Skip to main content

Advertisement

Log in

Does Corruption Have Social Roots? The Role of Culture and Social Capital

  • Published:
Journal of Business Ethics Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

The aim of this work is to analyse the influence of sociocultural factors on corruption levels. Taking as starting point Husted (J Int Bus Studies 30:339–359, 1999) and Graeff (In: Lambsdorff J, Taube M, Schramm M (eds) The new institutional economics of corruption. Routledge, London, 2005) proposals, we consider both the interrelation between cultural dimensions and the diverse expressions of social capital with corruption. According to our results, the universalistic trust (linking and bridging social capital) constitutes a positive social capital that is negatively linked to corruption. In contrast, the particularistic levels of trust (bonding) can constitute a negative social capital directly related to corruption levels. Furthermore, cultures which are favourable to the legitimation of dependency relations and the formation of closed particularistic groups (power-distance and community factors) create a breeding ground for the development of these amoral rent-seeking structures.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Graph 1

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. With respect to Economics, corruption has been integrated into the research agenda for the last quarter of XX century, as international data on this problem emerged and the institutionalist research program was developed. The seminal works of Rose-Ackerman (1975, 1978) are an essential reference as the booting of a purely economic approach to the problems of corruption. Zamagni (1999) reviewed the main studies on the subject.

  2. However, the existence of divergent explanatory guidelines should be noted. Some studies have shown that the relationship between corruption and output levels are not monotonic (Kaufmann and Kraay 2002; Canavese 2006). According to these approaches, under certain circumstances of inefficiency in the functioning of government, corruption may be a second best that mitigates the deficiencies of the bureaucracy.

  3. In general, the appropriation by individuals of the instruments that the government has at its disposal reduces the state’s ability to play its role on market correction. To a certain extent, this process could be interpreted as a privatization of the state but without returning the role played to the market, and instead to bureaucracy (LaPorta et al. 1998; Tanzi 1998; Leite and Weidmann 1999). Moreover, reducing the discretion of public officials and the decentralization of authority has been significant insomuch as reducing corruption in economies penetrated by market relations (Johnson et al. 1998; Fisman and Gati 2002; Treisman 2000; Kranton 1996). At the same time, competition within the press and even political competition are very effective in reducing corruption. Thus, corruption is a particularly salient problem in authoritarian regimes (Treisman 2000).

  4. NSE affirms that it is inappropriate to consider corruption as the exclusive result of inadequate organizational and institutional framework. This proposal adopts the basic results of the New Institutional Economics (NIE) and its derivatives on Game Theory (transaction costs, probability of uncovering…) as a starting point, but completes them with an analysis of the cultural roots of corruption.

  5. Previous studies have applied the Hofstede model for modelling market ethics (Vitell et al. 1993), although the economic variables are not specifically included in them, limiting the analysis to the perception of ethical problems and the existence of informal codes of behaviour.

  6. In this respect it is noted that the larger the group the greater coercion, since the defection of a single member poses a risk to the others. This is the case of the mafia.

  7. Trust is measured as the percentage of the population that recognizes having trust in society as a whole (generalistic) or in a particular institution (family, unions…).

  8. The only factor that is irrelevant or not significant is the masculine-feminine dimension. This is the only variable that is independent of any other cultural and social expression. In fact, Hofstede (1999) himself believes that it integrates aspects that can have different manifestations regardless of the levels of development of a society.

  9. Horizontal associations are groups formed spontaneously between peers, on the contrary, vertical associationism is related with top-down groups directly linked with some forms of authority (political parties…).

  10. We applied ordinary least squares linear models using cross section data.

  11. The Global Economic Freedom Index is a pool indicator composed of several related indices.

  12. In all models we find a combination of high R 2 values and high significance of regressors, so that problems derived from the existence of multicollinearity are limited.

References

  • Akçay, S. (2006). Corruption and human development. Cato Journal, 26, 29–48.

    Google Scholar 

  • Becker, G. (1968). Crime and punishment: An economic approach. The Journal of Political Economy, 76, 169–217.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Becker, G., & Landes, W. (1974). Essays in the economics of crime and punishment. National Bureau of Economic Research.

  • Bjornskov, C. (2004). Corruption and social capital, Working Paper 03-13, Aarhus School of Business, Department of Economics.

  • Bourdieu, P. (1986). The forms of capital. In J. G. Richardson (Ed.), Handbook of theory and research for the sociology of education. New York: Greenwood.

    Google Scholar 

  • Canavese, A. J. (2006). Corrupción organizativa y asignación de recursos. Desarrollo Económico, 45, 473–485.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Coleman, J. (1988). Social capital and the creation of human capital. American Journal of Sociology, 94, 95–120.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fisman, R., & Gati, R. (2002). Decentralization and corruption: Evidence across countries. Public Choice, 83, 325–345.

    Google Scholar 

  • Freisitzer, K. (1981). Gesellschaftliche Bedingungen der Korruption—Versuch einer verhaltenswissenschaftlichen Deutung. In Brünner, C. (Ed.), Korruption und Kontrolle (S.151–163). Wien.

  • Geertz, C. (1957). Ritual and social change. American Anthropologist, 59, 32–54.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Goode, R. (1984). Government finance in developing countries. Washington, DC: Brookings Institute.

    Google Scholar 

  • Graeff, P. (2005). Why should one trust in corruption? The linkage between corruption, norms and social capital. In Lambsdorff, J., Taube, M., & Schramm, M. (Eds.), The new institutional economics of corruption. London: Routledge.

  • Griesshaber, N., & Geys, B. (2011). Civic engagement and corruption in 20 European democracies: Separating the bright form the dark side. Discussion Paper, WZB, Berlin.

  • Grootaert, Ch. (1998). Social capital: The missing link? Social Capital Initiative, Working Paper no. 3, Washington, DC: World Bank.

  • Hall, R., & Jones, C. I. (1999). Why do some countries produce so much more output per worker than others? Quarterly Journal of Economics, 114, 83–116.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hofstede, G. (1999). Culturas y organizaciones. El software mental. Madrid: Alianza Editorial.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hofstede, G. (2003). Culture’s consequences, comparing values, behaviors, institutions and organizations across nations (2nd ed.). Newbury Park: Sage.

  • Hunt, S., & Vitell, S. (1986). A general theory of marketing ethics. Journal of Macromarketing, 8, 5–16.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Husted, B. W. (1994). Honour among thieves: A transaction-cost interpretation of corruption in third world countries. Business Ethics Quarterly, IV, 17–27.

  • Husted, B. W. (1999). Wealth, culture and corruption. Journal of International Business Studies, 30, 339–359.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Jain, A. K. (2001). The political economy of corruption (pp. 111–141). New York: Routledge Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Johnson, S., Kaufmann, D., & Zoido-Lobaton, P. (1998). Regulatory discretion and the unofficial economy. American Economic Review, 88, 387–392.

    Google Scholar 

  • Kaufmann, D., & Kraay, A. (2002). Growth without gobernance. The World Bank Discussion Paper, Washington DC.

  • Kluckhohn, C. (1951). The study of culture. In: D. Lerner & H. D. Lasswell (Eds.), The policy sciences. Stanford: Stanford University Press.

  • Kluckhohn, C., Parsons, T., & Shils, E. (1951). Values and value-orientations in the theory of action, toward a general theory of action. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Kranton, R. E. (1996). Reciprocal exchange: A self-sustaining system. American Economic Review, 86, 830–851.

    Google Scholar 

  • Lambsdorff, J. G. (1998). Corruption in comparative perception. In: A. Jain (Ed.) Economics of corruption. Boston: Kluwer

  • Lambsdorff, J. G. (2002). Corruption and rent-seeking. Public Choice, 113, 97–125.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lambsdorff, J., Taube, M., & Schramm, M. (2005). Corrupt contracting: Exploring the analytical capacity of new institutional economics and new economic sociology. In: Lambsdorff, J., Taube, M., & Schramm, M. (Eds.), The new institutional economics of corruption. London: Routledge.

  • Laporta, R., Lopez-de-Silanes, F., Shleifer, A., & Vishny, R. (1998). Law and finance. Journal of Political Economy, 106, 1113–1155.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Leite, C., & Weidmann, J. (1999). Does mother nature corrupt? Natural resources, corruption and economic growth. IMF Working Paper 99/85.

  • Mauro, P. (1995). Corruption and growth. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 110, 681–712.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Olson, M. (1965). The logic of collective action. Cambridge: Harvard University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Ouchi, W. G. (1981). Theory Z: How American business can meet the Japanese challenge. Addison-Wesley.

  • Paldam, M. (2002). The cross-country pattern of corruption: Economics, culture and the seesaw dynamics. European Journal of Political Economy, 18, 215–240.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Paldam, M., & Svendsen, G. T. (2002). Missing social capital and the transition in Eastern Europe. Journal for Institutional Innovation, Development and Transition, 5, 21–34.

    Google Scholar 

  • Parsons, T., & Shils, E. (1990). Values and social systems. In: J. Alexander & S. Seidman (Eds.), Culture and society, contemporary debates. Cambridge University Press: New York.

  • Pena López, J. A., & Sánchez Santos, J. M. (2009). La dotación de capital social como factor determinante de la corrupción. Revista de Economía Mundial, 22, 197–220.

    Google Scholar 

  • Putnam, R. (1993). Making democracy work: Civic traditions in modern Italy. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Riley, S. (1998). The political of anticorruption strategies in Africa. In M. Robinson (Ed.), Corruption and development. London: Frank Cass.

    Google Scholar 

  • Rose-Ackerman, S. (1975). The economics of corruption. Journal of Public Economics, 4, 187–203.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Rose-Ackerman, S. (1978). Corruption. A study in political economy. New York: Academic Press.

  • Rose-Ackerman, S. (1999). Corruption and government. Causes, consequences, and reform. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

  • Rose-Ackerman, S. (2000). Is leaner government necessarily cleaner government? In: J. Tulchin & R. Espach (Eds.), Combating corruption in Latin America (pp. 87–104). Washington DC: W. Wilson Center Press.

  • Schwartz, S. (1994). Are there universal aspects in the structure and content of human values? Journal of Social Issues, 50, 19–45.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Seleim, A., & Bontis, N. (2009). The relationship between culture and corruption: A cross-national study. Journal of Intellectual Capital, 10, 165–184.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Sen, A. K. (1997). Economics, business principles and moral sentiments. Business Ethics Quarterly, 7, 5–15.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Shihata, I. (2000). The role of the World Bank in combating corruption In: J. Tulchin & R. Espach (Eds.), Combating corruption in Latin America (pp. 205–209). Washington DC: W. Wilson Center Press.

  • Tanzi, V. (1994). Corruption, government activities, and markets. IMF Working Paper No. 94/99.

  • Tanzi, V. (1998). Corruption around the world causes, consequences, scope, and cures. IMF Staff Papers. 45, 4.

  • Tönnies, F. (1947). Comunidad y sociedad. Losada: Buenos Aires.

    Google Scholar 

  • Treisman, D. (2000). The causes of corruption: A cross-national study. Journal of Public Economics, 73, 399–457.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Uslaner, E. (2002). The moral foundations of trust. New York: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Uslaner, E. (2005). Trust and corruption. In J. Lambsdorff, M. Taube, & M. Schramm (Eds.), The new institutional economics of corruption. London: Routledge.

  • Vitell, S., Nwachukwu, S., & Barnes, J. (1993). The effects of culture on ethical decision-making: An application of Hofstede’s typology. Journal of Business Ethics, 10, 753–760.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Weber, M. (1964). Economía y Sociedad. Méjico: FCE.

    Google Scholar 

  • Woolcock, M. (2001). The place of social capital in understanding social and economic outcomes. Canadian Journal of Policy Research, 2, 1492–1525.

    Google Scholar 

  • Zamagni, S. (1999). The economics of corruption and illegal markets. Cheltenham, E. Elgar, 3 Vols.

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to José Atilano Pena López.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Cite this article

Pena López, J.A., Sánchez Santos, J.M. Does Corruption Have Social Roots? The Role of Culture and Social Capital. J Bus Ethics 122, 697–708 (2014). https://doi.org/10.1007/s10551-013-1789-9

Download citation

  • Received:

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s10551-013-1789-9

Keywords

Navigation