e^{\frac{-\alpha _{2}(1-\phi )}{\sigma -1}t}. \end{aligned}$$

We still have an additional negative component of the capital due to investment in energy saving technologies.

At the end of the first regime, we cross the pollution threshold so that:

$$\begin{aligned} \overline{Z}=\int _{0}^{T_{1}}\xi (E_{Yt}+E_{Ct}-2\varepsilon _{t}^{*})dt. \end{aligned}$$

By solving the above equation as before, we get the following expression:

where \(H_{0}\), \(H_{1}\) and \(H_{3}\) are the same as defined before and \(H_{4}=\frac{\xi \delta (\sigma -1)\alpha _{2}}{\beta _{2} \alpha _{2}((1-\phi )\left[ \alpha _{2}(1-\phi )(1-\delta )-\rho \right] }.\)

1.8.3 Boundary Conditions

As in the case without any investments in EST, we apply some boundary conditions. Continuity of \(\mu _{t}\) and continuity of \(K_{t}\) at the switching times \(T_{1}\) and \(T_{2}\) gives the following equation:

where

$$\begin{aligned} H_{5}= & {} -\frac{\Theta \delta }{\alpha _{2}-\rho -\delta \Lambda }e^{\frac{\alpha _{2}(1-\phi )-\rho }{\delta }T_{2}},\\ H_{6}= & {} \frac{\delta }{\alpha _{2}(1-\phi )(1-\delta )-\rho }\left[ \theta e^{\frac{\alpha _{2}(1-\phi )-\rho }{\delta }T_{1}}+(1-\phi )-e^{\frac{\alpha _{2}(1-\phi )-\rho }{\delta }T_{2}}\right] ,\\ H_{7}= & {} \frac{\sigma -1}{\alpha _{2}\sigma (1-\phi )}\left[ -e^{\frac{\rho -\alpha _{2}(1-\phi )}{\sigma -1}T_{1}} +e^{[{\frac{\rho }{\sigma -1}T_{1}-\frac{\alpha _{2}(1-\phi )}{\sigma -1}T_{2}}]}\right] \hbox { and }\\ H_{8}= & {} \frac{(\sigma -1)(1-\theta )}{\alpha _{2}\sigma (1-\phi )}\left[ -1+e^{\frac{-\alpha _{2}(1-\phi )}{\sigma -1}T_{1}}\right] .\\ \end{aligned}$$

Equations A, B and C express three different relationships between \(\mu _{T_0}\), \(\nu _{T_0}\) and \(\nu _{T_{1}}\) that we can simultaneously solve. Additionally, we simultaneously and numerically solve the equality of Hamiltonians at the switching time \(T_{1}\) and \(T_{2}\) to get \(T_{1}\) and \(T_{2}\).

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Dato, P. Energy Transition Under Irreversibility: A Two-Sector Approach. Environ Resource Econ 68, 797–820 (2017). https://doi.org/10.1007/s10640-016-0053-z

Download citation

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s10640-016-0053-z

Keywords

JEL Classification

Navigation