Skip to main content
Log in

Coordinating a decentralized hybrid push–pull assembly system with unreliable supply and uncertain demand

  • Published:
Annals of Operations Research Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

We consider a decentralized assembly system in which \(m+n\) unreliable suppliers sell complementary components to an assembler, who faces a random demand. We assume that \(m\) of these suppliers are more powerful than the assembler and sell components via push contracts, while the remaining \(n\) suppliers are less powerful than the assembler and sell components via pull contracts. The supply chain operations are modelled by a three-stage game. We first characterize the equilibrium decisions of all chain members, and find that supply chain efficiency depends heavily on system parameters. We then develop a mechanism to coordinate the supply chain. The mechanism consists of two policies, including a buyback policy between push suppliers and the assembler, and a subsidy policy between the assembler and pull suppliers. We show that the mechanism can eliminate the two sources of “double marginalization” that exist in the chain with unreliable supply and uncertain demand, and achieve Pareto improvements.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. It is worth pointing out that centralized assembly systems have been extensively studied. See Ghosh and Gagnon (1989) for a review. Especially, Aviv and Federgruen (2001) and Cheng et al. (2012) study centralized hybrid push–pull systems. However, since our focus here is on decentralized systems, we omit the literature on centralized systems.

References

  • Altug, M. S., & van Ryzin, G. (2013). Product quality selection: Contractual agreements and supplier competition in an assemble-to-order environment. International Journal of Production Economics, 141(2), 626–638.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Anupindi, R., & Akella, R. (1993). Diversification under supply uncertainty. Management Science, 39(8), 944–963.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Aviv, Y., & Federgruen, A. (2001). Capacitated multi-item inventory systems with random and seasonally fluctuating demands: Implications for postponement strategies. Management Sciences, 47(4), 512–531.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Barlow, R. E., & Proschan, F. (1965). Mathematical theory of reliability. New York: Wiley.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bernstein, F., DeCroix, G. A., & Wang, Y. (2007). Incentives and commonality in a decentralized multiproduct assembly system. Operations Research, 55(4), 630–646.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cachon, G. (2003). Supply chain coordination with contracts. In S. Graves & T. de Kok (Eds.), Handbooks in operations research and management science: Supply chain management. Amsterdam: North Holland Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Cachon, G. P. (2004). The allocation of inventory risk in a supply chain: Push, pull, and advance-purchase discount contracts. Management Science, 50(2), 222–238.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cheng, F., Ettl, M., Lu, Y., & Yao, D. D. (2012). A production-inventory model for a push–pull manufacturing system with capacity and service level constraints. Production and Operations Management, 21(4), 668–681.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Du, D., Chen, B., & Xu, D. (2014). Quantifying the efficiency of price-only contracts in push supply chains over demand distributions of known supports. Omega, 42(1), 98–108.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fang, X., Ru, J., & Wang, Y. (2014). Optimal procurement design of an assembly supply chain with information asymmetry. Production and Operations Management, 23(12), 2075–2088.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gerchak, Y., & Wang, Y. (2004). Revenue-sharing vs. wholesale-price contracts in assembly systems with random demand. Production and Operations Management, 13(1), 23–33.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ghosh, S., & Gagnon, R. J. (1989). A comprehensive literature review and analysis of the design, balancing and scheduling of assembly systems. International Journal of Production Research, 27(4), 637–670.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Granot, D., & Yin, S. (2008). Competition and cooperation in decentralized push and pull assembly systems. Management Science, 54(4), 733–747.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Grosfeld-Nir, A., & Gerchak, Y. (2004). Multiple lotsizing in production to order with random yields: Review of recent advances. Annals of Operations Research, 126, 43–69.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Güler, M. G., & Bilgic, T. (2009). On coordinating an assembly system under random yield and random demand. European Journal of Operational Research, 196(1), 342–350.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Jiang, L., & Wang, Y. (2010). Supplier competition in decentralized assembly systems with price-sensitive and uncertain demand. Manufacturing & Service Operations Management, 12(1), 93–101.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kalkancı, B., & Erhun, F. (2012). Pricing games and impact of private demand information in decentralized assembly systems. Operations Research, 60(5), 1142–1156.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lariviere, M. A. (2006). A note on probability distributions with increasing generalized failure rates. Operations Research, 54(3), 602–604.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Nagarajan, M., & Sošić, G. (2009). Coalition stability in assembly models. Operations Research, 57(1), 131–145.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Sošić, G. (2011). Impact of demand uncertainty on stability of supplier alliances in assembly models. Production and Operations Management, 20(6), 905–920.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Simchi-Levi, D., & Simchi-Levi, E. (2001). The effect of e-business on supply chain strategy. Working paper, MIT.

  • Tomlin, B. (2009). Impact of supply learning when suppliers are unreliable. Manufacturing & Service Operations Management, 11(2), 192–209.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Tomlin, B., & Wang, Y. (2005). On the value of mix flexibility and dual sourcing in unreliable newsvendor networks. Manufacturing & Service Operations Management, 7(1), 37–57.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Yin, S. (2010). Alliance formation among perfectly complementary suppliers in a price-sensitive assembly system. Manufacturing & Service Operations Management, 12(3), 527–544.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Zabel, E. (1970). Monopoly and uncertainty. The Review of Economic Studies, 37(2), 205–219.

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgments

The authors are grateful to the constructive comments of the editor and two anonymous referees. The authors also gratefully acknowledge the support of grants from (i) National Natural Science Foundation of China (No. 71272129) for D.B. Ni and H. Fu; (ii) National Natural Science Foundation of China (No. 71471029) for Y.K. Ma and H. Fu; and (iii) Program for New Century Excellent Talents in University (NCET-11-0064), and Sichuan Youth Science and Technology Foundation (No. 2013JQ0031) for D.B. Ni.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Yongkai Ma.

Appendix: Mathematical proofs

Appendix: Mathematical proofs

1.1 Appendix 1: Proof of Lemma 2

(i) We first prove that for any given \(q_{I}\), the assembler should set \(\{w_{j}\}\) such that \(F^{-1}\left( 1-\frac{c_{m+1}}{\beta _{I}\beta _{m+1}w_{m+1}}\right) =\cdots =F^{-1} \left( 1-\frac{c_{m+n}}{\beta _{I}\beta _{m+n}w_{m+n}}\right) \). If there exists a \(w_{j^{\prime }}\), such that \(F^{-1}\left( 1-\frac{c_{j^{\prime }}}{\beta _{I}\beta _{j^{\prime }}w_{j^{\prime }}}\right) <\min \big [F^{-1}\left( 1-\frac{c_{j}}{\beta _{I}\beta _{j}w_{j}}\right) , j=m+1,\ldots ,j^{\prime }-1,j^{\prime }+1,\ldots ,m+n\big ]\), we know from Eq. (10) that the assembler’s expected profit function becomes

$$\begin{aligned}&\pi _{a}(q_{I}, w_{m+1},\ldots ,w_{m+n})\\&\quad =\beta _{I}\left( \beta _{J}p -\sum _{j=m+1}^{m+n}\beta _{j}w_{j}\right) E\left\{ \min \left[ X, q_{I},F^{-1} \left( 1-\frac{c_{j^{\prime }}}{\beta _{I}\beta _{j^{\prime }}w_{j^{\prime }}}\right) \right] \right\} -\sum _{i=1}^{m}\beta _{i}w_{i}q_{I}. \end{aligned}$$

Then, by reducing \(w_{j}\), \(j\ne j^{\prime }\), to a value such that \(F^{-1}\left( 1-\frac{c_{j^{\prime }}}{\beta _{I}\beta _{j^{\prime }}w_{j^{\prime }}}\right) = \min \big [F^{-1}\left( 1-\frac{c_{j}}{\beta _{I}\beta _{j}w_{j}}\right) , j=m+1,\ldots ,j^{\prime }-1,j^{\prime }+1,\ldots ,m+n\big ]\), the assembler can increase its expected profit. Thus, the assembler should set \(\{w_{j}\}\) such that \(F^{-1}\left( 1-\frac{c_{m+1}}{\beta _{I}\beta _{m+1}w_{m+1}} \right) =\cdots =F^{-1}\left( 1-\frac{c_{m+n}}{\beta _{I}\beta _{m+n}w_{m+n}} \right) \).

Based upon the above analysis, we know that the assembler can set \(w_{m+1}\) first, and then determine \((w_{m+2},\ldots ,w_{m+n})\) according to \(\frac{c_{m+1}}{\beta _{m+1}w_{m+1}}\ldots = \frac{c_{m+n}}{\beta _{m+n}w_{m+n}}\).

(ii) Now, together with \(\frac{c_{m+1}}{\beta _{m+1}w_{m+1}}\ldots = \frac{c_{m+n}}{\beta _{m+n}w_{m+n}}\), we prove that the assembler should set \(w_{m+1}\) and \(q_{I}\) such that \(q_{I}=F^{-1}\left( 1-\frac{c_{m+1}}{\beta _{I}\beta _{m+1}w_{m+1}}\right) \). If \(q_{I}>F^{-1}\left( 1-\frac{c_{m+1}}{\beta _{I}\beta _{m+1}w_{m+1}}\right) \), the assembler’s expected profit function of Eq. (10) becomes

$$\begin{aligned} \pi _{a}(q_{I}, w_{m+1})= & {} \beta _{I}\left( \beta _{J}p-\frac{\beta _{m+1}w_{m+1}C_{J}}{c_{m+1}} \right) E\left\{ \min \left[ X, F^{-1}\left( 1-\frac{c_{m+1}}{\beta _{I}\beta _{m+1}w_{m+1}}\right) \right] \right\} \\&-\sum _{i=1}^{m}\beta _{i}w_{i}q_{I}. \end{aligned}$$

Then, by reducing \(q_{I}\) to a value such that \(q_{I}=F^{-1}\left( 1-\frac{c_{m+1}}{\beta _{I}\beta _{m+1}w_{m+1}}\right) \), the assembler can improve its expected profit.

If \(q_{I}<F^{-1}\left( 1-\frac{c_{m+1}}{\beta _{I}\beta _{m+1}w_{m+1}}\right) \), the assembler’s expected profit function of Eq. (10) becomes

$$\begin{aligned} \pi _{a}(q_{I}, w_{m+1})=\beta _{I}\left( \beta _{J}p-\frac{\beta _{m+1}w_{m+1}C_{J}}{c_{m+1}} \right) E\left[ \min \left( X,q_{I}\right) \right] -\sum _{i=1}^{m}\beta _{i}w_{i}q_{I}. \end{aligned}$$

Then, by reducing \(w_{m+1}\) to a value such that \(F^{-1}\left( 1-\frac{c_{m+1}}{\beta _{I}\beta _{m+1}w_{m+1}}\right) =q_{I}\), the assembler can again improve its expected profit. Combining (i) and (ii), we complete the Proof of Lemma 2.

1.2 Appendix 2: Proof of Lemma 3

Assume that \(h(q_{I})\) increases in \(q_{I}\), then \(\frac{d \pi _{a}(q_{I})}{d q_{I}}\) of Eq. (13) decreases in \(q_{I}\). Note that \(\lim \limits _{q_{I}\rightarrow 0}\frac{d \pi _{a}(q_{I})}{d q_{I}}=\beta _{I}\beta _{J}p-C_{J}-\sum _{i=1}^{m}\beta _{i}w_{i}>0\), and \(\lim \limits _{q_{I}\rightarrow +\infty }\frac{d \pi _{a}(q_{I})}{d q_{I}}<0\). Consequently, there exists a unique \(q_{I}^{*}\in (0,+\infty )\) such that \(\frac{d \pi _{a}(q_{I})}{d q_{I}}=0\) at \(q_{I}=q_{I}^{*}\), \(\frac{d \pi _{a}(q_{I})}{d q_{I}}>0\) for \(q_{I}<q_{I}^{*}\), and \(\frac{d \pi _{a}(q_{I})}{d q_{I}}<0\) for \(q_{I}>q_{I}^{*}\). So, \(\pi _{a}(q_{I})\) is unimodal in \(q_{I}\) and reaches its maximizer at \(q_{I}^{*}\).

1.3 Appendix 3: Proof of Lemma 4

Assume that \(h(q_{I}^{*})\), \(g(q_{I}^{*})\), and \(\frac{q_{I}^{*}f^{\prime }(q_{I}^{*})}{f(q_{I}^{*})}+2g(q_{I}^{*})\) all increase in \(q_{I}^{*}\).

(i) If there exists a \(q^{\prime }\) on \((0,+\infty )\) that satisfies \(g(q^{\prime })=1\), then \(\frac{d \pi _{i}(q_{I}^{*})}{d q_{I}^{*}}\) of Eq. (17) decreases in \(q_{I}^{*}\) for \(q_{I}^{*}\in (0, q^{\prime }]\) and is negative for \(q_{I}^{*}\in (q^{\prime }, +\infty )\). In conjunction with the fact that \(\lim \limits _{q_{I}^{*}\rightarrow 0}\frac{d \pi _{i}(q_{I}^{*})}{d q_{I}^{*}}= \beta _{I}\beta _{J}p-C_{J}-\sum _{l=1,l\ne i}^{m}\beta _{l}w_{l}-c_{i}>0\), we know there exists a unique \(q^{\prime \prime }\in (0, q^{\prime }]\) such that \(\frac{d \pi _{i}(q_{I}^{*})}{d q_{I}^{*}}=0\) at \(q_{I}^{*}=q^{\prime \prime }\), \(\frac{d \pi _{i}(q_{I}^{*})}{d q_{I}^{*}}>0\) for \(q_{I}^{*}<q^{\prime \prime }\), and \(\frac{d \pi _{i}(q_{I}^{*})}{d q_{I}^{*}}<0\) for \(q_{I}^{*}>q^{\prime \prime }\). Thus, \(\pi _{i}(q_{I}^{*})\) is unimodal in \(q_{I}^{*}\).

(ii) If such a \(q^{\prime }\) does not exist, it means \(g(q_{I}^{*})<1\) for \(q_{I}^{*}>0\). Thus, \(\frac{d \pi _{i}(q_{I}^{*})}{d q_{I}^{*}}\) decreases in \(q_{I}^{*}\) for \(q_{I}^{*}>0\). Consequently, \(\pi _{i}(q_{I}^{*})\) is again unimodal in \(q_{I}^{*}\). Combining (i) and (ii), we complete the proof of Lemma 4.

1.4 Appendix 4: Proof of Corollary 1

If \(q^{*}\ge q^{*}_{c}\), we have

$$\begin{aligned} \beta _{I}\beta _{J}p[1-F(q^{*}_{c})]\ge & {} \beta _{I}\beta _{J}p[1-F(q^{*})]>\beta _{I}\beta _{J}p[1-F(q^{*})] -\left( \sum _{i=1}^{m}\beta _{i}w_{i}^{*}-C_{I}\right) \\&-\,C_{J}h(q^{*}). \end{aligned}$$

Comparing Eq. (5) with Eqs. (14) and (19), we can get

$$\begin{aligned} \beta _{I}\beta _{J}p[1-F(q^{*}_{c})]=C= \beta _{I}\beta _{J}p[1-F(q^{*})]-\left( \sum _{i=1}^{m}\beta _{i}w_{i}^{*} -C_{I}\right) -C_{J}h(q^{*}). \end{aligned}$$

The above two expressions are contradictory. Thus, \(q^{*}<q^{*}_{c}\).

1.5 Appendix 5: Proof of Corollary 2

(i) Because \(h(q)\), \(g(q)\) and \(\frac{qf^{\prime }(q)}{f(q)}+2g(q)\) all increase in \(q\), we know from Eq. (19) that: (a) \(\frac{dq^{*}}{dc_{k}}<0\), \(k=1,\ldots ,m+n\). (b) \(\frac{dq^{*}}{dC_{J}}<0\) for any given \(C\). Consequently, \(\frac{d q^{*}}{d C_{I}}>0\), i.e., \(\frac{d q^{*}}{d \alpha }>0\).

(ii) From Eq. (4), we have

$$\begin{aligned} \frac{d\pi _{c}(q^{*})}{dc_{k}}= & {} \beta _{I}\beta _{J}p[1-F(q^{*})]\frac{dq^{*}}{dc_{k}}- \left( q^{*} +C\frac{dq^{*}}{dc_{k}}\right) \\= & {} \left\{ \beta _{I}\beta _{J}p[1-F(q^{*})] -C\right\} \frac{dq^{*}}{dc_{k}}-q^{*}, \end{aligned}$$

and

$$\begin{aligned} \frac{d\pi _{c}(q^{*})}{d\alpha }= & {} \frac{d\pi _{c}(q^{*})}{dq^{*}} \frac{dq^{*}}{d\alpha }\\= & {} \{\beta _{I}\beta _{J}p[1-F(q^{*})]-C\}\frac{dq^{*}}{d\alpha }. \end{aligned}$$

Because \(q^{*}<q_{c}^{*}\), then \(\beta _{I}\beta _{J}p[1-F(q^{*})]-C>0\). In conjunction with \(\frac{dq^{*}}{dc_{k}}<0\) and \(\frac{dq^{*}}{d\alpha }>0\), we have \(\frac{d\pi _{c}(q^{*})}{dc_{k}}<0\) and \(\frac{d\pi _{c}(q^{*})}{d\alpha }>0\). Combining (i) and (ii), we complete the Proof of Corollary 2.

1.6 Appendix 6: Proof of Corollary 3

(i) Because \(h(q)\), \(g(q)\) and \(\frac{qf^{\prime }(q)}{f(q)}+2g(q)\) all increase in \(q\), we know from Eq. (19) that \(\frac{dq^{*}}{d\beta _{k}}>0\), \(k=1,\ldots ,m+n\). Second, we know from Eq. (4) that

$$\begin{aligned} \frac{d\pi _{c}(q^{*})}{d\beta _{k}}= & {} \Pi _{l=1,l\ne k}^{m+n}\beta _{l}p\int _0^{q^{*}} [1-F(x)]dx +\beta _{I}\beta _{J}p[1-F(q^{*})] \frac{dq^{*}}{d\beta _{k}}-C\frac{dq^{*}}{d\beta _{k}}\\= & {} \{\beta _{I}\beta _{J}p[1-F(q^{*})]-C\}\frac{dq^{*}}{d\beta _{k}}+ \Pi _{l=1,l\ne k}^{m+n}\beta _{l}p\int _0^{q^{*}} [1-F(x)]dx. \end{aligned}$$

Due to \(q^{*}<q_{c}^{*}\), we have \(\beta _{I}\beta _{J}p[1-F(q^{*})]-C>0\), and hence \(\frac{d\pi _{c}(q^{*})}{d\beta _{k}}>0\), we complete the proof of Corollary 3 (i).

(ii) Corollary 3 (ii) can be easily verified from Eqs. (4) and (19).

1.7 Appendix 7: Proof of Corollary 4

(i) Because \(h(q)\), \(g(q)\) and \(\frac{qf^{\prime }(q)}{f(q)}+2g(q)\) all increase in \(q\), we know from Eq. (19) that \(\frac{d q^{*}}{d m}<0\). Consequently, the marginal procurement cost \(\sum _{j=m+1}^{m+n}\beta _{I}\beta _{j}w_{j}^{*}= \frac{C_{J}}{1-F(q^{*})}\) increases in \(q^{*}\) and decreases in \(m\). Then, from Eqs. (18) and (19), we can write the marginal procurement cost of components \(1,\ldots ,m\) as \(\sum _{i=1}^{m}\beta _{i}w_{i}^{*}= \beta _{I}\beta _{J}p[1-F(q^{*})]-C_{J}[1+h(q^{*})]\). Clearly, \(\sum _{i=1}^{m}\beta _{i}w_{i}^{*}\) decreases in \(q^{*}\) and increases in \(m\).

(ii) It can be seen from Eq. (19) that the production quantity is not related to the number of pull suppliers. Consequently, we know from Eqs. (18) and (20) that the marginal procurement costs \(\sum _{i=1}^{m}\beta _{i}w_{i}^{*}\) and \(\sum _{j=m+1}^{m+n}\beta _{I}\beta _{j}w_{j}^{*}\) are also not related to the number of pull suppliers.

(iii) From Eq. (4), we have

$$\begin{aligned} \frac{d\pi _{c}(q^{*})}{dm}= & {} \frac{d\pi _{c}(q^{*})}{dq^{*}} \frac{dq^{*}}{dm}\\= & {} \{\beta _{I}\beta _{J}p[1-F(q^{*})]-C\}\frac{dq^{*}}{dm}. \end{aligned}$$

Due to \(q^{*}<q_{c}^{*}\), we have \(\beta _{I}\beta _{J}p[1-F(q^{*})]-C>0\), and hence \(\frac{d\pi _{c}(q^{*})}{dm}<0\). Using the same analysis would verify \(\frac{d\pi _{c}(q^{*})}{dn}=0\). Combining (i), (i) and (iii), we complete the Proof of Corollary 4.

1.8 Appendix 8: Proof of Theorem 2

Using backward induction, we first investigate the production decisions of pull suppliers, and then analyze the assembler’s decision problem.

(i) From Eq. (28), we can rewrite supplier \(j\)’s expected profit function as

$$\begin{aligned}&\Pi _{j}(q_{j})\\&\quad =\left\{ \begin{array}{l@{\quad }l} \textstyle \beta _{I}\beta _{j}\left\{ w_{j} \int _0^{q_{j}} [1-F(x)]dx+b_{j}\int _0^{q_{j}} F(x)dx\right\} -c_{j}q_{j},&{}q_{j}\le \min (q_{I},q_{Jj}),\\ \textstyle \beta _{I}\beta _{j}\left\{ w_{j} \int _0^{\min (q_{I},q_{Jj})} [1-F(x)]dx+b_{j}q_{j}\right. \\ \textstyle \left. -\,b_{j}\int _0^{\min (q_{I},q_{Jj})} [1-F(x)]dx\right\} -c_{j}q_{j},&{}q_{j}>\min (q_{I},q_{Jj}). \end{array} \right. \end{aligned}$$

Substituting \(b_{j}=\frac{\frac{\beta _{J}c_{j}}{\beta _{j}}p-w_{j}C}{\beta _{I}\beta _{J}p-C}\) of Eq. (30) into the above expression and taking the first derivative of \(\Pi _{j}(q_{j})\) with respect to \(q_{j}\), after some algebra, we have

$$\begin{aligned} \frac{d \Pi _{j}(q_{j})}{d q_{j}}=\left\{ \begin{array}{l@{\quad }l} \textstyle (\beta _{I}\beta _{j}w_{j}-c_{j}) \left[ 1-\frac{\beta _{I}\beta _{J}p}{\beta _{I}\beta _{J}p-C}F(q_{j})\right] , &{}q_{j}\le \min (q_{I},q_{Jj}),\\ \textstyle \frac{-(\beta _{I}\beta _{j}w_{j}-c_{j})C}{\beta _{I}\beta _{J}p-C}, &{}q_{j}>\min (q_{I},q_{Jj}). \end{array} \right. \end{aligned}$$

In conjunction with the fact that \((\beta _{I}\beta _{j}w_{j}-c_{j})\left[ 1-\frac{\beta _{I}\beta _{J}p}{\beta _{I}\beta _{J}p-C}F(q_{j})\right] \) decreases in \(q_{j}\), we know \(\Pi _{j}(q_{j})\) is concave in \(q_{j}\) for \(q_{j}\le \min (q_{I},q_{Jj})\) and decreases in \(q_{j}\) for \(q_{j}>\min (q_{I},q_{Jj})\). Second, \((\beta _{I}\beta _{j}w_{j}- c_{j})\left[ 1-\frac{\beta _{I}\beta _{J}p}{\beta _{I}\beta _{J}p-C}F(q_{j})\right] >0\) at \(q_{j}=0\), and \((\beta _{I}\beta _{j}w_{j}-c_{j}) \left[ 1-\frac{\beta _{I}\beta _{J}p}{\beta _{I}\beta _{J}p-C}F(q_{j})\right] =0\) at \(q_{j}=q_{c}^{*}\). Thus, if \(q_{c}^{*}\le \min (q_{I},q_{Jj})\), \(\Pi _{j}(q_{j})\) increases in \(q_{j}\) for \(q_{j}\le q_{c}^{*}\) and decreases in \(q_{j}\) for \(q_{j}>q_{c}^{*}\); otherwise, \(\Pi _{j}(q_{j})\) increases in \(q_{j}\) for \(q_{j}\le \min (q_{I},q_{Jj})\) and decreases in \(q_{j}\) for \(q_{j}>\min (q_{I},q_{Jj})\). This means that \(\Pi _{j}(q_{j})\) is unimodal in \(q_{j}\), and increases in \(q_{j}\) for \(q_{j}\le \min (q_{I},q_{Jj}, q_{c}^{*})\) and decreases in \(q_{j}\) for \(q_{j}>\min (q_{I},q_{Jj}, q_{c}^{*})\). Consequently, for any given \(q_{I}\) and \(q_{Jj}\), the optimal production quantity of supplier \(j\) is \(\min (q_{c}^{*}, q_{I},q_{Jj})\).

We denote

$$\begin{aligned} q_{Jc}^{*}=\min (q_{I},q_{c}^{*}). \end{aligned}$$

Similar to the illustration of Eq. (9), we can conclude that \(q_{Jc}^{*}=\min (q_{I},q_{c}^{*})\) is the reaction function of pull suppliers here.

(ii) Substituting \(q_{j}=q_{J}=q_{Jc}^{*}=\min (q_{I},q_{c}^{*})\) into Eq. (27), we can rewrite the assembler’s expected profit function as

$$\begin{aligned}&\Pi _{a}(q_{I},w_{m+1},\ldots ,w_{m+n},b_{m+1},\ldots ,b_{m+n})\\&\quad =\left\{ \begin{array}{ll} \textstyle \beta _{I}\beta _{J}p\int _0^{q_{I}} [1-F(x)]dx-\sum \nolimits _{i=1}^{m}\beta _{i}w_{i}q_{I}+\sum \nolimits _{i=1}^{m}\beta _{i}b_{i}\int _0^{q_{I}}F(x)dx&{}\\ \textstyle - \sum \nolimits _{j=m+1}^{m+n}\beta _{I}\beta _{j}w_{j}\int _0^{q_{I}} [1-F(x)]dx-\sum \nolimits _{j=m+1}^{m+n}\beta _{I}\beta _{j}b_{j} \int _0^{q_{I}}F(x)dx,&{}q_{I}\le q_{c}^{*},\\ \textstyle \beta _{I}\beta _{J}p\int _0^{q_{c}} [1-F(x)]dx-\sum \nolimits _{i=1}^{m}\beta _{i} w_{i}q_{I}&{}\\ \textstyle - \sum \nolimits _{j=m+1}^{m+n}\beta _{I}\beta _{j}w_{j}\int _0^{q_{c}} [1-F(x)]dx-\sum \nolimits _{j=m+1}^{m+n}\beta _{I}\beta _{j}b_{j}\int _0^{q_{c}}F(x)dx,&{}q_{I}>q_{c}^{*}. \end{array} \right. \end{aligned}$$

Substituting \(b_{i}=\frac{\left( w_{i}-\frac{c_{i}}{\beta _{i}} \right) \beta _{I}\beta _{J}p}{\beta _{I}\beta _{J}p-C}\) of Eq. (29) and \(b_{j}=\frac{\frac{\beta _{J}c_{j}}{\beta _{j}}p -w_{j}C}{\beta _{I}\beta _{J}p-C}\) of Eq. (30) into the above expression and taking the first derivative of \(\Pi _{a}(q_{I},w_{m+1},\ldots ,w_{m+n})\) with respect to \(q_{I}\), after some algebra, we have

$$\begin{aligned}&\frac{d \Pi _{a}(q_{I},w_{m+1},\ldots ,w_{m+n})}{d q_{I}}\\&\quad =\left\{ \begin{array}{l@{\quad }l} \textstyle \left( \beta _{I}\beta _{J}p-\sum \nolimits _{i=1}^{m}\beta _{i} w_{i}-\sum \nolimits _{j=m+1}^{m+n}\beta _{I}\beta _{j}w_{j}\right) \left[ 1-\frac{\beta _{I}\beta _{J}p}{\beta _{I}\beta _{J}p-C}F(q_{I})\right] , &{}q_{I}\le q_{c}^{*},\\ \textstyle -\sum \nolimits _{i=1}^{m}\beta _{i} w_{i},&{}q_{I}>q_{c}^{*}. \end{array} \right. \end{aligned}$$

From the above expression, we are able to compute that \(\frac{d \Pi _{a}(q_{I},w_{m+1},\ldots ,w_{m+n})}{d q_{I}}>0\) for \(q_{I}<q_{c}^{*}\), \(\frac{d\Pi _{a}(q_{I},w_{m+1},\ldots ,w_{m+n})}{d q_{I}}<0\) for \(q_{I}>q_{c}^{*}\), and \(\frac{d\Pi _{a}(q_{I},w_{m+1},\ldots ,w_{m+n})}{d q_{I}}=0\) for \(q_{I}=q_{c}^{*}\). Thus, the unique maximizer of the assembler’s expected profit function is given by \(q_{c}^{*}\). Combining (i) and (ii), we complete the Proof of Theorem 2.

1.9 Appendix 9: Proof of Corollary 6

In Eqs. (34), (35) and (36) can be obtained by solving \(\Pi _{i}(w_{i})>\pi _{i}^{*}\), \(\Pi _{j}>\pi _{j}^{*}\) and \(\Pi _{a}(w_{m+1},\ldots ,w_{m+n})>\pi _{a}^{*}\), respectively.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Fu, H., Ma, Y., Ni, D. et al. Coordinating a decentralized hybrid push–pull assembly system with unreliable supply and uncertain demand. Ann Oper Res 257, 537–557 (2017). https://doi.org/10.1007/s10479-015-1865-x

Download citation

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s10479-015-1865-x

Keywords

Navigation