Skip to main content
Log in

Is there a self-enforcing monetary constitution?

  • Original Paper
  • Published:
Constitutional Political Economy Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

A self-enforcing monetary constitution has rules that agents acting within the system will uphold even in the presence of deviations from ideal knowledge and complete benevolence. It thus does not require external enforcement. What would such a constitution look like? I show that two regimes—a version of nominal gross domestic product targeting that relies on market implementation of monetary policy, and free banking—meet these requirements for self-enforcing monetary constitutions. The analysis draws insights from political economy, and from constitutional political economy in particular.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. Boettke and Luther (2009) argue that these two positions are reconcilable.

  2. Horwitz (2011) argues that market forces can devise a stable and predictable monetary order. I will revisit this claim in a subsequent section.

  3. Anna Schwartz (1987: 391) defines a monetary constitution as any established rule for monetary policy, which may or may not be formally embodied in a written document. This is how “monetary constitution” ought to be understood in this paper.

  4. The necessity of an explicit constitutional provision for gold was deemed necessary due to the central banks’ history of suspending redemption (Jonung 1984: 368).

  5. This obviously does not definitively show the inferiority of commodity standards in terms of insularity from political forces. But it does show that explicit constitutionalization is not a sufficient condition for insulation from these forces.

  6. Treaty on the Functioning of the European Union, Article 127(1).

  7. Inflation is measured by the Harmonized Index of Consumer prices (HICP), data for which is also available at the ECB’s website.

  8. The range of inflation above the 2 % target begins in December 2010 and continues today, although the most recent data shows falling inflation. As of this writing, the most recent estimate is 2.2 %.

  9. Technically, the ECB’s constitution mandates price stability without mentioning a specific inflation rate. However, it is clear the ECB’s governing council interprets price stability as 2 % inflation or less (European Central Bank 2011).

  10. This issue is inherent in all questions that fall within the scope of constitutional political economy (e.g. Brennan and Buchanan 2000).

  11. As an example, the Fed during its earliest years resembled a club environment, albeit imperfectly. The Federal Reserve System was originally intended to be a formalization of the interbank clearing mechanism. Individual reserve banks faced a quasi-budget constraint, operated in a decentralized environment with each reserve bank conducting open market operations based off of local conditions, and individual member banks could self-sort by choosing whether to be a part of the system. A true club-like scenario would feature even more decentralization and privatization, but the early Fed still came much closer to this standard than it does currently.

  12. Whether this is true net of switching costs is a question I relegate to a later section of the paper.

  13. Buchanan (1962), writing before the development of the robust political economy literature, argues for predictability as a chief criterion of a monetary constitution.

  14. See also Greenfield and Yeager (1983) for another take on institutional arrangements that yield stable money.

  15. Of course, this increase in purchasing power overlies many changes in relative prices, based on the productivity gains in specific sectors at the micro level.

  16. It is important to note that agents concerned with maintaining their money’s purchasing power would still be able to engage in post-constitutional contractual arrangements, such as purchasing inflation-indexed securities, to maintain that purchasing power. A monetary order that did not institutionalize monetary neutrality would be much more disruptive, and render such contracting much more difficult (costly). This is another argument for placing monetary equilibrium at a higher level of importance than stable purchasing power.

  17. The financial crisis has seen central banks adopt untraditional measures to combat deflation and unemployment, but the underlying paradigm remains the same. The theoretical justification for interest rates as the implementation mechanism is given in Woodford (2003).

  18. This is extraordinarily unlikely due to the fact individuals change their behavior in response to changing policy environments; the constants aren’t so constant after all (Lucas 1976).

  19. Stanford’s John Taylor is such an economist (e.g. Taylor 2007), as is Anna Schwartz (2009).

  20. This is a signal-extraction problem akin to the one made famous by Lucas (1972).

  21. In addition, Mankiw also counsels skepticism regarding the extent to which the rules versus discretion debate has influenced central banking in practice. “[T]he institutional changes we have observed are at best loosely connected to the issues raised in the theoretical literature” (Mankiw 2006: 16).

  22. See also Boettke and Smith (2012).

  23. Proponents of a Taylor Rule will be pleased to discover that a generalized version of this rule is a special case of NGDP targeting (Koenig 2012).

  24. Hendrickson’s (2012) view that NGDP targeting can be viewed as a “technology” for achieving monetary equilibrium is characteristic of Market Monetarism. However, insights from Hayek’s (1948) work on knowledge and the price mechanism suggest that the process by which NGDP is generated and sustained matters, and as such NGDP as a choice variable for a central bank is not the same thing as NGDP as the emergent outcome of market processes. This distinction has been noted elsewhere (Salter 2013a) but will not receive further treatment here.

  25. See also Sumner (1989, 2006).

  26. This may be some fraction of NGDP. As of the time of writing, U.S. NGDP is approximately $16 trillion. The initial price of each contract could be, say, one one-billionth of this value, adjusted for the particular form of the desired NGDP target. Even simpler, at the start of the regime, NGDP could be normalized to one, with subsequent values decided by the desired percentage growth of target NGDP. Also, it is assumed throughout that the monetary authority is the monopoly provider of base money, and can near-costlessly create or destroy additional balances, akin to the Fed’s actions when conducting open market operations by electronically altering banks’ account balances held at the Fed.

  27. This payment scheme is what leads Dowd (1994: 829) to refer to the contracts as Quasi-Futures Contracts (QFCs). In “real” futures contracts, payment is made at the time of maturity. In this case, payment at the time of the bargain is necessary to anchor the underlying variable which is being targeted.

  28. Because monetary policy is actually implemented by market actors, this scheme avoids the “circularity problem” outlined by Bernanke and Woodford (1997). However, the “first mover” problem discussed by Garrison and White (1997) is still a potential issue. Sumner (2006: 17–22) discusses ways this problem can be ameliorated.

  29. The evolution of free banking systems shows a remarkable degree of homogeneity across time and space. See the essays in Dowd (1992) for specific historical cases.

  30. Cf. White (1989: 231): “Eventually all the banks within an economy will be connected through one or a small number of clearinghouses … [t]he histories of the best-known early clearinghouses, in London, Edinburgh, and New York, all conform to this general pattern…”.

  31. This response is especially noteworthy, given the U.S. system at the time was constrained by regulations that rendered the money supply extremely inelastic to changes in money demand (Smith 1990: Ch. 5).

  32. See also White (1995: 27–29) for a description of how the Edinburgh clearinghouse prevented the failure of the Ayr Bank from crashing Scotland’s free banking system.

  33. That a specific monetary constitution is unnecessary does not imply that the general constitution need not have provisions preventing government interference with the monetary order. Cf. Horwitz (2011: 332): “A constitution might expressly prohibit the state from playing such a role, much as the First Amendment to the US Constitution does with respect to speech.”

  34. A third possibility may exist: instead of “scrapping” the Fed, the monetary base can be frozen at its current level and serve as the medium of redemption upon which banks can issue their own liabilities. This is basically free banking with Federal Reserve notes, rather than gold, serving as the monetary base. The Fed would be reduced to just one bank among many, forced to compete to survive (Selgin 1985). This would economize on switching costs, but there is some worry that, by preserving any of the Fed’s institutional structure, it would then be less costly for politicians to restore the Fed’s monopoly status. This is the same problem that plagues the NGDP targeting regime described above.

  35. Cf Brennan and Buchanan (2000: 4): “What advice can we offer ourselves in our own societies, standing as we do with the benefits of cooperation and the prospects of conflict on either hand? What aspects of our social life should we discard? Where are there "rules of social order"—institutional arrangements governing our interactions—that lead us to affect one another adversely? Where are there forces for harmony that can be mobilized? What rules—and what institutions—should we be struggling to preserve?… These questions represent the area of inquiry we term "constitutional political economy" (in the spirit of the classical political economists, for whom such questions were also central).”

References

  • Barro, R. J., & Gordon, D. B. (1983). A positive theory of monetary policy in a natural rate model. Journal of Political Economy, 91(4), 589–610.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Beckworth, D. (2012). How the Fed’s mishandling of the productivity boom helped pave the way for the housing boom. In D. Beckworth (Ed.), Boom and bust banking: The causes and cures of the great recession. Oakland: Independent Institute.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bernanke, B. S., & Mihov, I. (1998). Measuring monetary policy. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 113(3), 869–902.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bernanke, B., & Woodford, M. (1997). Inflation forecasts and monetary policy. Journal of Money, Credit, and Banking, 29(4), 653–684.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Boettke, P. J., & Coyne, C. J. (2010). The debt–inflation cycle and the global financial crisis. Working Paper. http://papers.ssrn.com/sol3/papers.cfm?abstract_id=1729228.

  • Boettke, P. J., & Luther, W. J. (2009). The ordinary economics of an extraordinary crisis. In S. Kates (Ed.), Macroeconomic theory and its failings: Alternative perspectives on the global financial crisis. Cheltenham: Edward Elgar.

    Google Scholar 

  • Boettke, P. J., & Smith, D. J. (2012). Monetary policy and the quest for robust political economy. Working Paper. http://ssrn.com/abstract=1720682.

  • Boettke, P. J., & Smith, D. J. (2013). A century of influence: An anecdotal history of compromised federal reserve independence. Working Paper. http://papers.ssrn.com/sol3/papers.cfm?abstract_id=2135233.

  • Brennan, G., & Buchanan, J. (2000). The reason of rules: Constitutional political economy (Collected Works of James Buchanan, Vol. 10). Indianapolis: Liberty Fund.

  • Buchanan, J. (1962). Predictability: The criterion of monetary constitutions. In L. B. Yeager (Ed.), In search of a monetary constitution. Cambridge: Harvard University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Buchanan, J. (2010). The constitutionalization of money. Cato Journal, 30(2), 251–258.

    Google Scholar 

  • Buchanan, J., & Wagner, R. (2000). Democracy in deficit: The political legacy of Lord Keynes (Collected Works of James Buchanan, Vol. 8). Indianapolis: Liberty Fund.

  • Buiter, W. H. (2008). Central banks and financial crises. Paper presented at the Federal Reserve Bank of Kansas City’s symposium on “Maintaining stability in a changing financial system”, at Jackson Hole, Wyoming, on August 21–23, 2008.

  • Cargill, T. F., & O’Driscoll, G. P, Jr. (2013). Federal reserve independence: Reality or myth? Cato Journal, 33(3), 417–435.

    Google Scholar 

  • Christensen, L. (2011). Market monetarism: The second monetarist counter-revolution. Working Paper. http://thefaintofheart.files.wordpress.com/2011/09/market-Monetarism-13092011.pdf.

  • Diamond, D. W., & Dybvig, P. H. (1983). Bank runs, deposit insurance, and liquidity. Journal of Political Economy, 91(3), 401–419.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dixit, A. (1991). Irreversible investment with price ceilings. Journal of Political Economy, 99(3), 541–557.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dixit, A. (1992). Investment and hysteresis. Journal of Economic Perspectives, 6(1), 107–132.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dixit, A. (1995). Irreversible investment with uncertainty and scale economies. Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control, 19(1–2), 327–350.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dixit, A., & Pindyck, R. (1994). Investment under uncertainty. Princeton: Princeton University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Dowd, K. (Ed.). (1992). The experience of free banking. London: Routledge.

    Google Scholar 

  • Dowd, K. (1994). A proposal to end inflation. Economic Journal, 104(425), 828–840.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dowd, K. (2009). Moral hazard and the financial crisis. Cato Journal, 29(1), 141–166.

    Google Scholar 

  • Espinoza, D. (2012). Chain Reaction: How the fed’s asymmetric policy in 2003 led to a panic in 2008. In D. Beckworth (Ed.), Boom and bust banking: The causes and cures of the great recession. Oakland: Independent Institute.

  • European Central Bank. (2011). Benefits of price stability. http://www.ecb.europa.eu/mopo/intro/benefits/html/index.en.html. Accessed 23 Apr 2014.

  • Fink, A. (2011). Free banking as an evolving system: The case of Switzerland reconsidered. Working Paper. http://papers.ssrn.com/sol3/papers.cfm?abstract_id=1751832.

  • Friedman, M., & Schwartz, A. J. (1963). A monetary history of the United States, 1867–1960. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Garrison, R. (2001). Time and money: The macroeconomics of capital structure. London: Routledge.

    Google Scholar 

  • Garrison, R., & White, L. H. (1997). Can monetary stabilization policy be improved by CPI futures targeting? Journal of Money, Credit, and Banking, 29(4), 535–541.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gorton, G. (1985). Clearinghouses and the origins of central banking in the United States. Journal of Economic History, 45(2), 277–283.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gorton, G. (1988). Banking panics and business cycles. Oxford Economic Papers, 40(4), 751–781.

    Google Scholar 

  • Gorton, G. (2010). Slapped by the invisible hand: The panic of 2007. New York: Oxford University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Gorton, G., & Mullineaux, D. J. (1987). The joint production of confidence: Endogenous regulation and nineteenth century commercial-bank clearinghouses. Journal of Money, Credit, and Banking, 19(4), 457–468.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Greenfield, R., & Yeager, L. (1983). A laissez-faire approach to monetary stability. Journal of Money, Credit, and Banking, 15(3), 302–315.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hayek, F. A. (1931). Prices and production. London: Routledge and Sons.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hayek, F. A. (1948). Individualism and economic order. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hayek, F. A. (1979). The counter-revolution of science: Studies on the abuse of reason. Indianapolis: Liberty Fund.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hendrickson, J. R. (2012). Nominal income targeting and monetary stability. In D. Beckworth (Ed.), Boom and bust banking: The causes and cures of the great recession. Oakland: Independent Institute.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hetzel, R. L. (1997). The case for a monetary rule in a constitutional democracy. Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond Economic Quarterly, 83(2), 45–65.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hetzel, R. L. (2012). The great recession: Market failure or policy failure?. New York: Cambridge University Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Horwitz, S. G. (2000). Microfoundations and macroeconomics: An Austrian perspective. London: Routledge.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Horwitz, S. G. (2011). Do we need a distinct monetary constitution? Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization, 80(2), 331–338.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Horwitz, S. G., & Luther, W. J. (2011). The great recession and its aftermath from a monetary equilibrium theory perspective. In S. Kates (Ed.), The global financial crisis: What have we learnt?. Aldershot: Edward Elgar.

    Google Scholar 

  • Issing, O. (2000). Hayek, Currency Competition and European Monetary Union. IEA Occasional Paper, Vol. 111, 61 pp.

  • Jonung, L. (1984). The Swedish experience under the classical gold standard, 1873–1914. In M. D. Bordo & A. J. Schwartz (Eds.), A retrospective on the classical gold standard, 1821–1931. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Koenig, E. F. (2012). All in the family: The close connection between NGDP-targeting and the Taylor rule. Federal Reserve Bank of Dallas StaffPAPERS, 17, 1–9.

    Google Scholar 

  • Kydland, F. E., & Prescott, E. C. (1977). Rules rather than discretion: The inconsistency of optimal plans. Journal of Political Economy, 85(3), 473–492.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kydland, F. E., & Wynne, M. A. (2002). Alternative monetary constitutions and the quest for price stability. Federal Reserve Bank of Dallas Economic and Financial Policy Review, 1(1), 1–19.

    Google Scholar 

  • Leeson, P. T. (2012). Government, clubs, and constitutions. Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization, 80(2), 301–308.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Leeson, P. T., & Robert Subrick, J. (2006). Robust political economy. Review of Austrian Economics, 19(2), 107–111.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lucas, R. (1972). Expectations and the neutrality of money. Journal of Economic Theory, 4(2), 103–124.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lucas, R. (1976). Econometric policy evaluation: A critique. In K. Brunner & A. Meltzer (Eds.), The Phillips curve and labor markets. Amsterdam: North Holland.

    Google Scholar 

  • Luther, W. J. (2013). Friedman versus Hayek on private outside monies: New evidence for the debate. Economic Affairs, 31(1), 127–135.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Luther, W. J., & White, L. H. (2011). Positively-valued fiat money after the sovereign disappears: The case of Somalia. Working Paper. http://papers.ssrn.com/sol3/papers.cfm?abstract_id=1801563.

  • Mankiw, N. G. (2006). The macroeconomist as scientist and engineer. NBER Working Paper No. 12349. http://www.nber.org/papers/w12349.

  • Nunes, M., & Cole, B. (2013). Market monetarism: Roadmap to economic prosperity (self-published).

  • Pennington, M. (2011). Robust political economy: Classical liberalism and the future of public policy. Cheltenham: Edward Elgar.

    Google Scholar 

  • Ravier, A., & Lewin, P. (2012). The subprime crisis. Quarterly Journal of Austrian Economics, 15(1), 45–74.

    Google Scholar 

  • Roberts, R. (2010). Gambling with other people’s money: How perverted incentives created the financial crisis. Arlington, VA: Mercatus Center.

  • Salter, A. W. (2013a). Not All NGDP is created equal: A critique of market monetarism. Journal of Private Enterprise, 29(1), 41–52.

  • Salter, A. W. (2013b). Robust political economy and the lender of last resort. Working paper. http://papers.ssrn.com/sol3/papers.cfm?abstract_id=2246176.

  • Salter, A. W., & Luther, W. J. (2012). Monetary equilibrium and price stickiness reconsidered: A reply to Bagus and Howden. Review of Austrian Economics, 25(3), 263–269.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Schwartz, A. J. (1987). Lessons of the gold standard era and the Bretton Woods system for the prospects of an international monetary constitution. In A. Schwartz (Ed.), Money in historical perspective. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.

    Chapter  Google Scholar 

  • Schwartz, A. J. (2009). Origins of the financial market crisis of 2008. Cato Journal, 29(1), 19–23.

    Google Scholar 

  • Selgin, G. (1985). The case for free banking: Then and now. Cato Policy Analysis No. 60. http://www.cato.org/pubs/pas/pa060.html.

  • Selgin, G. (1988). The theory of free banking: Money supply under competitive note issue. Totowa: Rowman and Littlefield.

    Google Scholar 

  • Selgin, G. A. (1997). Less than zero: The case for a falling price level in a growing economy. London: Institute of Economic Affairs.

    Google Scholar 

  • Selgin, G. A. (2010). The futility of central banking. Cato Journal, 30(3), 465–473.

    Google Scholar 

  • Selgin, G. A. (2012). L Street: Bagehotian prescriptions for a 21st-century money market. Cato Journal, 32(2), 303–332.

    Google Scholar 

  • Selgin, G., & White, L. H. (1994). How would the invisible hand handle money? Journal of Economic Literature, 32(4), 1718–1749.

    Google Scholar 

  • Smith, A. 1776 [1982]. An inquiry into the nature and causes of the wealth of nations (Vol. 2). Indianapolis: Liberty Fund.

  • Smith, V. (1990). The rationale of central banking and the free banking alternative. Indianapolis: Liberty Fund.

    Google Scholar 

  • Sumner, S. (1989). Using futures instrument prices to target nominal income. Bulletin of Economic Research, 41(2), 157–162.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Sumner, S. (2006). Let a thousand models bloom: The advantages of making the FOMC a truly ‘open market’. Contributions to Macroeconomics, 6(1): Article 8.

  • Sumner, S. (2011). Re-targeting the fed. National Affairs 9(Fall). http://www.nationalaffairs.com/doclib/20110919_Sumner.pdf.

  • Sumner, S. (2012). How nominal GDP targeting could have prevented the crash of 2008. In D. Beckworth (Ed.), Boom and bust banking: The causes and cures of the great recession. Oakland: Independent Institute.

    Google Scholar 

  • Taylor, J. B. (2007). Housing and monetary policy. NBER Working Paper Series. http://www.nber.org/papers/w13682.

  • Taylor, J. B. (2009). Getting off track: How government actions and intervention caused, prolonged, and worsened the financial crisis. Stanford: Hoover Institution Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Taylor, J. B. (2012, 29 March). The dangers of an interventionist Fed. The Wall Street Journal. http://online.wsj.com/article/SB10001424052702303816504577307403971824094.html. Accessed March 7, 2013.

  • Timberlake, R. H, Jr. (1984). The central banking role of clearinghouse associations. Journal of Money, Credit, and Banking, 16(1), 1–16.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Tornell, A. (2012). The dynamic tragedy-of-the-commons in the Eurozone, the ECB and Target2 imbalances. Working paper.

  • White, L. H. (1989). Competition and currency: Essays on free banking and money. New York: New York University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • White, L. H. (1995). Free banking in Britain: Theory, experience, and debate, 1800–1845 (2nd ed.). London: Institute of Economic Affairs.

    Google Scholar 

  • White, L. H. (2008). How did we get into this financial mess? Cato Briefing Papers No. 110.

  • White, L. H. (2009). Federal reserve policy and the housing bubble. Cato Journal, 29(1), 115–125.

    Google Scholar 

  • White, L. H. (2011). The Euro’s problems are fundamental. American Institute for Economic Research Economic Bulletins (August 1). https://www.aier.org/article/2514-euro%E2%80%99s-problems-are-fundamental.

  • White, L. H. (2012). Monetary policy and the financial crisis. In D. Beckworth (Ed.), Boom and bust banking: The causes and cures of the great recession. Oakland: Independent Institute.

    Google Scholar 

  • Woodford, M. (2003). Interest and prices. Princeton: Princeton University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Yeager, L. B. (1956). A cash-balance interpretation of depression. Southern Economic Journal, 22(4), 438–447.

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Alexander William Salter.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Salter, A.W. Is there a self-enforcing monetary constitution?. Const Polit Econ 25, 280–300 (2014). https://doi.org/10.1007/s10602-014-9163-1

Download citation

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s10602-014-9163-1

Keywords

JEL Classification

Navigation