Skip to main content

Advertisement

Log in

Is it all about competence? The human capital of U.S. presidents and economic performance

  • Original Paper
  • Published:
Constitutional Political Economy Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

This paper explores the extent to which human capital improves the economic policy competence of US presidents. Several recent studies have used international data to test similar hypotheses. However, international studies suffer from a variety of comparability issues, not all of which can be avoided through fixed effects and error correction. The US results developed in this paper suggest that both career paths and education have significant effects on a president’s economic policy judgment, particularly in the period after the Civil War. However, the paper also suggests that more than good economic management skills are required to win national elections.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. A “Yellow Dog Democrat” is a person who would vote for a yellow dog (listed as a Democratic candidate), rather than a Republican candidate.

  2. An early version of this paper was presented at the 2008 meetings of the Public Choice Society, where several useful comments were received. Subsequent versions of the paper have been posted on Social Science Research Network website since 2009.

  3. This slogan was used by the Republican Party during Hoover’s 1928 campaign for office along with “vote for prosperity.”

  4. Even in this case, presidential competence may influence policy choices at the margin. In their empirical estimations, Alesina and Rosenthal include the “components of competence” in the error term, because these components cannot be observed separately by the voters. The variance/covariance structure is used to examine whether “a change in party control of the White House makes a difference in aggregate economic growth in the year following the election.” This model of partisan administrative policy effectiveness is rejected by their analysis (Alesina and Rosenthal 1995: 216).

  5. See Bordo and Rockoff (1996) for an overview of modifications to the Gold Standard during the nineteenth and early twentieth centuries and of the effects that such policies had on international capital flows. See Cleveland and Powell (1909) for a thorough overview of state and national subsidies to US railroads.

  6. A second reason to exclude the post 2000 observations is an apparent data entry error in the Mitchell series. Mitchell (2003), suggests that the average growth rate of GNP person during George H. W. Bush’s term was as high as 9.5 %. In contrast, the averaged growth rate of GDP per capita was only 0.7 %; hence, it is obviously a typographical error in Mitchell (2003). (If we include the entry for George H. W. Bush, the correlation between the Mitchell and Maddison per capita GDP series decreases to 0.8707.)

  7. A regression between a president’s average growth rate of real per capita GNP on the previous president’s average in the 1870–2009 period yields: dYt = 0.02747 − 0.059dYt−1 with a t-statistic of 4.89 for the constant and of −3.23 for the coefficient. The coefficient should have been zero (statistically) if the dY series were stationary. The R2 for this regression is 0.31 and the DW is 2.14. Because it is unlikely that a “competent” president is always followed by an incompetent one, the most likely explanation is that business cycles occur for exogenous reasons but around a classical long-run steady-state growth path. Note that without shocks, the fact that the coefficient is less than one implies that, in the long run, the series is asymptotically stable (stationary) and would converge to the constant term, 0.02747, which can be interpreted as the long-run equilibrium growth rate of classical models (here, 2.7 %/year).

  8. Military governors included Andrew Jackson and Andrew Johnson.

  9. Martin van Buren.

  10. After 1870, observations share the score of 0 on secretary of state, so we omit this variable from the estimates in Table 4.

  11. When we distinguish between “Yrs House” and “Yrs Senate” and re-run years 4, we observe that both variables have positive but insignificant coefficients. The t statistic equals to 1.31 for “Yrs House,” and 0.76 for “Yrs Senate.”

  12. Among the many pooling problems are assumptions that implicitly require institutions to be stable in the period of interest. Otherwise, country-fixed effects will not capture all relevant institutional differences. Political and economic institutions, however, changed at different rates during the 50 year period after 1875. Moreover, some of those changes may reflect the same leadership characteristics focused on in the international studies focusing on economic growth and political success (Hayo and Voigt 2013).

References

  • Alesina, A., & Rosenthal, H. (1995). Partisan politics, divided government, and the economy. New York, NY: Cambridge University Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Berger, M. M., Munger, M. C., & Potthoff, R. F. (2000). The downsian model predicts divergence. Journal of Theoretical Politics, 12, 228–240.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Besley, T. (2006). Principled agents? The political economy of good government. New York, NY: Oxford University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Besley, T., Montalvo, J., & Reynal-Querol, M. (2011). Do educated leaders matter? Economic Journal, 121, 205–227.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Besley, T., & Reynal-Querol, M. (2011). Do democracies select more educated leaders? American Political Science Review, 105, 552–556.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bordo, M. D., & Rockoff, H. (1996). The gold standard as a ‘good housekeeping’ seal of approval. Journal of Economic History, 56, 389–428.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Checchi, D. (2006). The economics of education: Human capital, family background, and inequality. New York, NY: Cambridge University Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Cleveland, F. A., & Powell, F. W. (1909). Railroad promotion and capitalization in the United States. New York, NY: Longmans, Green, and Co.

    Google Scholar 

  • Congleton, R. D. (2007). Informational limits to democratic public policy: The jury theorem, yardstick competition, and ignorance. Public Choice, 132, 333–352.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Glass, D. P. (1985). Evaluating presidential candidates: Who focuses on their personal attributes? The Public Opinion Quarterly, 49, 517–534.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Groseclose, T. (2001). A model of candidate location when one candidate has a valence advantage. American Journal of Political Science, 45, 862–886.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hayo, B., & Voigt, S. (2013). Endogenous constitutions: Politics and politicians matter, economic outcomes don’t. Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization, 88, 47–61.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hibbs, D. A. (1989). The American political economy: Macroeconomics and electoral politics in the United States. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Lowi, T., Ginsberg, B., & Shepsle, K. A. (2002). American government: Power and purpose (7th ed.). New York, NY: W. W. Norton & Company, Inc.

    Google Scholar 

  • MacRae, C. D. (1977). A political model of the business cycle. Journal of Political Economy, 85, 239–263.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Maddison, A. (2001). Development centre studies, The world economy: A millennial perspective. Paris, France: Organization for Economic Cooperation and Development.

  • Mitchell, B. R. (Ed.) (2003). International historical statistics (pp. 1750–2000). New York, NY: Palgrave.

  • Mondak, J. J. (1995). Competence, integrity, and the electoral success of congressional incumbents. Journal of Politics, 57, 1043–1069.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Nordaus, W. (1975). The political business cycle. Review of Economic Studies, 51, 169–190.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Peffley, M. (1989). Presidential image and economic performance: A dynamic analysis. Political Behavior, 11, 309–333.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ridings, W. J., Jr., & McIver, S. B. (1997). Rating the presidents: A ranking of U.S. leaders, from the great and honorable to the dishonest and incompetent. Secaucus, NJ: Citadel Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Simonton, D. K. (1988). Presidential style: Personality, biography, and performance. Journal of Personality and Social Psychology, 60, 607–619.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Simonton, D. K. (1995). Personality and intellectual predictors of leadership. In D. H. Saklofske & M. Zeidner (Eds.), International handbook of personality and intelligence (pp. 739–757). New York, NY: Plenum.

    Chapter  Google Scholar 

  • Simonton, D. K. (2006). Presidential IQ, openness, intellectual brilliance, and leadership: estimates and correlations for 42 U.S. chief executives. Political Psychology, 27, 511–526.

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Roger D. Congleton.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Cite this article

Congleton, R.D., Zhang, Y. Is it all about competence? The human capital of U.S. presidents and economic performance. Const Polit Econ 24, 108–124 (2013). https://doi.org/10.1007/s10602-013-9138-7

Download citation

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s10602-013-9138-7

Keywords

JEL Classification

Navigation