Skip to main content

Advertisement

Log in

Market Effects of Voluntary Climate Action by Firms: Evidence from the Chicago Climate Exchange

  • Published:
Environmental and Resource Economics Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

Are private voluntary environmental actions by firms a sign of mismanagement, or a profitable “win-win” replacement for regulation? Empirical evidence is decidedly mixed. In this study, we use 19 years of monthly stock price returns, from 1991 to 2009, to examine the profitability of participation in CCX, a large voluntary greenhouse gas mitigation program. After controlling for systemic market risk as well as industry-specific shocks, we find statistically significant and positive excess returns for firms that announce their decision to join CCX. In addition, the progress of proposed greenhouse gas legislation (the Waxman–Markey bill) had a positive and large impact on excess returns for CCX member firms, suggesting that a major incentive for firms to join CCX may be to prepare for future regulation. Marginal abatement costs (proxied by the carbon price), on the other hand, were unrelated to excess returns. Our results imply that voluntary approaches should play a role in combating climate change, but that relying on them alone is not enough.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. Although the EPA changed its policy and now includes CO2 as an air pollutant, there are no federal standards, taxes or other regulation that puts a price on CO2 emissions. Regional and local initiatives exist, however, such as the Regional Greenhouse Gas Initiative (RGGI) and California’s Global Warming Solutions Act (AB 32).

  2. E.g., Derwall et al. (2005); Dowell et al. (2000), Hart and Ahuja (1996), King and Lenox (2001), Russo and Fouts (1997), Yamashita et al. (1999), Ziegler et al. (2007).

  3. E.g. Dasgupta et al. (2001), Filbeck and Gorman (2004), Fisher-Vanden and Thorburn (1998), Gupta and Goldar (2005), Khanna et al. (1998), Konar and Cohen (1997, 2001), Muoghalu et al. (1995).

  4. A review of the CCX and other voluntary programs can be found in Kollmuss et al. (2008).

  5. There are 3 classes of membership on CCX: Members, participant members, and associate members. Participant members establish a registry and get their emissions verified, but don’t make any commitment on emissions reduction. Associate members have negligible direct emissions, but pledge to report and fully offset their indirect emissions. We focus here solely on full members: Those with sizeable direct emissions who pledge to reduce them.

  6. CCX was founded by Climate Exchange PLC, a publicly traded company. In July 2010, Intercontinental Exchange (ICE) acquired CCX and its global affiliates. Members reduced emissions by more than the required amount by the end of 2010, explaining the virtually zero carbon price in the last year. In July 2011, ICE launched the CCX Offset Registry Program, a platform to generate, register and trade carbon credits based on verified emission reductions (CCX fact sheet by ICE, available at www.theice.com/ccx, last accessed in June 2012).

  7. There is a separate literature that focuses specifically on the environmental effectiveness of various voluntary programs. In the current context, Matisoff (2012) finds that emissions from firms that participated in the CCX decreased, but that this decrease was due to a reduction in output rather than a reduction of carbon intensity.

  8. Furthermore, it is possible that the EUA carbon price during the first part of phase 1 substantially exceeded marginal abatement costs (Hintermann 2010), and that the price was driven by the (declining) probability that the cap would turn out to be binding at all (Hintermann 2012).

  9. If the market correctly prices securities, stock prices are equal to the discounted expected stream of dividends, which in turn reflect firm profits. If the efficient market hypothesis does not hold and stock prices are also affected by variables other than future profits, such as self-fulfilling expectations or investor ”herding” behavior, our approach remains valid as long as the deviation between price and fundamental equally applies to CCX member firms and their rivals. Other researchers use Tobin’s Q (equity value divided by market replacement cost of assets) which can be interpreted as a measure of intangible firm value. But like stock prices, Tobin’s Q tends to be non- stationary, which complicates statistical inference in our multivariate regression approach. Taking first differences solves the non-stationarity problem, but since the market replacement cost presumably does not change month-to-month, the information contained in first-differenced Tobin’s Q is identical to the information contained in returns.

  10. See Fama and French (2004) for a review of its history and application. The main reason why we use the CAPM is that it is frequently applied in finance, and its parsimonious nature. Rather than making stock prices depend on a range of (usually unobserved) firm characteristics, the CAPM relies on aggregate market information to price stock.

  11. For a balanced panel with \(\text{ N} \times \text{ T}\) observations, regressing individual stock returns on time-varying common factors yields the same point estimates as regressing cross-section averages (i.e. portfolio returns) on the same factors. In our case of an unbalanced panel, the point estimates will slightly differ because the portfolio approach equally weighs time averages, whereas the individual stock regression gives equal weight to all observations, implying a greater weight for months with more data. The interpretation of \(\alpha \) and \(\upbeta \) remains unchanged.

  12. See e.g. Banz (1981) and De Bondt and Thaler (1985).

  13. The book-to-market ratio is defined as book equity divided by market equity. Book equity captures a firm’s total assets minus liabilities and is defined as the value of stockholders’ equity plus the value of deferred taxes and investment tax credit, minus the value of preferred stock; market equity is the stock price times the number of shares.

  14. The actual calculation is the difference between the average of two winning portfolios (formed from small firms and big firms), minus the average from two losers (small and big). The winners and losers are formed above the 70 % percentile form the previous month, and below the 30 % percentile, respectively.

  15. http://mba.tuck.dartmouth.edu/pages/faculty/ken.french/datalibrary.html (last access on 8/16/2011).

  16. Prospects for a federal cap-and-trade system decreased somewhat when the bill was tabled in the Senate and attention was shifted to the recession and the deficit. This undoubtedly postponed the advent of a mandatory program, but mandatory permit trading remains the cornerstone of action against climate change in most other OECD countries, making it at least possible that the US will eventually institute a mandatory system as well. Because there was no clearly identifiable moment at which the probability of a mandated program decreased, we did not include an “anti-Waxman” dummy in the analysis. If such a moment existed, we would expect negative excess returns for CCX members.

  17. The weak inequality follows directly from stepwise marginal abatement cost curves. A second reason for our assumption is related to perception: The voluntary nature of the market should not change the basic arbitrage condition that firms abate as long as this is cheaper than buying permits. The reverse, however, may not be true if firms’ main incentive to join CCX is to generate an image of greenness: They could choose to abate even if this is costlier than covering all of their emissions by purchasing permits. There remains a stigma of absolution from environmental sins associated with buying offsets, if not among economists then in the general public.

  18. We set the announcement dummy to one for the month of the announcement for all firms. To address the fact that some firms joined late in the month, giving the market much less time to react than for firms joining early, we set the announcement dummy equal to one for the month following the announcement month for all firms that announced their decision to join after the 15th of each month. This means that the period during which we measure excess returns after the announcement varies from a minimum of 15 days (for firms announcing on the 15th) to a maximum of 44 days (for firms announcing on the 16th).

  19. In specification (4), the effect of joining CCX is captured by a one-time effect on returns, which is equivalent to a permanent effect on prices. To control for the possibility of lagged and/or permanent effect on returns, we introduced lagged versions of the announcement dummy, but they were statistically insignificant (results available on request).

  20. As in Kim and Lyon (2011), the voluntary program can be viewed as a treatment, and here the effect of joining CCX is treatment effect on the treated. Complicating the analysis is the fact that different firms joined at different times. In theory, the average treatment effect on the treated (ATT) would have to be constructed from several distinct effects occurring at different times. Rather than explicitly computing the ATT for each firm and then form an average, we construct a single control group by matching and use a D-in-D-type estimation procedure.

  21. The CRSP is a database of daily and monthly stock prices for publicly-listed firms in the United States going back to 1925. CRSP is maintained at the University of Chicago; for more information, see: http://www.crsp.com/.

  22. We use the effective federal funds rate as the risk-free rate of interest. The effective federal funds rate is a weighted average of rates on brokered trades. Monthly figures include each calendar day in the month, and are annualized using a 360-day year or bank interest. Information and data are available at http://www.federalreserve.gov/econresdata/releases/statisticsdata.htm.

  23. The CCX was comprised of a mix of municipalities, non-profits, and for-profit corporations. Among the for-profit firms (the object of this study), over 14 major (SIC) industry groups were represented, including agricultural, manufacturing, financial services, and consumer products. The most frequent industry represented in our sample was energy utilities (\(\text{ n} = 17\)), followed by pulp/paper and packaging (\(\text{ n} = 8\)), and petrochemicals (\(\text{ n} = 7\)).

  24. We do not include excess returns on the industry level for the full sample regressions because this would amount to including a time average of the LHS variable as a regressor, which would then “explain” almost the entire variation of excess returns. This is not the case for the matched-sample regressions because the industry averages are computed using the full sample.

  25. This point was made by a reviewer. It implies that the CFI market is not efficient in the sense that the CFI price is not equal to marginal abatement costs. Although not consistent with theory, this is a valid point in practice, especially considering the low carbon price and the different impact that reducing emissions and buying offsets may have on consumers and investors. Whereas reducing emissions sends a message of “greenness”, buying offsets (which is physically equivalent, conditional on additionality of the offset project) may be perceived less favorably.

References

  • Alberini A, Segerson K (2002) Assessing voluntary programs to improve environmental quality. Environ Resour Econ 22(1–2):157–184

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Anton WRQ, Deltas G, Khanna M (2004) Incentives for environmental self-regulation and implications for environmental performance. J Environ Econ Manag 48(1):632–654

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Arora S, Gangopadhyay S (1995) Toward a theoretical model of voluntary overcompliance. J Econ Behav Organ 28(3):289–309

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Banz RW (1981) The relationship between return and market value of common stocks. J Financ Econ 9(1):3–18

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Barnett ML, Salomon RM (2006) Beyond dichotomy: the curvilinear relationship between social responsibility and financial performance. Strateg Manag J 27(11):1101–1122

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Carhart MM (1997) On persistence in mutual fund performance. J Financ 52(1):57–82

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dasgupta S, Laplante B, Mamingi N (2001) Pollution and capital markets in developing countries. J Environ Econ Manag 42(3):310–335

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • De Bondt WFM, Thaler R (1985) Does the stock market overreact? J Financ 40(3):793–805

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Derwall J, Guenster N, Bauer R, Koedijk K (2005) The eco-efficiency premium puzzle. Financ Anal J 61(2): 51–63

    Google Scholar 

  • Dowell G, Hart S, Yeung B (2000) Do corporate global environmental standards create or destroy market value? Manage Sci 46(8):1059

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fama EF, French KR (1992) The cross-section of expected stock returns. J Financ 47(2):427–465

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fama EF, French KR (1993) Common risk factors in the returns on stock and bonds. J Financ Econ 33(1):3–56

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fama EF, French KR (2004) The capital asset pricing model: theory and evidence. J Econ Perspect 18(3):25–46

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Filbeck G, Gorman RF (2004) The relationship between the environmental and financial performance of public utilities. Environ Resour Econ 29(2):137–157

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fisher-Vanden K, Thorburn KS (1998) Voluntary corporate environmental initiatives and shareholder wealth. Tuck School of Business at Dartmouth working paper

  • Friedman M (2007) The social responsibility of business is to increase profits. In: Zimmerli WC, Holzinger M, Richter K (eds) Corporate ethics and corporate governance. Springer, Berlin, pp 173–178

  • Gupta S, Goldar B (2005) Do stock markets penalize environment-unfriendly behaviour? Evidence from India. Ecol. Econ. 52(1):81–95

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hart O, Tirole J (1990) Vertical integration and market foreclosure. Brookings papers on economic activity pp 205–276

  • Hart SL, Ahuja G (1996) Does it pay to be green? An empirical examination of the relationship between emission reduction and firm performance. Bus Strategy Environ 5:30–37

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Heal G (2005) Corporate social responsibility: an economic and financial framework. Geneva Pap Risk Insur Issues Pract 30(3):387–409

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Heinkel R, Kraus A, Zechner J (2001) The effect of green investment on corporate behavior. J Financ Quant Anal 36(4):431–449

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hintermann B (2010) Allowance price drivers in the first phase of the eu ets. J Environ Econ Manag 59(1):43–56

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hintermann B (2011) Market power, permit allocation and efficiency in emission permit markets. Environ Resour Econ 49(3):327–349

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hintermann B (2012) Pricing emission permits in the absence of abatement. Energy Econ 34(5):1329–1340

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Khanna M (2001) Non-mandatory approaches to environmental protection. J Econ Surv 15(3):291–324

    Google Scholar 

  • Khanna M, Quimio WRH, Bojilova D (1998) Toxics release information: a policy tool for environmental protection. J Environ Econ Manag 36(3):243–266

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kim E-H, Lyon TP (2011) Strategic environmental disclosure: evidence from the DOE’s voluntary greenhouse gas registry. J Environ Econ Manag 61:311–326

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • King AA, Lenox MJ (2002) Exploring the locus of profitable pollution reduction. Manag Sci 48(2):289–299

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • King AA, Lenox MJ (2001) Does it really pay to be green? J Ind Ecol 5(1):105–116

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kollmuss A, Zink H, Polycarp C (2008) Making sense of the voluntary carbon market: a comparison of carbon offset standards. WWF Germany report

  • Konar S, Cohen MA (1997) Information as regulation: the effect of community right to know laws on toxic emissions. J Environ Econ Manag 32(1):109–124

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Konar S, Cohen MA (2001) Does the market value environmental performance? Rev Econ Stat 83(2):281–289

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Krattenmaker TG, Salop SC (1986) Competition and cooperation in the market for exclusionary rights. Am Econ Rev 76(2):109

    Google Scholar 

  • Lintner J (1965) The valuation of risk assets and the selection of risky investments in stock portfolios and capital budgets. Rev Econ Stat 47(1):13

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mallory J (2009) Will pension funds save the world? An analysis of institutional activism as a potential mechanism for carbon emissions reduction. University of Toronto working paper

  • McWilliams A, Siegel DS, Wright PM (2006) Corporate social responsibility: strategic implications. J Manag Stud 43(1):1–18

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Matisoff DC (2012) Privatizing climate change policy: is there a public benefit? Environ Resour Econ 53: 409–433

    Google Scholar 

  • Muoghalu MI, Little P, Robison HD (1995) Hazardous waste lawsuits, financial disclosure, and investors’ interests. J Acc Auditing Financ 10(2):383–400

    Google Scholar 

  • Nehrt C (1996) Timing and intensity effects of environmental investments. Strateg Manag J 17(7):535–547

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Oberndorfer U (2009) EU emission allowances and the stock market: evidence from the electricity industry. Ecol Econ 68(4):1116–1126

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Porter ME, van der Linde C (1995) Toward a new conception of the environment-competitiveness relationship. J Econ Perspect 9(4):97–118

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Reinhardt FL (1999) Bringing the environment down to earth. Harv Bus Rev 36(3):149–157

    Google Scholar 

  • Russo MV, Fouts PA (1997) A resource-based perspective on corporate environmental performance and profitability. Acad Manag J 40(3):534–559

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Salop SC, Scheffman DT (1983) Raising rival’s cost. Am Econ Rev 73(2):267

    Google Scholar 

  • Salop SC, Scheffman DT (1987) Cost-raising strategies. J Ind Econ 36(1):19–34

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Sharpe WF (1964) Capital asset prices: A theory of market equilibrium under conditions of risk. J Financ 19(3):425–442

    Google Scholar 

  • Sijm J, Neuhoff K, Chen Y (2006) CO2 cost pass through and windfall profits in the power sector. Clim Policy 6:49–72

    Google Scholar 

  • Telle K (2006) It pays to be green a premature conclusion? Environ Resour Econ 35:195–220

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Yamashita M, Sen WS, Roberts MC (1999) The rewards for environmental conscientiousness in the US capital markets. J Financ Strateg Decis 12(1):73–82

    Google Scholar 

  • Ziegler A, Schroeder M, Rennings K (2007) The effect of environmental and social performance on the stock performance of european corporations. Environ Resour Econ 37:661–680

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ziegler A, Busch T, Hoffman VH (2009) Corporate responses to climate change and financial performance: the impact of climate policy. ETH-CER working paper Nr. 09/105, February

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Beat Hintermann.

Appendix: Derivation of the Regression Specification

Appendix: Derivation of the Regression Specification

In order to derive a theoretically consistent regression specification, we start by considering the price equation that gives rise to the CAPM while suppressing the subscripts on the coefficients:

$$\begin{aligned} \frac{P_{it}}{P_{ft}}= e^{\alpha t}\cdot \left(\frac{P_{mt}}{P_{ft}}\right)^{\beta } \end{aligned}$$
(A.1)

or, equivalently,

$$\begin{aligned} P_{it}= e^{\alpha t}\cdot P_{mt}^{\beta } \cdot P_{ft}^{-{\beta -1}} \end{aligned}$$
(A.2)

Taking logs and differentiating w.r.t time gives

$$\begin{aligned} \frac{\dot{P}_{it}}{P_{it}}= \alpha +\beta \cdot \frac{\dot{P}_{mt}}{P_{mt}} -(\beta -1) \cdot \frac{\dot{P}_{ft}}{P_{ft}} \end{aligned}$$
(A.3)

where a dot represents a time derivative. Rearranging and discretizing in order to accommodate market data results in

$$\begin{aligned} \frac{\Delta P_{it}}{P_{it-1}} - \frac{\Delta P_{ft}}{P_{ft-1}} = \alpha +\beta \cdot \left(\frac{\Delta P_{mt}}{P_{mt-1}} -\frac{\Delta P_{ft}}{P_{ft-1}}\right) \end{aligned}$$
(A.4)

where \(\Delta \) is the first-difference operator. Since proportional first differences are equal to returns, () is equivalent to Eq. (2) in the main text. We now add average prices for “small” and “big” (in terms of market value), “high” and “low” (in terms of book-to-market ratio) and “winners” and “losers” (in terms of the past month’s market performance), which are the basis for the SMB, HML and MOM factors. This leads to the following equation in prices:

$$\begin{aligned} P_{it}= P_{ft}\cdot e^{\alpha t}\cdot \left(\frac{P_{mt}}{P_{ft}} \right)^{\beta _{1}} \cdot \left(\frac{P_{t}^{small}}{P_{t}^{big}} \right)^{\beta _{2}} \cdot \left(\frac{P_{t}^{high}}{P_{t}^{low}} \right)^{\beta _{3}} \cdot \left(\frac{P_{t}^{growth}}{P_{t}^{blue}} \right)^{\beta _{4}} \equiv \Gamma _{t} \end{aligned}$$
(A.5)

Following the same steps as above and using the definitions of the four factors, this becomes Eq. (3) defined in returns.

The RHS of () does not include any firm-specific information but only depends on aggregate market data. We now introduce firm-specific information. Specifically, we include industry-level stock prices \(P_{it}^{sic}\), the CCX carbon price \(P_{t}^{C}\), and dummies indicating CCX membership \(M_{it}\) (1 for CCX members, 0 otherwise) and the passing of the Waxman–Markey bill \(W_{t}\) (1 for June 2009, 0 otherwise). Since the effect of the carbon price and Waxman–Markey can be expected to differ between members and nonmembers, we also include interaction terms. In order to be consistent (both in terms of theory and math) with the four-factor model, we add these terms multiplicatively to the price equation:

$$\begin{aligned} P_{it} =\Gamma _{t} \cdot e^{\gamma _{1} M_{it}} \cdot e^{\gamma _{2} W_{t}} \cdot e^{\gamma _{3} M_{it} W_{t}} \cdot \left(\frac{P_{it}^{sic}}{P_{ft}}\right)^{\delta _{1}}\cdot \left(P_{t}^{C}\right)^{\delta _{2}}\cdot \left(P_{t}^{C}\right)^{\delta _{3}M_{it}} \end{aligned}$$
(A.6)

Taking logs and differentiating w.r.t time:

$$\begin{aligned} \begin{aligned}\frac{\dot{P}_{it}}{P_{it}}&= \frac{\dot{\Gamma }_{t}}{\Gamma _{t}} + \gamma _{1} \dot{M}_{it} + \gamma _{2} \dot{W}_{t} + \gamma _{3}\left( \dot{M}_{it}W_{t} +{M}_{it}\dot{W}_{t} \right)\nonumber \\&\quad +\,\delta _{1}\left(\frac{\dot{P}_{it}^{sic}}{{P}_{it}^{sic}} -\frac{\dot{P}_{ft}}{P_{ft}}\right) +\delta _{2}\frac{\dot{P}_{t}^{C}}{{P}_{t}^{C}} +\delta _{3}\left(M_{it}\frac{\dot{P}_{t}^{C}}{{P}_{t}^{C}}+\dot{M}_{it} ln \left(P_{t}^{C}\right)\right) \end{aligned} \end{aligned}$$
(A.7)

Substituting for \(\Gamma _{t}\), discretizing and using the fact that all member firms joined CCX before June 2009 (implying that \(\Delta M_{it}W_{t-1}=0\,\forall t\)) leads to the following specification:

$$\begin{aligned} \begin{aligned}&\frac{\Delta P_{it}}{P_{it-1}}- \frac{\Delta P_{ft}}{P_{ft-1}} \nonumber \\&\quad =\alpha +{\beta _{1}} \left(\frac{\Delta P_{mt}}{P_{mt-1}} -\frac{\Delta P_{ft}}{P_{ft-1}}\right) +{\beta _{2}} \left(\frac{\Delta P_{t}^{small}}{P_{t-1}^{small}} -\frac{\Delta P_{t}^{big}}{P_{t-1}^{big}}\right) \nonumber \\&\quad \quad +{\beta _{3}} \left(\frac{\Delta P_{t}^{high}}{P_{t-1}^{high}} -\frac{\Delta P_{t}^{low}}{P_{t-1}^{low}}\right)\, +{\beta _{4}} \left(\frac{\Delta P_{t}^{growth}}{P_{t-1}^{growth}} -\frac{\Delta P_{t}^{blue}}{P_{t-1}^{blue}}\right) \nonumber \\&\quad \quad + \gamma _{1}\Delta M_{it}+ \gamma _{2}\Delta W_{t} + \gamma _{3}\Delta M_{it-1}\Delta W_{t} \nonumber \\&\quad \quad + \delta _{1}\left(\frac{\Delta {P}_{it}^{sic}}{{P}_{it-1}^{sic}} -\frac{\Delta {P}_{ft}}{P_{ft-1}}\right) +\delta _{2}\frac{\Delta {P}_{t}^{C}}{{P}_{t-1}^{C}} +\delta _{3}\left(M_{it-1}\frac{\Delta {P}_{t}^{C}}{{P}_{t-1}^{C}}+\Delta {M}_{it} ln \left(P_{t-1}^{C}\right)\right)\qquad \end{aligned} \end{aligned}$$
(A.8)

Writing the proportional first differences as returns and substituting the definitions of the SMB, HML and MOM factors, this becomes Eq. (4).

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Cite this article

Gans, W., Hintermann, B. Market Effects of Voluntary Climate Action by Firms: Evidence from the Chicago Climate Exchange. Environ Resource Econ 55, 291–308 (2013). https://doi.org/10.1007/s10640-012-9626-7

Download citation

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s10640-012-9626-7

Keywords

Navigation