Skip to main content
Log in

Does value-at-risk encourage diversification when losses follow tempered stable or more general Lévy processes?

  • Research Article
  • Published:
Annals of Finance Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

In this paper, we address the question of when portfolio selection based on Value-at-risk encourages diversification [in the sense of Ibragimov (Quant Financ 9(5):565–580, 2009)]. Specifically, we give sufficient conditions for the case when losses follow a Lévy process. When the process has finite variation, these conditions are also necessary. We then specialize our results to the case when losses have tempered stable distributions.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Similar content being viewed by others

References

  • Aas, K., Haff, I.H., Dimakos, X.K.: Risk estimation using the multivariate normal inverse Gaussian distribution. J Risk 8(2), 39–60 (2006)

    Google Scholar 

  • Artzner, P., Delbaen, F., Eber, J., Heath, D.: Coherent measures of risk. Math Financ 9(3), 203–228 (1999)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Clark, P.K.: A subordinated stochastic process model with finite variance for speculative prices. Econometrica 41(1), 135–155 (1973)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cont, R., Tankov, P.: Financial Modelling with Jump Processes. Boca Raton: Chapman & Hall (2004)

  • Daníelsson, J., Jorgensen, B.N., Samorodnitsky, G., Sarma, M., de Vries, C.G.: Fat tails, VaR and subadditivity. J Econ 172(2), 283–291 (2013)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Embrechts, P., Klüppelberg, C., Mikosch, T.: Modelling Extremal Events or Insurance and Finance. Berlin: Springer (1997)

  • Garcia, R., Renault, E., Tsafack, G.: Proper conditioning for coherent var in portfolio management. Manag Sci 53(3), 483–494 (2007)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Grabchak, M.: Limit theorem for tempered stable and related distributions. (2012a). arXiv:1201.6006

  • Grabchak, M.: On a new class of tempered stable distributions: moments and regular variation. J Appl Probab 49(4), 1015–1035 (2012b)

  • Grabchak, M.: Inversions of Lévy measures and the relation between long and short time behavior of Lévy processes. J Theor Probab (2013). doi:10.1007/s10959-012-0476-6

  • Grabchak, M., Molchanov, S.A.: Limit theorems and phase transitions for two models of summation of iid random variables depending on parameters. Doklady Math 88(1), 431–434 (2013)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Grabchak, M., Samorodnitsky, G.: Do financial returns have finite or infinite variance? A paradox and an explanation. Quant Financ 10(8), 883–893 (2010)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ibragimov, R.: Efficiency of linear estimators under under heavy-tailedness: convolutions of \(\alpha \)-symmetric distributions. Econ Theory 23(3), 501–517 (2007)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ibragimov, R.: Portfolio diversification and value at risk under thick-tailedness. Quant Financ 9(5), 565–580 (2009)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ibragimov, R., Walden, J.: Portfolio diversification under local deviations from power laws. Insur Math Econ 42(2), 594–599 (2008)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ibragimov, R., Walden, J.: Optimal bundling strategies under heavy-tailed valuations. Manag Sci 56(11), 1963–1976 (2010)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ibragimov, R., Walden, J.: Value at risk and efficiency under dependence and heavy-tailedness: models with common shocks. Ann Financ 7(3), 285–318 (2011)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Jorion, P.: Value at Risk: The New Benchmark for Managing Financial Risk, 3rd edn. New York: McGraw-Hill (2006)

  • Kallenberg, O.: Foundations of Modern Probability, 2nd edn. New York: Springer (2002)

  • Kim, Y.S., Giacometti, R., Rachev, S.T., Fabozzi, F.J., Mignacca, D.: Measuring financial risk and portfolio optimization with a non-Gaussian multivariate model. Ann Oper Res 201(1), 325–343 (2012)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Koponen, I.: Analytic approach to the problem of convergence of truncated Lévy flights towards the Gaussian stochastic process. Phys Rev E 52(1), 1197–1199 (1995)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Maejima, M., Nakahara, G.: A note on new classes of infinitely divisible distributions on \(\mathbb{R}^d\). Electron Commun Probab 14, 358–371 (2009)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mandelbrot, B., Taylor, H.M.: On the distribution of stock price differences. Oper Res 15(6), 1057–1062 (1967)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mantegna, R.N., Stanley, H.E.: Stochastic process with ultraslow convergence to a Gaussian: the truncated Lévy flight. Phys Rev Lett 73(22), 2946–2949 (1994)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Marshall, A.W., Olkin, I., Arnold, B.C.: Inequalities: Theory of Majorization and Its Applications, 2nd edn. New York: Springer (2011)

  • McNeil, A.J., Frey, R., Embrechts, P.: Quantitative Risk Management: Concepts, Techniques and Tools. Princeton: Princeton University Press (2005)

  • Rachev, S.T. (Ed.): Handbook of Heavy Tailed Distributions in Finance. Amsterdam: Elsevier Science (2003)

  • Rachev, S.T., Kim, Y.S., Bianchi, M.L., Fabozzi, F.J.: Financial Models with Levy Processes and Volatility Clustering. London: Wiley (2011)

  • Rosiński, J.: Tempering stable processes. Stoch Process Appl 117(6), 677–707 (2007)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Rosiński, J., Sinclair, J.L.: Generalized tempered stable processes. Banach Center Publ 90, 153–170 (2010)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Samorodnitsky, G., Taqqu, M.: Stochastic monotonicity and Slepian-type inequalities for infinitely divisible and stable random vectors. Ann Probab 21(1), 143–160 (1993)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Samorodnitsky, G., Taqqu, M.: Levy measures of infinitely divisible random vectors and Slepian inequalities. Ann Probab 22(4), 1930–1956 (1994)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Sato, K.: Lévy Processes and Infinitely Divisible Distributions. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press (1999)

Download references

Acknowledgments

The author wishes to thank Dr. Weidong Tian for the benefit of several discussions and the anonymous referee whose suggestions lead to a great improvement in the presentation of this paper.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Michael Grabchak.

Appendix

Appendix

The proof of Theorem 1 is based on the following result, which is a specialization of Theorems 2.1 and 3.2 in Samorodnitsky and Taqqu (1994) [see also Theorem 2.2 in Samorodnitsky and Taqqu (1993)].

Lemma 1

Let \(\{X_t:t\ge 0\}\) and \(\{Y_t:t\ge 0\}\) be Lévy processes such that \(X_1\sim ID_0(0,M_X,0)\) and \(Y_1\sim ID_0(0,M_Y,0)\) with \(M_X((-\infty ,0])=M_Y((-\infty ,0])=0\). We have

$$\begin{aligned} M_X((r,\infty )) \le M_Y((r,\infty )) \quad \text{ for } \text{ every } r>0 \end{aligned}$$

if and only if

$$\begin{aligned} P(X_t>r) \le P(Y_t>r) \quad \text{ for } \text{ very } r>0, t>0. \end{aligned}$$

Proof (Proof of Theorem 1)

[Proof of Theorem 1] We only prove results related to Schur-convexity of \(g_r(\cdot )\) as proofs of the other results are similar.

We begin with the case when \(\mu \in \fancyscript{P}\). By positivity, we have \(\mathrm{VaR}_\gamma (X_{\varvec{u},t})\le \mathrm{VaR}_\gamma (X_{\varvec{v},t})\) for all \(t>0\) and all \(\gamma \in (0,1)\) if and only if \(P(X_{\varvec{u},t}>r)\le P(X_{\varvec{v},t}>r)\) for all \(t>0\) and all \(r>0\). By Lemma 1, this holds if and only if \(g_r(\varvec{u})=M_{\varvec{u}}((r,\infty )) \le M_{\varvec{v}}((r,\infty ))=g_r(\varvec{v})\) for all \(r>0\). This holds for all \(\varvec{u},\varvec{v}\in \mathbb R^n_+\) with \(\varvec{u}\prec \varvec{v}\) if and only if \(g_r(\cdot )\) is Schur-convex for all \(r>0\).

Now assume that \(\mu \in \fancyscript{S}\). By symmetry, \(\mathrm{VaR}_\gamma (X_{\varvec{u},t})\le \mathrm{VaR}_\gamma (X_{\varvec{v},t})\) for all \(t>0\) and all \(\gamma \in (.5,1)\) if and only if \(P(X_{\varvec{u},t}>r)\le P(X_{\varvec{v},t}>r)\) for all \(t>0\) and all \(r>0\).

First, consider the case when \(\int _{\mathbb R}\left( |x|\wedge 1\right) M(\mathrm{d}x)<\infty \). For any \(\varvec{w}\in \mathbb R^n_+\) and any \(t>0\), the distribution of \(X_{\varvec{w},t}\) is symmetric around zero and thus \(X_{\varvec{w},t} \mathop {=}\limits ^{d}X_{\varvec{w},t}^{(1)}-X^{(2)}_{\varvec{w}, t}\) where \(\{X_{\varvec{w},t}^{(1)}:t\ge 0\}\) and \(\{X_{\varvec{w},t}^{(2)}:t\ge 0\}\) are independent Lévy processes with \(X^{(1)}_{\varvec{w},1},X^{(2)}_{\varvec{w},1}\mathop {\sim }\limits ^{\mathrm{iid}}ID_0(0,M'_{\varvec{w}},0)\) and

$$\begin{aligned} M'_{\varvec{w}}(A) = \int \limits _{[x>0]} 1_A(x) M_{\varvec{w}}(\mathrm{d}x), \quad A\in \mathfrak B(\mathbb R), \end{aligned}$$

where \(M_{\varvec{w}}\) is as in (7). Note that \(|X_{\varvec{w},t}|\mathop {=}\limits ^{d}X^{(1)}_{\varvec{w},t}+X^{(2)}_{\varvec{w},t}\sim ID_0(0,2M'_{\varvec{w}},0)\). If \(r>0\) then, by symmetry,

$$\begin{aligned} P(X^{(1)}_{\varvec{w},t}+X^{(2)}_{\varvec{w},t}>r) = P(|X_{\varvec{w},t}|>r)= 2P(X_{\varvec{w},t} >r). \end{aligned}$$

Thus,

$$\begin{aligned} P(X_{\varvec{u},t} >r)\le P(X_{\varvec{v},t} >r), \quad \text{ for } \text{ all } t>0, r>0, \varvec{u}\prec \varvec{v} \end{aligned}$$

is equivalent to

$$\begin{aligned} P(X^{(1)}_{\varvec{u},t}+X^{(2)}_{\varvec{u},t}>r)\le P(X^{(1)}_{\varvec{v},t}+X^{(2)}_{\varvec{v},t}>r), \quad \text{ for } \text{ all } t>0, r>0, \varvec{u}\prec \varvec{v}. \end{aligned}$$

By Lemma 1 this is equivalent to

$$\begin{aligned} 2M'_{\varvec{u}}((r,\infty )) \le 2M'_{\varvec{v}}((r,\infty )), \quad \text{ for } \text{ all } r>0, \varvec{u}\prec \varvec{v}. \end{aligned}$$

Since \(M'_{\varvec{u}}((r,\infty )) = g_{r}(\varvec{u})\) and \(M'_{\varvec{v}}((r,\infty )) =g_{r}(\varvec{v})\), this is equivalent to

$$\begin{aligned} g_{r}(\varvec{u}) \le g_{r}(\varvec{v}), \quad \text{ for } \text{ all } r>0,\varvec{u}\prec \varvec{v}, \end{aligned}$$

which is equivalent to \(g_r(\cdot )\) being Schur-convex for each \(r>0\).

Now, consider the case \(\int _{\mathbb R}\left( |x|\wedge 1\right) M(\mathrm{d}x)=\infty \). Assume that \(g_r(\cdot )\) is Schur-convex for each \(r>0\). Here the Lévy measure is not well behaved near zero, so we begin by truncating it. For a vector \(\varvec{w}\in \mathbb R_+^n\) define

$$\begin{aligned} M_{\varvec{w}}^{(m)}(A) = \int \limits _{[|x|>1/m]}1_A(x) M_{\varvec{w}}(\mathrm{d}x), \quad A\in \mathfrak B(\mathbb R). \end{aligned}$$

Let \(\{X^{(m)}_{\varvec{w},t}:t\ge 0\}\) be a Lévy process where \(X^{(m)}_{\varvec{w},1}\sim ID(0,M^{(m)}_{\varvec{w}},0)\). Since \(M^{(m)}_{\varvec{w}}\) is symmetric, \(\int _{\mathbb R} \left( |x|\wedge 1\right) M^{(m)}_{\varvec{w}}(\mathrm{d}x)<\infty \), and \(M_{\varvec{w}}^{(m)}((r,\infty ))=g_{r\vee (1/m)}(\varvec{w})\) is Schur-convex for all \(r>0\), we can use arguments as in the previous case to show that

$$\begin{aligned} P(X^{(m)}_{\varvec{u},t} >r)\le P(X^{(m)}_{\varvec{v},t} >r), \quad \text{ for } \text{ all } t>0,r>0,\varvec{u}\prec \varvec{v}. \end{aligned}$$

We now remove the truncation by taking limits. Using standard results for convergence of infinitely divisible distributions (see e.g. Theorem 15.14 in Kallenberg (2002)) it is straightforward to show that \(X^{(m)}_{\varvec{u},t}\mathop {\rightarrow }\limits ^{d}X_{\varvec{u},t}\) and \(X^{(m)}_{\varvec{v},t}\mathop {\rightarrow }\limits ^{d}X_{\varvec{v},t}\) as \(m\rightarrow \infty \). Further, so long as \(\varvec{u},\varvec{v}\ne \varvec{0}\), we have \(M_{\varvec{u}}(\mathbb R)=M_{\varvec{v}}(\mathbb R)=\infty \) and thus, by Theorem 27.4 in Sato (1999), both \(X_{\varvec{u},t}\) and \(X_{\varvec{v},t}\) have continuous distributions. Hence, for every \(t>0\) and \(r>0\),

$$\begin{aligned} P(X_{\varvec{u},t} >r)=\lim _{m\rightarrow \infty }P(X^{(m)}_{\varvec{u},t} >r)\le \lim _{m\rightarrow \infty } P(X^{(m)}_{\varvec{v},t} >r)=P(X_{\varvec{v},t} >r). \end{aligned}$$

If \(\varvec{u}=\varvec{0}\) or \(\varvec{v}=\varvec{0}\) then \(\varvec{u}=\varvec{v}=\varvec{0}\) and the result is immediate.

Before proving Corollary 1, we give the following fact, which follows from the proof of Proposition A.6 in Ibragimov (2009).

Lemma 2

Let \(X_1,X_2,\ldots ,X_n\) and \(Y_1,Y_2,\ldots ,Y_n\) be two sets of independent random variables all having symmetric unimodal densities. If \(\mathrm{VaR}_\gamma (X_i)\le \mathrm{VaR}_\gamma (Y_i)\) for all \(=1,2,\ldots ,n\) and all \(\gamma \in (.5,1)\) then \(\mathrm{VaR}_\gamma (\sum _{i=1}^nX_i)\le \mathrm{VaR}_\gamma (\sum _{i=1}^nY_i)\) for all \(\gamma \in (.5,1)\).

Proof (Proof of Corollary 1)

We focus on the case \(t=1\) as the other cases are similar. If \(a=0\) the result follows by Theorem 1. Now assume that \(a\ne 0\). Let \(Z_{1},\ldots , Z_{n}\mathop {\sim }\limits ^{\mathrm{iid}}N(0,1)\) and let \(Y_{1},\ldots ,Y_{n}\mathop {\sim }\limits ^{\mathrm{iid}}ID(0,M,0)\) be independent sequences of random variables. If \(X_{1}, \ldots ,X_{n}\mathop {\sim }\limits ^{\mathrm{iid}}\mu \) then \((X_1,\ldots ,X_n)\mathop {=}\limits ^{d}(\sqrt{a}Z_1+Y_1, \ldots ,\sqrt{a}Z_n+Y_n)\). For any \(\varvec{w}\in \mathbb R^n_+\) we have \(X_{\varvec{w}} \mathop {=}\limits ^{d}\sqrt{a} Z_{\varvec{w}} + Y_{\varvec{w}}\). If \(\varvec{u}\prec \varvec{v}\) then Theorem 1 implies that \(\mathrm{VaR}_\gamma (Y_{\varvec{u}})\le \mathrm{VaR}_\gamma (Y_{\varvec{v}})\) and Proposition A.7 in Ibragimov (2009) implies that \(\mathrm{VaR}_\gamma (\sqrt{a}Z_{\varvec{u}})\le \mathrm{VaR}_\gamma (\sqrt{a}Z_{\varvec{v}})\). By Proposition A.5 in Ibragimov (2009) both \(Z_{\varvec{u}}\) and \(Y_{\varvec{u}}\) have symmetric and unimodal densities. Thus the result follows by Lemma 2.

Proof (Proof of Proposition 1.)

[Proof of Proposition 1.] If \(f_r(\cdot )\) is convex then \(g_r(\cdot )\) is Schur-convex by Proposition C.1 on page 92 in Marshall et al. (2011). Now assume that \(M\) has a continuous Lebesgue density \(m\). This implies that \(f_r(s)\) is a continuous function of \(s\) and thus it is convex if and only if \(g_r(\cdot )\) is Schur-convex by Proposition C.1 on page 92 and Proposition C.1.c on page 95 of Marshall et al. (2011). By Leibniz’s rule \(f_r(s)\) is differentiable in \(s\) and

$$\begin{aligned} \frac{\partial }{\partial s}f_r(s) = \frac{\partial }{\partial s}\int \limits _{r/s}^\infty m(x) \mathrm{d}x = rs^{-2}m(r/s) = r^{-1}(r/s)^{2}m(r/s). \end{aligned}$$

From here, the fact that a differentiable function is convex if and only if its derivative is non-decreasing gives the equivalence between the convexity of \(f_r(\cdot )\) and the non-increasing of \(x^2m(x)\). Conditions for \(g_r(\cdot )\) to be Schur-concave can be shown in a similar way using the corresponding properties of concave and Schur-concave functions.

Proof (Proof of Corollary 3)

[Proof of Corollary 3] By Theorem 30.1 in Sato (1999), \(W_Y\sim ID(0,M^*,0)\) where \(M^*\) has a continuous density \(m^*(x)\) given by

$$\begin{aligned} m^*(x)= \int \limits _{0}^\infty \frac{1}{\sqrt{2\pi s}}e^{-x^2/(2s)}m(s)\mathrm{d}s =\frac{|x|}{\sqrt{2\pi }} \int \limits _{0}^\infty e^{-u/2}m(x^2/u)u^{-3/2}\mathrm{d}u. \end{aligned}$$

Thus

$$\begin{aligned} x^2m^*(x)= \frac{1}{\sqrt{2\pi }} \int \limits _{0}^\infty e^{-u/2} (|x|/\sqrt{u})^3 m((|x|/\sqrt{u})^2)\mathrm{d}u. \end{aligned}$$

From here the result follows by Corollary 2.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Grabchak, M. Does value-at-risk encourage diversification when losses follow tempered stable or more general Lévy processes?. Ann Finance 10, 553–568 (2014). https://doi.org/10.1007/s10436-014-0249-6

Download citation

  • Received:

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s10436-014-0249-6

Keywords

JEL Classification

Navigation