Skip to main content

Advertisement

Log in

Unilateral Climate Policy with Production-Based and Consumption-Based Carbon Emission Taxes

  • Published:
Environmental and Resource Economics Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

This paper characterizes a sub-global climate coalition’s unilateral policy of reaching a given climate damage reduction goal at minimum costs. Following Eichner and Pethig (J Environ Econ Manag, 2013) we set up a two-country two-period model in which one of the countries represents a climate coalition that implements a binding ceiling on the world’s first-period emissions. The other country is the rest of the world and refrains from taking action. The coalition can make use of production-based carbon emission taxes in both periods, as in Eichner and Pethig (J Environ Econ Manag, 2013), but here we consider consumption-based carbon emission taxes as an additional instrument. The central question is whether and how the coalition employs the consumption-based taxes along with the production-based taxes in its unilateral cost-effective ceiling policy. All cost-effective policies identified analytically and numerically consist of a mix of both types of taxes implying that there is a tax mix which is less expensive for the coalition than stand-alone consumption-based or stand-alone production-based taxes. With full cooperation both taxes are perfect substitutes (in our model), but in case of unilateral action they are imperfect substitutes, because coalition’s total welfare loss from two different but moderate distortions is smaller than that from a single but severe distortion.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. Here we are not concerned with the issue of coalition formation and stability (e.g. Finus 2003).

  2. Such a policy reduces the present value of total world climate damage but the coalition’s present value of mitigation costs may exceed its benefits from climate damage reduction. Numerical exercises (not documented here) show that the coalition may be ‘profitable’ (Carraro and Siniscalco 1993, p. 313) in the sense that its net gain may be positive against the benchmark of the no-policy scenario.

  3. Our concept of ceiling policy differs from the so-called carbon budget policy in Chakravorty and Magne (2006) and Kalkuhl and Edenhofer (2010). The ceiling is an upper bound on emissions that have cumulated until some point in time in the medium term, while the carbon budget is an upper bound on total cumulative emissions.

  4. The potential role of consumption taxes as pollution control instruments has been investigated by Albrecht (2006) and others who suggest differentiated rates according to the environmental impact of products. Holland (2012) finds that a consumption tax improves the efficiency of an intensity standard and may prevent leakage. Adopting a CGE approach Elliott et al. (2010) study various scenarios of taxing carbon without overlapping tax instruments and show that adding full border tax adjustment to carbon taxation in Annex B countries eliminates the leakage into developing countries. However, this literature neither studies a mix of p- and c-emission taxes nor does it account for the intertemporal allocation of scarce fossil fuel resources.

  5. Notice that mitigation policies in one-country models are tantamount to fully cooperative climate policies.

  6. In that regard our model is in line e.g. with Sinclair (1992), Sinn (2008), Hoel (2011), Michielsen (2011). A more encompassing approach would be to endogenize cumulative emissions as e.g. in Ploeg and Withagen (2012), Grafton et al. (2010), Kalkuhl and Edenhofer (2010), Gerlagh (2011) and Ritter and Schopf (2013). However, our more restrictive setup suffices for the problem at hand, because we will show that the driving force of our results is the manipulation of the terms of trade via unilateral emission regulation, and that mechanism also works in more complex and more realistic settings.

  7. Essentially, the model is the same as in Eichner and Pethig (2011), even though we now deal with 2 rather than 3 countries. The two-period time horizon is chosen for analytical tractability. Eichner and Pethig (2011) show that the model is robust with respect to extending the number of periods.

  8. In (1) the superscript \(s\) indicates quantities supplied. Upper case letters denote functions and subscripts attached to them indicate first partial derivatives. Note that the production functions (1) can be interpreted as being linear homogeneous in fossil fuel and in a domestic production factor, e.g. labor, which is in fixed supply.

  9. To capture total utility one would have to add in (2) a climate damage term. However, we suppress that term without loss of generality, because the climate damage reduction achieved when moving from the no-policy equilibrium to the ceiling-policy equilibrium is a constant.

  10. The extraction of fossil fuel is assumed to be costless and the interest rate is zero. For the rationale (and admissibility) of setting equal to zero the interest rate see Eichner and Pethig (2013).

  11. The proof of Proposition 1(i) is due to Eichner and Pethig (2013) who study a model in which governments have at their disposal p-emission taxes but no c-emission taxes. It is straightforward to prove Proposition 1(ii) by comparing the first-order conditions of the social planner’s solution (Eichner and Pethig 2013, Appendix B) with the first-order conditions of the market agents in Sect. 2 of the present paper.

  12. To keep focused we mention only in passing that ‘convex combinations’ of the first period p-emission taxes and first-period c-emission taxes also do the job as well as policies that consist of p-emission taxes [c-emission taxes] only which differ from Policy I [Policy II] of Proposition 1 in that the tax rate in each period is shifted up or down by a constant (see Eichner and Pethig 2013). The crucial feature of all these hybrid policies is that they sustain one and the same equilibrium allocation.

  13. Recall that we specified the base of the c-emission tax by approximating the emission intensity \(Q(e_{Bt})\) by \(Q(e_{At})\). In case of unilateral action that simplification receives additional support from the concept of ‘best available technology’ for border carbon adjustment (Ismer and Neuhoff 2007; Jakob and Marschinski 2013) which proceeds on the plausible assumption that the taxing country \(A\) uses the best available technology with regard to the emissions intensity in production, i.e. \(Q(e_{At}) \le Q(e_{Bt})\). In that case country \(A\) does not overestimate country \(B\)’s emission intensity and thus observes the WTO principle of non-discrimination (in addition to avoiding high costs of collecting information on \(Q(e_{Bt})\)).

  14. Note that \((\pi _1, \pi _2, \tau _1, \tau _2) \in \mathbb {R}^4\) encompasses ceiling policies with stand-alone p-emission taxes, \((\pi _1, \pi _2, \tau _1 = 0, \tau _2 = 0)\), with stand-alone c-emission taxes, \((\pi _1 = 0, \pi _2 = 0, \tau _1, \tau _2)\) and with mixed taxes exhibiting \(\pi _t \ne 0\) and \(\tau _t \ne 0\) for \(t = 1\), and/or \(t=2\).

  15. Proposition 2 does not determine the sign of \(F(0)\). The only information we have from Eichner and Pethig (2013) is that there are feasible ceiling policies satisfying \(F(0) = 0\).

  16. That welfare loss is a partial welfare effect, because the benefits from reduced climate damage are not accounted for.

  17. In a broader sense, country \(A\) acts as a Stackelberg leader. The deviation from the standard Stackelberg approach is that in our model country \(B\), the Stackelberg follower, does not play Nash. Note also that country \(A\)’s unilateral cost-effective policy is one that maximizes country \(A\)’s welfare rather than the sum of both countries’ welfare.

  18. Laissez-faire levels are indicated with the superscript “\(o\)”.

  19. The parameter values used in this section are not based on calibration exercises.

  20. Interestingly, the stick \(\tau _1>0\) can be replaced by a carrot \(\tau _2 < 0\), as established in Proposition 3. In contrast, the p-emission tax sticks and carrots are no perfect substitutes.

  21. For convenience of simple wording we refer to every specific numerical parameter constellation of our model as an ’economy’. Each row in Table 2 corresponds to such an economy.

  22. We are grateful to one of the anonymous reviewers for the following intuition.

  23. If (30) is satisfied, the second-period market for good \(X\) is also in equlibrium owing to Walras law.

  24. In (37) the equality signs are important because they may force the tax rates \(\pi _{1}\), \(\pi _{2}\) to take on negative values.

References

  • Albrecht J (2006) The use of consumption taxes to re-launch green tax reforms. Int Rev Law Econ 26:88–103

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Biermann F, Brohm R (2005) Implementing the Kyoto protocol without the USA: the strategic role of energy tax adjustments at the border. Clim Policy 4:289–302

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Carraro C, Siniscalco D (1993) Strategies for the international protection of environment. J Public Econ 52:309–328

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Chakravorty U, Magne B, Moreaux M (2006) A Hotelling model with a ceiling on the stock of pollution. J Econ Dyn Control 30:2875–2904

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Davis SJ, Caldeira K (2010) Consumption-based accounting CO\(_2\) emissions. Proc Natl Acad Sci 107:5687–5693

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Eichner T, Pethig R (2011) Carbon leakage, the green paradox and perfect future markets. Int Econ Rev 52:767–805

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Eichner T, Pethig R (2013) Flattening the carbon extraction path in unilateral cost-effective action. J Environ Econ Manag 66:185–201

  • Elliott J, Foster I, Kortum S, Munson T, Perez Cervantes F, Weisbach D (2010) Trade and carbon taxes. Am Econ Rev Pap Proc 100:465–469

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Elliott J, Foster I, Kortum S, Khun Jush G, Munson T, Weisbach D (2012) Unilateral carbon taxes, border tax adjustments and carbon leakage. Argonne National Laboratory, Mathematics and Computer Science Division, Preprint ANL/MCS-P1711-0110

  • Finus M (2003) Stability and design of international environmental agreements: the case of transboundary pollution. In: Folmer H, Tietenberg T (eds) The international yearbook of environmental and resource economics 2003/2004. Edward Elgar, Cheltenham

    Google Scholar 

  • Gerlagh R (2011) Too much oil. CESifo Econ Stud 57:25–43

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Grafton RQ, can Long N, Kompas T (2010) Biofuels subsidies and the green paradox. CESifo Working Paper No. 2960

  • Hoel M (1994) Efficient climate policy in the presence of free riders. J Environ Econ Manag 27:259–274

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hoel M (2011) Climate change and carbon tax expectations. CESifo Working Paper No. 2966

  • Holland SP (2012) Emission taxes versus intensity standards: second-best environmental policies with incomplete regulation. J Environ Econ Manag 63:375–387

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ismer R, Neuhoff K (2007) Border tax adjustment: a feasible way to support stringent emission trading. Eur J Law Econ 24:137–164

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Jakob M, Marschinski R, Hübler M (2013) Between a rock and a hard place: a trade-theory analysis of leakage under production- and consumption-based policies. Environ Resour Econ. doi:10.1007/s10640-013-9638-y

  • Kalkuhl M, Edenhofer O (2010) Prices vs. quantities and the intertemporal dynamics of the climate rent. Conference Paper WCERE 2010

  • Michielsen T (2011) Brown backstops versus the green paradox. CentER discussion paper No. 2011-076

  • Monjon S, Quirion P (2010) How to design a border adjustment for the European Union Emissions Trading System? Energy Policy 38:5199–5207

  • Peters GP, Minx JC, Weber CL, Edenhofer O (2011) Growth in emission transfer via international trade from 1990 to 2008. Proc Natl Acad Sci 108:8903–8908

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ritter H, Schopf M (2013) Unilateral climate policy: harmful or disastrous? Environ Resour Econ. doi:10.1007/s10640-013-9697-0

  • Sinclair P (1992) High does nothing and rising is worse: carbon taxes should be kept declining to cut harmful emissions. Manch Sch 60:41–52

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Sinclair P (1994) On the optimum trend of fossil fuel taxation. Oxf Econ Pap 46:869–877

    Google Scholar 

  • Sinn H-W (2008) Public policies against global warming: a supply side approach. Int Tax Public Finance 15:360–394

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Van der Ploeg F, Withagen C (2012) Is there really a green paradox? J Environ Econ Manag 64:342–363

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Whalley J, Wigle R (1991) The international incidence of carbon taxes. In: Dornbusch R, Poterba JM (eds) Global warming. Economic policy responses. MIT Press, Cambridge, pp 233–270

    Google Scholar 

  • Wiedmann T (2009) A review of recent multi-region input–output models used for consumption-based emissions and resource accounting. Ecol Econ 69:211–222

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Zhang Z (2010) Climate change meets trade in promoting green growth: potential conflicts and synergies. FEEM Working Paper Series 408.2010

  • Zhang Z (2012) Competitiveness and leakage concern and border carbon adjustments. FEEM Working Paper Series 80.2012

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Thomas Eichner.

Additional information

An earlier version of this paper was circulated under the title “The carbon budget approach to climate stabilization: Cost-effective subglobal versus global action”. CESifo sponsorship for presenting the paper at the CESifo Area Conference on Energy and Climate Economics, October 2010, is gratefully acknowledged. We thank an associate editor and two referees for helpful comments. Remaining errors are the authors’ sole responsibility.

Appendix

Appendix

1.1 Proof of Proposition 2

Observe that (4), (5), (13) and the first-order conditions

$$\begin{aligned} X^A_{e_{A1}} (e_{A1}) = X^B_{e_{B1}} (\bar{e}_1 - e_{A1}) = p_x X^A_{e_{A2}} (e_{A2}) = p_x X^B_{e_{B2}} (\bar{e} - \bar{e}_1 - e_{A2}) \end{aligned}$$
(18)

determine \(e_{A1}, e_{A2}, p_e\) and \(p_x\) for given \(\bar{e}_1\). Hence country \(B\)’s income

$$\begin{aligned} y_B := X^B(\bar{e}_1 - e_{A1}) + p_x X^B(\bar{e} - \bar{e}_1 - e_{A2}) + p_e [\alpha _B \bar{e} - (\bar{e} - e_{A1} - e_{A2})] \end{aligned}$$

is fixed and so are the levels of consumption, \(x_{B1}\) and \(x_{B2}\). From the market clearing condition \(x_{A1}^s + x_{B1}^s = x_{A1} + x_{B1}\) therefore follows that the equilibrium value

$$\begin{aligned} x_{A1} := x_{A1}^s + x_B^s - x_{B1}, \end{aligned}$$
(19)

is uniquely determined by \(\bar{e}_1\). Consider next country \(A\)’s demand functions for the consumption good derived from CES utility (14)

$$\begin{aligned} x_{A1}&= \frac{\bar{\gamma }_A (p_x + \tau _2 q_2)^{\sigma _A} y_A}{\bar{\gamma }_A (1+ \tau _1 q_1)(p_x +\tau _2 q_2)^{\sigma _A}+ (p_x+\tau _2 q_2)(1+\tau _1 q_1)^{\sigma _A}}, \end{aligned}$$
(20)
$$\begin{aligned} x_{A2}&= \frac{y_A}{p_x} - \frac{x_{A1}}{p_x}, \end{aligned}$$
(21)

where

$$\begin{aligned} y_A&:= \underbrace{X^A (e_{A1}) + p_x X^A (e_{A2}) + p_e (\alpha _A \bar{e} - e_{A1} - e_{A2})}_{= y_{Ao}} + \tau _1 q_1 x_{A1} + \tau _2 q_2 x_{A2},\\&= y_{Ao} + \tau _1 q_1 x_{A1} + \tau _2 q_2 x_{A2}. \end{aligned}$$

Note that the above definition of \(y_A\) holds irrespective of the sign and size of \(\pi _1\) and \(\pi _2\). In (18) and (19) we have already accounted for all conditions of market clearing other than that of the second-period market for the consumption good. The latter is taken care of by Walras Law which is why we disregard Eq. (21). Closer inspection of (20) reveals that keeping the equilibrium values of \(\pi _1, \pi _2\) and \(p_x\) constant the equilibrium value \(x_{A1}\) can be attained through various combinations of \(\tau _1\) and \(\tau _2\). Formally speaking, there is a function \(F: \, \, ]-p_x, \infty [\, \, \longrightarrow \, \,] -1, \infty [\) such that the right-hand side of \(\frac{U^A_{x_{A2}}}{U^A_{x_{A1}}} = \frac{p_x + \tau _2}{1 + \tau _1}\) is unchanged for all \((\tau _1, \tau _2)\) satisfying \(\tau _1 = F(\tau _2)\). In order to specify the properties of that function \(F\) rearrange terms in (20) to obtain

$$\begin{aligned} x_{A1} \left[1 + (p_x + \tau _2 q_2)^{1-\sigma _A} (1+\tau _1 q_1)^{\sigma _A} \bar{\gamma }_A^{-1} \right]= y_{Ao} + \tau _2 q_2 x_{A2}. \end{aligned}$$
(22)

Differentiate (22) and account for \({\mathrm {d}}x_{A1} = {\mathrm {d}}x_{A2} = {\mathrm {d}}y_{Ao}\) and \({\mathrm {d}}q_1 = {\mathrm {d}}q_2 ={\mathrm {d}}p_x = 0\) to get

$$\begin{aligned}&x_{A1} \left[(1-\sigma _A)(p_x + \tau _2 q_2)^{- \sigma _A} (1+\tau _1 q_1)^{\sigma _A} \bar{\gamma }_A^{-1} q_2 {\mathrm {d}}\tau _2 \right]\nonumber \\&\quad +\, \sigma _A (p_x + \tau _2 q_2)^{1-\sigma _A} (1+\tau _1 q_1)^{\sigma _A - 1} \bar{\gamma }_A^{-1} q_1 {\mathrm {d}}\tau _1 = x_{A2} q_2 {\mathrm {d}}\tau _2. \end{aligned}$$
(23)

Next turn (23) into

$$\begin{aligned} x_{A1} \left[ (1- \sigma _A) \left( \frac{p_x + \tau _2 q_2}{1 + \tau _1 q_1} \right) ^{-\sigma _A} q_2 {\mathrm {d}}\tau _2 + \sigma _A \left( \frac{p_x + \tau _2 q_2}{1 + \tau _1 q_1} \right) ^{1-\sigma _A} q_1 {\mathrm {d}}\tau _1 \right] = \bar{\gamma }_A x_{A2} q_2 {\mathrm {d}}\tau _2. \nonumber \\ \end{aligned}$$
(24)

Account for \(\frac{x_{A1}}{x_{A2}} = \bar{\gamma }_A \left( \frac{p_x + \tau _2 q_2}{1 + \tau _1 q_1} \right) ^{\sigma _A}\) or \(\left( \frac{p_x + \tau _2 q_2}{1 + \tau _1 q_1} \right) ^{-\sigma _A} = \bar{\gamma }_A \frac{x_{A2}}{x_{A1}}\) in (24) to reach

$$\begin{aligned}&x_{A1} \left[ (1-\sigma _A) \bar{\gamma }_A \frac{x_{A2}}{x_{A1}} {\mathrm {d}}\tau _2 + \sigma _A \frac{p_x+ \tau _2 q_2}{1 + \tau _1 q_1} \bar{\gamma }_A \frac{x_{A2}}{x_{A1}} \frac{q_1}{q_2} {\mathrm {d}}\tau _1 \right] = \bar{\gamma }_A x_{A2} {\mathrm {d}}\tau _2,\\&\iff (1-\sigma _A) \bar{\gamma }_A x_{A2} {\mathrm {d}}\tau _2 + \sigma _A \frac{p_x + \tau _2 q_2}{1 + \tau _1 q_1} \bar{\gamma }_A x_{A2} \frac{q_1}{q_2} {\mathrm {d}}\tau _1 = \bar{\gamma }_A x_{A2} {\mathrm {d}}\tau _2, \\&\iff - \sigma _A {\mathrm {d}}\tau _2 + \sigma _A \frac{p_x + \tau _2 q_2}{1 + \tau _1 q_1} \cdot \frac{q_1}{q_2} {\mathrm {d}}\tau _1 = 0 \quad \iff \quad \frac{{\mathrm {d}}\tau _1}{{\mathrm {d}}\tau _2} \!=\! F_{\tau _2} \!=\! \frac{1 + \tau _1 q_1}{p_x + \tau _2 q_2} \cdot \frac{q_2}{q_1} > 0. \end{aligned}$$

We conclude that \(F_{\tau _2} > 0\) because \(q_1>0\), \(q_2>0\), \(1+ \tau _1q_1 > 0\) and \(p_x + \tau _2 q_2> 0\) and that

$$\begin{aligned} F_{\tau _2\tau _2} = \frac{(p_x + \tau _2 q_2) q_1 F_{\tau _2} - (1+ \tau _1 q_1) q_2}{(p_x + \tau _2 q_2)^2} \cdot \frac{q_2}{q_1} \gtreqless 0 \quad \Longleftrightarrow \quad F_{\tau _2} \gtreqless \frac{1+ \tau _1 q_1}{p_x + \tau _2 q_2} \cdot \frac{q_2}{q_1}. \end{aligned}$$

Hence \(F_{\tau _2 \tau _2} = 0\).

1.2 Proof of Proposition 3

Consider first the supply-side partial equilibrium established by the equations

$$\begin{aligned} e_{A1} + e_{B1}&= \bar{e}_1, \quad \quad e_{A2} + e_{B2} = \bar{e}_2:= \bar{e} - \bar{e}_1, \end{aligned}$$
(25)
$$\begin{aligned} X_{e_{A1}}^A (e_{A1})&= p_e + \pi _{1}, \end{aligned}$$
(26)
$$\begin{aligned} X_{e_{B1}}^B (\bar{e}_1 - e_{A1})&= p_e, \end{aligned}$$
(27)
$$\begin{aligned} p_x X_{e_{A2}}^A (e_{A2})&= p_e + \pi _{2}, \end{aligned}$$
(28)
$$\begin{aligned} p_x X_{e_{B2}}^B (\bar{e}_2 - e_{A2})&= p_e. \end{aligned}$$
(29)

These equations determine \(p_e\), \(p_x\), \(\pi _{1}\), \(\pi _{2}\) and \(x_{it}^s\) for \(i=A,B\) and \(t=1,2\) for every \((e_{A1}, e_{A2}) \in [0, \bar{e}_1] \times [0, \bar{e}_2]\). That equilibrium is partial, because the demand for good \(X\) still needs to be specified in order to establish equilibrium on the commodity markets,Footnote 23

$$\begin{aligned} x_{A1} + x_{B1} = x^s_{A1} + x^s_{B1}. \end{aligned}$$
(30)

The CES utility functions yield the demands

$$\begin{aligned} x_{A1}&= \frac{\left( \frac{\gamma _1 p_x}{(1+\tau _1 q_1) \gamma _2} \right) ^\sigma (y_{Ao} + \tau _1 q_1 x_{A1})}{(1+\tau _1 q_1) \left( \frac{\gamma _1 p_x}{(1+\tau _1 q_1) \gamma _2} \right) ^\sigma +p_x} = \frac{\left( \gamma _1 p_x \right) ^\sigma y_{Ao} }{\left( \gamma _1 p_x \right) ^\sigma + (1+\tau _1 q_1)^\sigma \gamma _2^\sigma p_x}, \end{aligned}$$
(31)
$$\begin{aligned} x_{B1}&= \frac{\left( \frac{\gamma _1 p_x}{\gamma _2} \right) ^\sigma y_{B}}{ p_x + \left( \frac{\gamma _1 p_x}{\gamma _2} \right) ^\sigma }, \end{aligned}$$
(32)

where \(y_{Ao}\) and \(y_B\) are incomes (see (11)) with \(y_{Ao}\) representing income before the tax revenue \(\tau _1 x_{A1}\) is recycled to the consumer. Note that if \(\sigma >0\) and \(\tau _1 \in \mathbb {R}\), \(x_{A1}\) in (31) and \(x_{B1}\) in (32) are fully determined for every \((e_{A1}, e_{A2}) \in [0, \bar{e}_1] \times [0, \bar{e}_2]\).

We first investigate how \(x_{B1}\) varies with \(\sigma \). Since utility maximization implies

$$\begin{aligned} \frac{x_{B1}}{x_{B2}} = \left( \frac{\gamma _1 p_x}{\gamma _2} \right) ^\sigma , \end{aligned}$$
(33)

the straightforward conclusion from (33) and constant \(y_B\) is

$$\begin{aligned} \frac{{\mathrm {d}}x_{B1}}{{\mathrm {d}}\sigma } \, \left\{ \begin{array}{l@{\quad }l} >0, \, \text{ if } \, (\gamma _1 p_x/ \gamma _2)>1 &{}(\text{ and } \, x_{B1} \rightarrow y_B,\, \text{ if } \, \sigma \rightarrow \infty ), \\ =0, \, \text{ if } \, (\gamma _1 p_x/ \gamma _2) =1, &{}\\ <0, \, \text{ if } \, (\gamma _1 p_x/ \gamma _2)<1 &{} (\text{ and } \, x_{B1} \rightarrow 0,\, \text{ if } \, \sigma \rightarrow \infty ). \end{array} \right. \end{aligned}$$
(34)

Consequently, disregarding the knife-edge case \((\gamma _1 p_x/\gamma _2)=1\) we find that for every \((e_{A1}, e_{A2})\) there is some set \(S \subset \mathbb {R}\) with non-empty interior such that

$$\begin{aligned} x_{B1} \le x^s_{A1} + x^s_{B1} \quad \forall \, \sigma \in S. \end{aligned}$$
(35)

Since \(x_{A1} \ge 0\), (35) is clearly a necessary condition for (30). Given (35), sufficient for (30) is \(x_{A1} = x^s_{A1} + x^s_{B1} - x_{B1}\). For \(\tau _1=0\) this equality will not hold, in general. But \(x_{A1}\) varies with \(\tau _1\). Differentiation of (31) with respect to \(\tau _1\) yields

$$\begin{aligned} \frac{{\mathrm {d}}x_{A1}}{{\mathrm {d}}\tau _1} = - \frac{(\gamma _1 p_x)^\sigma y_{Ao} \sigma q_1 (1+\tau _1q_1)^{\sigma -1}}{\left[ (\gamma _1 p_x)^\sigma + (1+\tau _1 q_1)^\sigma \gamma _2^\sigma p_x \right] ^2} \quad \text{ and } \quad \lim _{\sigma \rightarrow 0} \frac{{\mathrm {d}}x_{A1}}{{\mathrm {d}}\tau _1} =0. \end{aligned}$$
(36)

It follows that if \(\sigma \in S\) and \(x_{A1} \ne x^s_{A1} + x^s_{B1} - x_{B1}\) for \(\tau _1=0\), one can change the magnitude of \(x_{A1}\) by an appropriate choice of \(\tau _1\) such that (30) is satisfied. This completes the proof of Proposition 3.

1.3 Proof of Proposition 4

Based on our results in Proposition 3 we set \(\tau _2 = 0\) and treat the quantities \(e_{A1}\) and \(e_{A2}\) as the regulator’s decision variables for analytical convenience while the tax rates \(\pi _1\) and \(\pi _2\) adjust endogenously in order to sustain \(e_{A1}\) and \(e_{A2}\). The consumption tax rate \(\tau _1\) is implied by the solution of the regulator’s optimization problem. In her optimization procedure she takes into account

  • the equilibrium conditions (3) for the commodity markets,

  • the fuel/emission constraintsFootnote 24

    $$\begin{aligned} e_{A1} + e_{B1} = \bar{e}_1 \quad \text{ and } \quad e_{A2} + e_{B2} = \bar{e}_2 := \bar{e} - \bar{e}_1, \end{aligned}$$
    (37)
  • the input demand and output supply functions of all producers,

  • and the consumption demand functions of the consumer in country \(B\).

Ad (i): For the quadratic production functions (15) the supply-side partial equilibrium (25) – (29) turns into

$$\begin{aligned} p_e&= a-b(\bar{e}_1-e_{A1}), \end{aligned}$$
(38)
$$\begin{aligned} p_x&= \frac{a-b(\bar{e}_1-e_{A1})}{a-b(\bar{e}_2-e_{A2})}, \end{aligned}$$
(39)
$$\begin{aligned} \pi _{1}&= b(\bar{e}_1-2e_{A1}), \end{aligned}$$
(40)
$$\begin{aligned} \pi _{2}&= \frac{[a-b(\bar{e}_1-e_{A1})]b(\bar{e}_2-2b e_{A2})}{a-b(\bar{e}_2-e_{A2})} \end{aligned}$$
(41)

and

$$\begin{aligned} \frac{{\mathrm {d}}p_e}{{\mathrm {d}}e_{A1}} =b,&\quad \frac{{\mathrm {d}}p_e}{{\mathrm {d}}e_{A2}} =0, \end{aligned}$$
(42)
$$\begin{aligned} \frac{{\mathrm {d}}p_x}{{\mathrm {d}}e_{A1}} = \frac{b}{a-b(\bar{e}_2-e_{A2})} = \frac{b p_x}{p_e},&\quad \frac{{\mathrm {d}}p_x}{{\mathrm {d}}e_{A2}}= - \frac{p_e b}{[a-b \bar{e}_2 - e_{A2}]^2} = - \frac{b p_x^2}{p_e}. \end{aligned}$$
(43)

Next, we determine \(x_{A1}\) and \(x_{A2}\) with the help of country \(B\)’s demand

$$\begin{aligned} x_{B1} = \gamma y_B,&\quad x_{B2} = \frac{(1-\gamma )y_B}{p_x}. \end{aligned}$$
(44)

and with

$$\begin{aligned} X^A(e_{At})+X^B(e_{Bt})=x_{At}+x_{Bt} t=1,2. \end{aligned}$$
(45)

Observe that

$$\begin{aligned} x_t^s := X^A(e_{At})+X^B(e_{Bt})=a(e_{At}+e_{Bt})-\frac{b}{2} \left( e_{At}^2+e_{Bt}^2 \right) . \end{aligned}$$
(46)

From \(e_{At}^2 + e_{Bt}^2=\left( e_{At}+e_{Bt} \right) ^2 - 2 e_{At}e_{Bt}\) follows \(x_t^s=x_t^{s*}- b \left( \frac{\bar{e}_t^2}{4}-e_{At}e_{Bt} \right) \) with \(x_t^{s*}:=a\bar{e}_t-\frac{b \bar{e}_t^2}{4}\). Combined with (45) we get

$$\begin{aligned} x_{At}=x_t^s-x_{Bt}=x_t^{s*}- \frac{b \bar{e}_t^2}{4}+ b e_{At}e_{Bt}-x_{Bt}. \end{aligned}$$
(47)

Making use of (44) and inserting (47) into the Cobb–Douglas utility function yields

$$\begin{aligned} u_A = \left[ \underbrace{\left( x_1^{s*}- \frac{b \bar{e}_1^2}{4} \right) + b e_{A1} (\bar{e}_1 - e_{A1}) -\gamma y_B}_{x_{A1}} \right] ^{\gamma } \left[ \underbrace{\left( x_2^{s*}-\frac{b \bar{e}_2^2}{4} \right) + b e_{A2} (\bar{e}_2 - e_{A2}) -\frac{(1-\gamma ) y_B}{p_x}}_{x_{A2}} \right] ^{1-\gamma }. \end{aligned}$$
(48)

We differentiate \(u_A\) in (48) with respect to \(e_{A1}\) and \(e_{A2}\) and account for (42), (43) and

$$\begin{aligned} \frac{{\mathrm {d}}y_B}{{\mathrm {d}}e_{A1}}&= \frac{b p_x x^s_{B2}}{p_e}-b \Delta e_A, \end{aligned}$$
(49)
$$\begin{aligned} \frac{{\mathrm {d}}y_B}{{\mathrm {d}}e_{A2}}&= -\frac{b}{p_e} p_x^2 x_{B2}^s, \end{aligned}$$
(50)

to obtain, after rearrangement of terms,

$$\begin{aligned} \frac{{\mathrm {d}}u_A}{{\mathrm {d}}e_{A1}}&= \frac{b u_A}{p_e} \left[\frac{\gamma }{x_{A1}} [p_e (e_{B1}-e_{A1})- \gamma (y_B-x_{B1}^s) ]+ \frac{(1-\gamma )^2x_{B1}^s}{p_x x_{A2}} \right], \end{aligned}$$
(51)
$$\begin{aligned} \frac{{\mathrm {d}}u_A}{{\mathrm {d}}e_{A2}}&= \frac{b u_A}{p_e}\left[\frac{ \gamma ^2 p_x^2 x_{B2}^s}{x_{A1}}+ \frac{1-\gamma }{x_{A2}} [p_e(e_{B2}-e_{A2})- (1-\gamma ) (y_B-p_x x_{B2}^s) ]\right]. \end{aligned}$$
(52)

Next, we use (51), (52) and \(\frac{x_{A1} (1-\gamma )}{x_{A2} \gamma }=\frac{p_x}{1+\tau _1 q_1}\) in \(\frac{{\mathrm {d}}u_A}{{\mathrm {d}}e_{A1}} = 0\) and \(\frac{{\mathrm {d}}u_A}{{\mathrm {d}}e_{A2}} = 0\), respectively, to get

$$\begin{aligned} \frac{{\mathrm {d}}u_A}{{\mathrm {d}}e_{A1}} = 0&\Longleftrightarrow&(1 + \tau _1 q_1) \left[ p_e (e_{B1} - e_{A1}) - \gamma (y_B - x_{B1}^s) \right] + (1 - \gamma ) x_{B1}^s = 0,\quad \end{aligned}$$
(53)
$$\begin{aligned} \frac{{\mathrm {d}}u_A}{{\mathrm {d}}e_{A2}} = 0&\Longleftrightarrow&p_e (e_{B2} - e_{A2}) \!+\! (1 \!+\! \tau _1 q_1) \gamma p_x x_{B2}^s - (1 \!-\! \gamma ) (y_B \!-\! p_x x_{B2}^s) = 0. \end{aligned}$$
(54)

From summation of (53) and (54), we obtain

$$\begin{aligned} (1+\tau _1 q_1)(e_{B1}-e_{A1})+(e_{B2}-e_{A2})=-(1+\gamma \tau _1 q_1) \Delta e_A. \end{aligned}$$
(55)

Then we make use of (38)–(41) and get

$$\begin{aligned} (1+\tau _1 q_1) \pi _{1} + \frac{\pi _{2}}{p_x} = - (1+\gamma \tau _1 q_1) b \Delta e_A. \end{aligned}$$
(56)

Observe that (45) for \(t=1\), (51) and (56) determine the cost-effective policy \((e_{A1},e_{A2},\tau _1)\). Total differentiation of (56) yields

$$\begin{aligned}&- \left( 3+2 \tau _1 q_1 + \tau _1 \gamma q_1 -\frac{\tau _1 (\pi _1 +\gamma )}{2 \left( 1 -\frac{b}{2} e_{A1}\right) ^2} \right) {\mathrm {d}}e_{A1} - (3+ \tau _1 q_1 \gamma ) {\mathrm {d}}e_{A2} \nonumber \\&\quad + (\bar{e}_1-2e_{A1}+ \gamma \Delta e_A) q_1 {\mathrm {d}}\tau _1 + \tau _1 q_1 {\mathrm {d}}\bar{e}_1 = 0. \end{aligned}$$
(57)

For the laissez faire values \(\tau _1=0\), \(e_{A1}^o=e_{B1}^o=\bar{e}_1^o\), \(\Delta e_A^o=0,\) (57) simplifies to

$$\begin{aligned} 3 {\mathrm {d}}e_{A1} + 3 {\mathrm {d}}e_{A2} = 0. \end{aligned}$$
(58)

Next we account for \(x_{B1} = \gamma y_B\) and \(x_{A1} = \underbrace{\frac{1}{1 + \tau _1 q_1 (1 - \gamma )}}_{=:\check{\tau }_1}\gamma \underbrace{[X(e_{A1}) + p_x X(e_{A2}) + p_e \Delta e_A ]}_{=: y_{Ao}}\) and obtain after total differentiation of the equation

$$\begin{aligned} x_{A1} + x_{B1} - X(e_{A1}) - X(\bar{e}_1 - e_{A1}) = 0 \end{aligned}$$
(59)
$$\begin{aligned}&\left[\check{\tau }_1 \gamma (X_{e_{A1}} - p_e) + \frac{b p_x x_{A2}^s}{p_e} + b \Delta e_A + \gamma \left( \frac{b p_x x_{B2}^s}{p_e} - b \Delta e_A \right) - X_{e_{A1}} + X_{e_{A1}} \right]{\mathrm {d}}e_{A1} \nonumber \\&\quad + \left[\check{\tau }_1 \gamma \left( p_x X_{e_{A2}} - p_e - \frac{b p_x^2 x_{A2}^s}{p_e}\right) - \left( \frac{\gamma b p_x^2 x_{B2}^s}{p_e} \right) \right]{\mathrm {d}}e_{A2} - \frac{(1-\gamma ) q_1}{[1 + \tau _1 q_1 (1-\gamma ) ]^2} \gamma y_{Ao} {\mathrm {d}}\tau _1 \nonumber \\&\quad + \left[ \check{\tau }_1 \gamma \left( - \frac{2 b p_x x_{A2}^s}{p_e} - \frac{b p_x^2 x_{A2}^s}{p_e} - b \Delta e_A \right) \right. \nonumber \\&\quad \left. + \gamma \left( -\frac{b p_x x_{B2}^s}{p_e}-\frac{b p_x^2 x_{B2}^s}{p_e}-b\Delta e_B\right) - X_{e_{B1}} \right] {\mathrm {d}}\bar{e}_1 = 0. \end{aligned}$$
(60)

Assessing (60) at laissez faire, which is characterized by \(\tau _1=0\), \(X_{e_{A1}} = p_e\), \(p_x X_{e_{A2}} = p_e\), \(X_{e_{A1}}= X_{e_{B1}}\), \(\Delta e_A = \Delta e_B=0\), \(\gamma y_A = X(e_{A1})= x_{A1}^s = x_{B1}^s\), \(x_{B2}^s = x_{A2}^s\), we get

$$\begin{aligned}&\frac{2 \gamma b p_x x_{A2}^s}{p_e} {\mathrm {d}}e_{A1} - \frac{2 \gamma b p_x^2 x_{A2}^s}{p_e} {\mathrm {d}}e_{A2} - (1 - \gamma ) q_1x_{B1}^s {\mathrm {d}}\tau _1\nonumber \\&\quad = \left[ 2 \gamma \left( \frac{b p_x x_{A2}^s}{p_e} + \frac{b p_x^2 x_{A2}^s}{p_e} \right) + p_e \right] {\mathrm {d}}\bar{e}_1. \end{aligned}$$
(61)

Finally, we differentiate (53) to get

$$\begin{aligned}&\left[(\bar{e}_1 - 2 e_{A1}) \frac{{\mathrm {d}}p_e}{{\mathrm {d}}e_{A1}} - 2 p_e - \gamma \left( \frac{{\mathrm {d}}y_B}{{\mathrm {d}}e_{A1}} + X_{e_{B1}} \right) - \frac{(1-\gamma )}{1+\tau _1 q_1} X_{e_{B1}} \right]{\mathrm {d}}e_{A1} \nonumber \\&\quad + \left[(\bar{e}_1-2 e_{A1}) \frac{{\mathrm {d}}p_e}{{\mathrm {d}}e_{A2}} - \gamma \frac{{\mathrm {d}}y_B}{{\mathrm {d}}e_{A2}} \right]{\mathrm {d}}e_{A2} - \frac{(1-\gamma ) q_1 x_{B1}^s}{(1+\tau _1 q_1)^2} {\mathrm {d}}\tau _1 \nonumber \\&\quad + \left[(\bar{e}_1-2 e_{A1}) \frac{{\mathrm {d}}p_e}{{\mathrm {d}}\bar{e}_1} - \gamma \left( \frac{{\mathrm {d}}y_B}{{\mathrm {d}}\bar{e}_1} - X_{e_{B1}} \right) + \frac{(1-\gamma )}{1+\tau _1 q_1} X_{e_{B1}} \right]{\mathrm {d}}\bar{e}_1 = 0. \end{aligned}$$
(62)

Assessing (62) at laissez-faire, (62) turns into

$$\begin{aligned} \left[- 3 p_e - \frac{\gamma b p_x x_{B2}^s}{p_e} \right]{\mathrm {d}}e_{A1} + \frac{\gamma b p_x^2 x_{B2}^s}{p_e} {\mathrm {d}}e_{A2} - (1 - \gamma ) q_1 x_{B1}^s {\mathrm {d}}\tau _1 \nonumber \\ = - \left[\gamma \left( \frac{b p_x x_{B2}^s}{p_e} + \frac{p_x^2 x_{B2}^s}{p_e} \right) + p_e \right]{\mathrm {d}}\bar{e}_1. \end{aligned}$$
(63)

(58), (61) and (63) jointly determine \({\mathrm {d}}e_{A1}\), \({\mathrm {d}}e_{A2}\) and \({\mathrm {d}}\tau _1\). In matrix notation, these equations read

$$\begin{aligned} \begin{bmatrix} 3&3&0 \\ 2a&-2ap_x&-(1-\gamma ) q_1 x_{B1}^s \\ -3p_e-a&ap_x&-(1-\gamma ) q_1 x_{B1}^s \end{bmatrix} \begin{bmatrix} {\mathrm {d}}e_{A1} \\ {\mathrm {d}}e_{A2} \\ {\mathrm {d}}\tau _1 \end{bmatrix} = \begin{bmatrix} 0 \\ \left[ 2(a+ap_x) + p_e \right] {\mathrm {d}}\bar{e}_1 \\ \left( -a- a p_x-p_e \right) {\mathrm {d}}\bar{e}_1 \end{bmatrix}, \end{aligned}$$
(64)

where \(a:=\frac{\gamma b p_x x_{B2}^s}{p_e}\). Solving the equation system (64) by means of Cramer’s rule yields

$$\begin{aligned} \frac{{\mathrm {d}}e_{A1}}{{\mathrm {d}}\bar{e}_1}&= \frac{3(a+ap_x)+2p_e}{3(a+ap_x p_e)}>0, \end{aligned}$$
(65)
$$\begin{aligned} \frac{{\mathrm {d}}e_{A2}}{{\mathrm {d}}\bar{e}_1}&= - \frac{3(a+ap_x)+2p_e}{3(a+ap_x p_e)}<0, \end{aligned}$$
(66)
$$\begin{aligned} \frac{{\mathrm {d}}\tau _1}{{\mathrm {d}}\bar{e}_1}&= - \frac{5p_e(a+ap_x)+3p_e}{3x_{B1}^s(1-\gamma ) q_1 (a+ap_x p_e)}<0. \end{aligned}$$
(67)

The associated changes of the prices \(\pi _1\), \(\pi _2\), \(p_e\) and \(p_x\) follow from making use of (65) and (66) in (40)–(43).

Ad (ii): In case of \(\tau _1 ={\mathrm {d}}\tau _1=0\), (61) and (63) jointly determine \({\mathrm {d}}e_{A1}\) and \({\mathrm {d}}e_{A2}\). In matrix notation, these equations read

$$\begin{aligned} \begin{bmatrix} 2a&-2a p_x \\ -3p_e - a&a p_x \end{bmatrix} \begin{bmatrix} {\mathrm {d}}e_{A1} \\ {\mathrm {d}}e_{A2} \end{bmatrix} = \begin{bmatrix} \left[ 2(a+ap_x) + p_e \right] {\mathrm {d}}\bar{e}_1 \\ \left( -a- a p_x-p_e \right) {\mathrm {d}}\bar{e}_1 \end{bmatrix}. \end{aligned}$$
(68)

Solving the equation system (68), we obtain

$$\begin{aligned} \frac{{\mathrm {d}}e_{A1}}{{\mathrm {d}}\bar{e}_1}&= \frac{a p_x p_e}{6 a p_x p_e} =\frac{1}{6}>0, \end{aligned}$$
(69)
$$\begin{aligned} \frac{{\mathrm {d}}e_{A2}}{{\mathrm {d}}\bar{e}_1}&= - \frac{5a+ 6 a p_x +3 p_e}{6 a p_x}<0. \end{aligned}$$
(70)

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Eichner, T., Pethig, R. Unilateral Climate Policy with Production-Based and Consumption-Based Carbon Emission Taxes. Environ Resource Econ 61, 141–163 (2015). https://doi.org/10.1007/s10640-014-9786-8

Download citation

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s10640-014-9786-8

Keywords

JEL classification

Navigation