Skip to main content
Log in

Inequity-averse agents’ deserved concerns under the linear contract: a social network setting

  • S.I.: BOM in Social Networks
  • Published:
Annals of Operations Research Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

We model how inequity-averse agents’ deserved concerns generated by a social network setting impact on their behaviors and interactions under linear contract. Based on self-perception in the network, the agent will have deserved perception on the two essential elements of linear contract, i.e., deserved fixed wage and deserved output sharing, and thus generate deserved pay gap. By incorporating deserved pay gap into pay comparisons, we obtain three main findings: (1) perceived relative incentive fairness or inequity over the entire networks decides agents’ effort competition. When agents perceive over-incentivized over the networks, the heterogeneity in the network will stimulate agents to compete. While in an overall under-incentivized network, the agent tends to compete with homogenous ones, and will instead reduce effort with increasing heterogeneity in the network; (2) the normal conclusion that inequity aversion can enhance agent effort will be reversed when the agent perceives under-incentivized; and (3) wage compression remains valid, yet we provide a definitive range for the optimal incentive level.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1
Fig. 2
Fig. 3
Fig. 4

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. For instance, Jackson (2007) argued that “The rise of what one might refer to as ‘social economics’ comes very much from the realization by economists that there are many economic interactions where the social context is not a second-order consideration, but is actually a primary driver of behaviors and outcomes.”

  2. Bolton and Ockenfels (2000) proposed the ERC model to measure a player’s inequity aversion by comparing one’s relative payoff with those of opponents, in which the players cared about their own relative shares of total payoff, although Fehr and Schmidt (1999)’s model was cited more often in subsequent studies. Further, the ERC model failed to take account of people’s deserved concerns about the level of pay that they deserved.

  3. However, even if the principal provides different contracts to agents, it implies the principal’s different comprehensive judgments on agents. Such different judgments versus identical contract will be more likely to trigger agents’ deserved concerns about the pay that they deserve.

  4. We posit that \(\beta +p_i \) is always above zero proceeding from the reality. In practical terms, a very low negative \(p_i \) such that \(\beta +p_i \) implies that the agent feels significantly under-incentivized. In this case, the agent is more likely to quit. When \(\lambda _i >1\), a much higher \(\lambda _i \) may lead to \(\beta +\lambda _i p_i <0\).

References

  • Bartling, B. (2011). Relative performance or team evaluation? Optimal contracts for other-regarding agents. Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization, 79(3), 183–193.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bartling, B., & Siemens, F. V. (2004). Inequity aversion and moral hazard with multiple agents. http://www.uibk.ac.at/economics/bbl/bbl/bartling.paper.pdf. Accessed 5 April 2015.

  • Basu, A. K., Lal, R., Srinivasan, V., & Staelin, R. (1985). Salesforce compensation plans: An agency theoretic perspective. Marketing Science, 4(4), 267–291.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bolton, G. E., & Ockenfels, A. (2000). ERC: A theory of equity, reciprocity, and competition. American Economic Review, 90(1), 166–193.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Burrows, P., & Loomes, G. (1994). The impact of fairness on bargaining behaviour. In Experimental Economics (pp. 21–41, Studies in Empirical Economics): Physica-Verlag HD.

  • Cox, C. A. (2013). Inequity aversion and advantage seeking with asymmetric competition. Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization, 86, 121–136.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • De la Rosa, L. E. (2011). Overconfidence and moral hazard. Games and Economic Behavior, 73(2), 429–451.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Demougin, D., Fluet, C., & Helm, C. (2006). Output and wages with inequality averse agents. Canadian Journal of Economics, 39(2), 399–413.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Drach-Zahavy, A., & Somech, A. (2002). Team heterogeneity and its relationship with team support and team effectiveness. Journal of Educational Administration, 40(1), 44–66.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Englmaier, F., & Wambach, A. (2010). Optimal incentive contracts under inequity aversion. Games and Economic Behavior, 69(2), 312–328.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fehr, E., & Schmidt, K. M. (1999). A theory of fairness, competition and cooperation. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 114(3), 817–868.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fudenberg, D., & Tirole, J. (1991). Game theory. Cambridge: MIT Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Gaba, A., & Kalra, A. (1999). Risk behavior in response to quotas and contests. Marketing Science, 18(3), 417–434.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gill, D., & Stone, R. (2010). Fairness and desert in tournaments. Games and Economic Behavior, 69(2), 346–364.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gill, D., & Stone, R. (2015). Desert and inequity aversion in teams. Journal of Public Economics, 123, 42–54.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gino, F., & Pisano, G. (2008). Toward a theory of behavioral operations. Manufacturing & Service Operations Management, 10(4), 676–691.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Grund, C., & Sliwka, D. (2005). Envy and compassion in tournaments. Journal of Economics & Management Strategy, 14(1), 187–207.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ho, T.-H., & Su, X. (2009). Peer-induced fairness in games. The American Economic Review, 99(5), 2022–2049.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ho, T.-H., Su, X., & Wu, Y. (2014). Distributional and peer-induced fairness in supply chain contract design. Production and Operations Management, 23(2), 161–175.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hvide, H. K. (2002). Tournament rewards and risk taking. Journal of Labor Economics, 20(4), 877–898.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Itoh, H. (2004). Moral hazard and other-regarding preferences. Japanese Economic Review, 55(1), 18–45.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Jackson, M. O. (2007). The study of social networks in economics. In J. E. Rauch (Ed.), The missing links: Formation and decay of economic networks.

  • Kadushin, C. (2012). Understanding social networks: Theories, concepts, and findings. Oxford: Oxford University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Kahneman, D., & Tversky, A. (1979). Prospect theory: An analysis of decision under risk. Econometrica, 47(2), 263–292.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kataria, M., & Regner, T. (2015). Honestly, why are you donating money to charity? An experimental study about self-awareness in status-seeking behavior. Theory and Decision, 79(3), 493–515.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kőszegi, B. (2014). Behavioral contract theory. Journal of Economic Literature, 52(4), 1075–1118.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Krackhardt, D., & Brass, D. J. (1994). Intraorganizational networks. Thousand Oaks, CA: Sage.

    Google Scholar 

  • Larrick, R. P., Burson, K. A., & Soll, J. B. (2007). Social comparison and confidence: When thinking you are better than average predicts overconfidence (and when it does not). Organizational Behavior and Human Decision Processes, 102(1), 76–94.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Levine, J. M., Resnick, L. B., & Higgins, E. T. (1993). Social foundations of cognition. Annual Review of Psychology, 44(1), 585–612.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Major, B., & Konar, E. (1984). An investigation of sex differences in pay expectations and their possible causes. Academy of Management Journal, 27(4), 777–792.

    Google Scholar 

  • Mantrala, M., Raman, K., & Desiraju, R. (1997). Sales quota plans: Mechanisms for adaptive learning. Marketing Letters, 8(4), 393–405.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • McPherson, M., Smith-Lovin, L., & Cook, J. M. (2001). Birds of a feather: Homophily in social networks. Annual Review of Sociology, 27, 415–444.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Miceli, M. P., & Lane, M. C. (1990). Antecedents of pay satisfaction: A review and extension. College of Business, Ohio State University.

  • Nadkarni, A., & Hofmann, S. G. (2012). Why do people use facebook? Personality and Individual Differences, 52(3), 243–249.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Neilson, W. S., & Stowe, J. (2008). Piece-rate contracts for other-regarding workers. Economic Inquiry, 48(3), 575–586.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Oshagbemi, T. (2000). Correlates of pay satisfaction in higher education. International Journal of Educational Management, 14(1), 31–39.

    Google Scholar 

  • Pepper, A., & Gore, J. (2015). Behavioral agency theory: New foundations for theorizing about executive compensation. Journal of Management, 41(4), 1045–1068.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Plambeck, E. L., & Zenios, S. A. (2000). Performance-based incentives in a dynamic principal-agent model. Manufacturing & Service Operations Management, 2(3), 240–263.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Provan, K. G., Fish, A., & Sydow, J. (2007). Interorganizational networks at the network level: A review of the empirical literature on whole networks. Journal of Management, 33(3), 479–516.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Rablen, M. D. (2010). Performance targets, effort and risk-taking. Journal of Economic Psychology, 31(4), 687–697. doi:10.1016/j.joep.2010.05.002.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Raju, J. S., & Srinivasan, V. (1996). Quota-based compensation plans for multiterritory heterogeneous salesforces. Management Science, 42(10), 1454–1462.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Reagans, R., Zuckerman, E., & McEvily, B. (2004). How to make the team: Social networks vs. demography as criteria for designing effective teams. Administrative science quarterly, 49(1), 101–133.

    Google Scholar 

  • Rey-Biel, P. (2008). Inequity aversion and team incentives. Scandinavian Journal of Economics, 110(2), 297–320.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Stoughton, N. M. (1993). Moral hazard and the portfolio management problem. The Journal of Finance, 48(5), 2009–2028.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Tversky, A., & Kahneman, D. (1974). Judgment under uncertainty: Heuristics and biases. Science, 185(4157), 1124–1131.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Willness, C. R., Steel, P., & Lee, K. (2007). A meta-analysis of the antecedents and consequences of workplace sexual harassment. Personnel Psychology, 60(1), 127–162.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Xing, D., & Liu, T. (2012). Sales effort free riding and coordination with price match and channel rebate. European Journal of Operational Research, 219(2), 264–271.

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgements

This work is supported by the National Natural Science Foundation of China (Grant Nos. 71272064, 71121061) and the Science and Technological Fund of Anhui Province for Outstanding Youth (Grant No. 1308085JGD07).

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Chengyuan Wang.

Appendix

Appendix

Proof of Proposition 1

According to Eq. 7, we have:

$$\begin{aligned} \frac{\partial ^{2}u_i }{\partial e_i \partial e_j }=p_i \left( {p_i +q_i } \right) \left( {\lambda _i -1} \right) \varphi \left( {T_i } \right) . \end{aligned}$$
(9)

The slope of agent i’s reaction function is given by:

$$\begin{aligned} \frac{de_i^*}{de_j }=-\frac{\frac{\partial ^{2}u_i }{\partial e_i \partial e_j }}{\frac{\partial ^{2}u_i }{\partial e_i^2 }}=\frac{p_i \left( {p_i +q_i } \right) \left( {\lambda _i -1} \right) \varphi \left( {T_i } \right) }{b+p_i^2 \left( {\lambda _i -1} \right) \varphi \left( {T_i } \right) }, \end{aligned}$$
(10)

where \(\frac{\partial ^{2}u_i }{\partial e_i^2 }<0\) (see Eq. 8 in the text).

Because \(0<\mathop \int \nolimits _{-\infty }^{T_i } \varphi \left( \varepsilon \right) d\varepsilon <1\), we incorporate it into Eq. 7 and obtain \(\beta +p_i<be_i <\beta +\lambda _i p_i \) when \(p_i >0\), and \(\beta +\lambda _i p_i<be_i <\beta +p_i \) when \(p_i <0\). In addition, \(\beta +\lambda _i p_i <0\) when \(p_i <0\) if \(\lambda _i \) is sufficiently large. Thus, we can conclude that \(e_i^*\) falls between \(\frac{\beta +p_i }{b}\) and \(max\left( {0,\frac{\beta +\lambda _i p_i }{b}} \right) \).

Proof of Proposition 2

Because \(\frac{\partial ^{2}u_i }{\partial e_i \partial \lambda _i }=p_i \mathop \int \nolimits _{-\infty }^{T_i } \varphi \left( \varepsilon \right) d\varepsilon \), we get:

$$\begin{aligned} \frac{de_i^*}{d\lambda _i }=-\frac{\frac{\partial ^{2}u_i }{\partial e_i \partial \lambda _i }}{\frac{\partial ^{2}u_i }{\partial e_i^2 }}=\frac{p_i \mathop \int \nolimits _{-\infty }^{T_i } \varphi \left( \varepsilon \right) d\varepsilon }{b+p_i^2 \left( {\lambda _i -1} \right) \varphi \left( {T_i } \right) }. \end{aligned}$$
(11)

We can find that the sign of \(\frac{de_i^*}{d\lambda _i }\) depends on \(p_i \), and therefore Proposition 2 holds.

Proof of Proposition 3

Because \(\frac{\partial ^{2}u_i }{\partial e_i \partial t_i }=p_i \left( {\lambda _i -1} \right) \varphi \left( {T_i } \right) \), we have:

$$\begin{aligned} \frac{de_i^*}{dt_i }=-\frac{\frac{\partial ^{2}u_i }{\partial e_i \partial t_i }}{\frac{\partial ^{2}u_i }{\partial e_i^2 }}=\frac{p_i \left( {\lambda _i -1} \right) \varphi \left( {T_i } \right) }{b+p_i^2 \left( {\lambda _i -1} \right) \varphi \left( {T_i } \right) }. \end{aligned}$$
(12)

This case also depends on the sign of \(p_i \).

Proof of Proposition 4

$$\begin{aligned} \frac{de_i^*}{dq_i }=-\frac{\frac{\partial ^{2}u_i }{\partial e_i \partial q_i }}{\frac{\partial ^{2}u_i }{\partial e_i^2 }}=\frac{\frac{p_i^2 \left( {\lambda _i -1} \right) \varphi \left( {T_i } \right) }{p_i^2 +\left( {p_i +q_i } \right) ^{2}}}{b+p_i^2 \left( {\lambda _i -1} \right) \varphi \left( {T_i } \right) }\left[ {\left( {p_i +q_i } \right) e_i^*+p_i e_j -\frac{p_i +q_i }{p_i }t_i } \right] . \end{aligned}$$
(13)

First, if \(p_i <0\) and \(p_i +q_i \le 0\), the section in the bracket is non-positive, and thus \(\frac{de_i^*}{dq_i }\le 0\) (if and only if \(e_j =0\), \(\frac{de_i^*}{dq_i }=0)\). Second, if \(p_i >0\) and \(t_i =0\), the section in the bracket is doubtlessly positive, and hence \(\frac{de_i^*}{dq_i }>0\). Thus, by continuity, there must exist \(\gamma >0\) to make \(\frac{de_i^*}{dq_i }>0\) when \(t_i \in \left[ {0,\gamma } \right] \). Third, if \(p_i <0\) and \(p_i +q_i >0\), the sign of the section in the bracket will mainly depend on the values of \(e_i^*\) and \(e_j \).

Proof of Proposition 5

The optimal output sharing is decided by \(\frac{\partial {{u}_p}}{\partial {\upbeta }}=0\), where

$$\begin{aligned} \frac{\partial u_p }{\partial \upbeta }=\sum \nolimits _i^2 \left\{ {\left( {p-be_i^*} \right) \frac{de_i^*}{d\beta }+\left( {e_i^*-e_j^*} \right) \left[ {1+\left( {\lambda _i -1} \right) \int \nolimits _{-\infty }^{T_i } \varphi \left( \varepsilon \right) d\varepsilon } \right] } \right\} . \end{aligned}$$
(14)

If \(\lambda _i =\lambda _j =1\), the Eq. 7 in the text is simplified as \(\beta -be_i +p_i =0\), and thus the optimal effort of agent i is given by \(e_i^*=\frac{\beta +p_i }{b}=\frac{2\beta -\beta _{ii} }{b}\). Similarly, the optimal effort of agent j is \(e_j^*=\frac{\beta +p_j }{b}=\frac{2\beta -\beta _{jj} }{b}\). Accordingly, we get that \(\frac{de_i^*}{d\beta }=\frac{de_i^*}{d\beta }=\frac{2}{b}\). Then, \(\frac{\partial u_p }{\partial \upbeta }=\frac{2}{b}\left[ {2p-\left( {4\beta -\beta _{ii} -\beta _{jj} } \right) } \right] =0\). Finally, we have \(\beta ^{*}=\frac{p}{2}+\frac{\beta _{ii} +\beta _{jj} }{4}\).

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Luo, B., Wang, C. & Li, T. Inequity-averse agents’ deserved concerns under the linear contract: a social network setting. Ann Oper Res 268, 129–148 (2018). https://doi.org/10.1007/s10479-017-2436-0

Download citation

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s10479-017-2436-0

Keywords

Navigation