Skip to main content

Advertisement

Log in

Optimal subsidy in promoting distributed renewable energy generation based on policy benefit

  • Original Paper
  • Published:
Clean Technologies and Environmental Policy Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

Distributed renewable energy generation via micro-grid plays a strategic role in defining energy policy for mitigating the pressure of global climate changes and energy reservation. As the initial installation of the renewable generation equipment is costly, it is necessary that the government provides incentive schemes to private investors aiming at mobilizing private capital to support distributed renewable energy generation. This paper brings forward optimal subsidy to stimulate private investment and focuses more on the government’s expected policy benefit. We formulate principal–agent model in which the private investor’s preference toward renewable generation is described as asymmetric information. We analyze the optimal subsidy with the purpose of maximizing the expected policy benefit; besides, this paper reveals benefit conflicts between the policymakers and the private investors, and examines the parameters’ effect on the government’s purpose under the condition of asymmetric information. Finally, a numerical example is presented to test the effectiveness of the model. The results shed new light on the role of investor’s preference in determining the share of renewable energy generation; moreover, it has important implication for policymakers: the results suggest that radically innovative systems will get down the cost curve and may display higher long-term potentials, but in the short run, the government should eliminate asymmetric information as far as possible and improve the investors’ environment-friendly awareness.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1
Fig. 2
Fig. 3

Similar content being viewed by others

References

  • Akikur RK et al (2016) Economic feasibility analysis of a solar energy and solid oxide fuel cell-based cogeneration system in Malaysia. Clean Technol Environ Policy 18:669–687

    Article  CAS  Google Scholar 

  • Bakshi N, Gans N (2010) Securing the containerized supply chain: analysis of government incentives for private investment. Manage Sci 56(2):219–233

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bierbrauer F (2009) A note on optimal income taxation, public goods provision and robust mechanism design. J Publ Econ 93(5):667–670

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Burtt D, Dargusch P (2015) The cost-effectiveness of household photovoltaic systems in reducing greenhouse gas emissions in Australia: linking subsidies with emission reductions. Appl Energy 148:439–448

    Article  CAS  Google Scholar 

  • Carley S, Browne TR (2013) Innovative US energy policy: a review of states’ policy experiences. Wiley Interdiscip Rev Energy Environ 2(5):488–506

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Casisi M, De Nardi A, Pinamonti P, Reini M (2015) Effect of different economic support policies on the optimal synthesis and operation of a distributed energy supply system with renewable energy sources for an industrial area. Energy Convers Manag 95:131–139

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Chen W, Hong X (2015) Design of effective subsidy policy to develop green buildings: from the perspective of policy benefit. Clean Technol Environ Policy 17(4):1029–1038

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Chiaroni D, Chiesa V, Colasanti L, Cucchiella F, D’Adamo I, Frattini F (2014) Evaluating solar energy profitability: a focus on the role of self-consumption. Energy Convers Manag 88:317–331

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cucchiella F, D’Adamo I (2015) Residential photovoltaic plant: environmental and economical implications from renewable support policies. Clean Technol Environ Policy 17(7):1929–1944

    Article  CAS  Google Scholar 

  • Cucchiella F, D’Adamo I, Gastaldi M (2014) Financial analysis for investment and policy decisions in the renewable energy sector. Clean Technol Environ Policy 17(4):887–904

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dietl HM, Grossmann M, Lang M, Wey S (2013) Incentive effects of bonus taxes in a principal-agent model. J Econ Behav Organ 89:93–104

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dincer F (2011) The analysis on wind energy electricity generation status, potential and policies in the world. Renew Sustain Energy Rev 15(9):5135–5142

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Duić N (2015) Is the success of clean energy guaranteed? Clean Technol Environ Policy 17(8):2093–2100

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fokaides PA, Miltiadous IC, Neophytou MKA, Spyridou LP (2014) Promotion of wind energy in isolated energy systems: the case of the Orites wind farm. Clean Technol Environ Policy 16(3):477–488

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fouquet D, Johansson TB (2008) European renewable energy policy at crossroads—Focus on electricity support mechanisms. Energy Policy 36(11):4079–4092

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Geller H, Harrington P, Rosenfeld AH, Tanishima S, Unander F (2006) Polices for increasing energy efficiency: thirty years of experience in OECD countries. Energy Policy 34(5):556–573

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Houser T, Mohan S, Heilmayr R (2009) A green global recovery? Assessing US economic stimulus and the prospects for international coordination. Policy Brief, Peterson Institute for International Economics, Washington

    Google Scholar 

  • Hua Y, Oliphant M, Hu EJ (2016) Development of renewable energy in Australia and China: a comparison of policies and status. Renew Energy 85:1044–1051

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • IEA (2014a) International Energy Agency. How solar energy could be the largest source of electricity by mid-century. http://www.iea.org/newsroomandevents/pressreleases/2014/september/how-solar-energy-could-be-the-largest-source-of-electricity-by-mid-century.html

  • IEA (2014b) Energy Policies of IEA Countries—The United States 2014 review. http://www.iea.org/bookshop/489-Energy_Policies_of_IEA_Countries_-_The_United_States

  • Iyer AV, Schwarz LB, Zenios SA (2005) A principal-agent model for product specification and production. Manage Sci 51(1):106–119

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lan Y, Zhao R, Tang W (2011) A bilevel fuzzy principal-agent model for optimal nonlinear taxation problems. Fuzzy Optim Decis Mak 10(3):211–232

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Maroušek J, Hašková S, Zeman R, Váchal J, Vaníčková R (2014) Assessing the implications of EU subsidy policy on renewable energy in Czech Republic. Clean Technol Environ Policy 17(2):549–554

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Masini A, Menichetti E (2013) Investment decisions in the renewable energy sector: an analysis of non-financial drivers. Technol Forecast Soc Chang 80(3):510–524

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mathews JA, Kidney S, Mallon K, Hughes M (2010) Mobilizing private finance to drive an energy industrial revolution. Energy Policy 38(7):3263–3265

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mayer FD, Salbego PRS, de Almeida TC, Hoffmann R (2015) Quantification and use of rice husk in decentralized electricity generation in Rio Grande do Sul State Brazil. Clean Technol Environ Policy 17(4):993–1003

    Article  CAS  Google Scholar 

  • Mizuno E (2014) Overview of wind energy policy and development in Japan. Renew Sustain Energy Rev 40:999–1018

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Niknam T, Golestaneh F, Malekpour A (2012) Probabilistic energy and operation management of a microgrid containing wind/photovoltaic/fuel cell generation and energy storage devices based on point estimate method and self-adaptive gravitational search algorithm. Energy 43(1):427–437

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Østergaard PA (2009) Reviewing optimisation criteria for energy systems analyses of renewable energy integration. Energy 34(9):1236–1245

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Timilsina GR, Kurdgelashvili L, Narbel PA (2012) Solar energy: markets, economics and policies. Renew Sustain Energy Rev 16(1):449–465

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgments

This research is supported by the National Social Science Foundation of China(major program) (2014B1—0130), the National Natural Science Foundation of China (71273173).

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Hui Yin.

Appendix

Appendix

Proof of Proposition 1

Proposition 1 including analysis of incentive-compatibility constraint and participation constrains. First, let L(x, y) = s(y)q(y+ v(α, y C(β, ρ, x, q(y)) and L(x, y) mean the utility function of private investor toward preference x but choosing the pair (s(x),q(x)), where xy  [0, b] and x ≠ y. Thus, for any given x, the incentive-compatibility constraint can be written as

\(L(x,x) \ge L(x,y),\forall y \in \left[ {0,b} \right]\), L(x, y) satisfies the first-order condition \(\frac{\partial L(x,y)}{\partial y}|_{y = x} = 0\) and the second-order condition \(\frac{{\partial^{2} L(x,y)}}{{\partial y^{2} }}|_{y = x} < 0\). It follows from the first-order condition that

$$s(x)\frac{{{\text{d}}q(x)}}{{{\text{d}}x}} + q(x)\frac{{{\text{d}}s(x)}}{{{\text{d}}x}} + \frac{{{\text{d}}v(\alpha ,x)}}{{{\text{d}}x}} - \frac{\partial C}{\partial q}\frac{{{\text{d}}q(x)}}{{{\text{d}}x}} = 0, \, \forall x \in \left[ {0,b} \right]$$
(P1)

Differentiating (P1) with respect to x,

$$\begin{aligned} s(x)\frac{{{\text{d}}^{2} q(x)}}{{{\text{d}}x^{2} }} + & q(x)\frac{{{\text{d}}^{2} s(x)}}{{{\text{d}}x^{2} }} + 2\frac{{{\text{d}}q(x)}}{{{\text{d}}x}}\frac{{{\text{d}}s(x)}}{{{\text{d}}x}} + \frac{{{\text{d}}^{2} v(\alpha ,x)}}{{{\text{d}}x^{2} }} - \frac{{{\text{d}}^{2} C}}{{{\text{d}}q^{2} }}\left(\frac{{{\text{d}}q(x)}}{{{\text{d}}x}}\right)^{2} \\ \, - & \frac{{{\text{d}}^{2} C}}{{{\text{d}}q{\text{d}}x}}\frac{{{\text{d}}q(x)}}{{{\text{d}}x}} - \frac{{{\text{d}}C}}{{{\text{d}}q}}\frac{{{\text{d}}^{2} q(x)}}{{{\text{d}}x^{2} }} = 0, \, \quad \forall x \in \left[ {0,b} \right] \\ \end{aligned}$$
(P2)

It follows from the second-order condition that

$$\begin{aligned} s(x)\frac{{{\text{d}}^{2} q(x)}}{{{\text{d}}x^{2} }} + & q(x)\frac{{{\text{d}}^{2} s(x)}}{{{\text{d}}x^{2} }} + 2\frac{{{\text{d}}q(x)}}{{{\text{d}}x}}\frac{{{\text{d}}s(x)}}{{{\text{d}}x}} + \frac{{{\text{d}}^{2} v(\alpha ,x)}}{{{\text{d}}x^{2} }} \\ \, - & \frac{{{\text{d}}^{2} C}}{{{\text{d}}q^{2} }}(\frac{{{\text{d}}q(x)}}{{{\text{d}}x}})^{2} - \frac{{{\text{d}}C}}{{{\text{d}}q}}\frac{{{\text{d}}^{2} q(x)}}{{{\text{d}}x^{2} }} < 0,\quad \, \forall x \in \left[ {0,b} \right] \\ \end{aligned}$$
(P3)

Applying (P2) to (P3) yields, \(\frac{{{\text{d}}^{2} C}}{{{\text{d}}q{\text{d}}x}}\frac{{{\text{d}}q(x)}}{{{\text{d}}x}} < 0,\quad \forall x \in \left[ {0,b} \right]\). Because we have assumed \(\frac{{\partial^{2} C}}{\partial x\partial q} \le 0\), thus we derive \(\frac{{{\text{d}}q(x)}}{{{\text{d}}x}} > 0\). The proof of part (i) is completed.

On the other hand, when xy, by \(\frac{dq(x)}{dx} > 0\), \(\frac{{\partial^{2} r(q(x),x)}}{\partial x\partial q} \le 0\) and integrating (P1) yields

$$\begin{aligned} [s(x)q(x) + v(\alpha ,x)] - [s(y)q(y) + v(\alpha ,y)] = & \int_{y}^{x} {\frac{\partial C(\beta ,\rho ,s,q(s))}{\partial q}} \frac{{{\text{d}}q(s)}}{{{\text{d}}s}}{\text{d}}s \\ \, \ge & \int_{y}^{x} {\frac{\partial C(\beta ,\rho ,x,q(s))}{\partial q}} \frac{{{\text{d}}q(s)}}{{{\text{d}}s}}{\text{d}}s = C(\beta ,\rho ,x,q(x)) - C(\beta ,\rho ,x,q(y)) \\ \end{aligned}$$

and when x < y,

$$\begin{aligned} [s(x)q(x) + v(\alpha ,x)] - [s(y)q(y) + v(\alpha ,y)] = & - \int_{x}^{y} {\frac{C(\beta ,\rho ,s,q(s))}{\partial q}} \frac{{{\text{d}}q(s)}}{ds}{\text{d}}s \\ \, \ge & \int_{x}^{y} {\frac{\partial C(\beta ,\rho ,x,q(s))}{\partial q}} \frac{{{\text{d}}q(s)}}{{{\text{d}}s}}{\text{d}}s = C(\beta ,\rho ,x,q(x)) - C(\beta ,\rho ,x,q(y)) \\ \end{aligned}$$

Therefore, no matter what is the relationship between x and y, we can always obtain incentive constraints (1). That is, we can get (1) from equation (i) and (ii).

For equation (iii), differentiating \(\prod (s(x),q(x),x) = s(x)q(x) + v(\alpha ,x) - C(\beta ,\rho ,x,q(x))\) with respect to x: \(\frac{\partial \prod }{\partial x} = q(x)\frac{{{\text{d}}s(x)}}{{{\text{d}}x}} + s(x)\frac{{{\text{d}}q(x)}}{{{\text{d}}x}} + \frac{{{\text{d}}v(\alpha ,x)}}{{{\text{d}}x}} - \frac{\partial C}{\partial q(x)}\frac{{{\text{d}}q(x)}}{{{\text{d}}x}} - \frac{\partial C}{\partial x}\) Substituting (P1) into \(\frac{\pi \prod }{\partial x}\), there will be \(\frac{\partial \pi }{\partial x} = - \frac{\partial C(\beta ,\rho ,x,q(x))}{\partial x} \ge 0\) which means П is increasing with respect to x. Thus, we can rewrite participant constraint as \(\prod (s(0),q(0),0) = s(0)q(0) + v(a,0) - C(\beta ,\rho ,0,q(0)) = C_{0},\) which represents the minimum of private investor’s profits.

Proof of Proposition 2

Since \(\frac{\partial \prod }{\partial x} = - \frac{\partial C(\beta ,\rho ,x,q(x))}{\partial x}\) , that is equivalent to \(\prod (s(x),q(x),x) - \prod (s(0),q(0),0) = \int_{0}^{x} { - \frac{C(\beta ,\rho ,x,q(x))}{\partial s}} {\text{d}}s,\) according to equation (iii), therefore, we can yield

$$s(x)q(x) = C(\beta ,\rho ,x,q(x)) - v(\alpha ,x) + C_{0} - \int_{0}^{x} {\frac{\partial C(\beta ,\rho ,s,q(s))}{\partial s}} {\text{d}}s$$
(P4)

then substituting (P4) into the objective function yields

$$\begin{aligned} E[U(q(x) + R(x) - s(x)q(x)] \hfill \\ = \int_{0}^{b} {\left[ {U(q(x) + R(x) - C(\beta ,\rho ,x,q(x)) + v(\alpha ,x) - C_{0} + \int_{0}^{x} {\frac{{\partial C(\beta ,\rho ,s,q(s))}}{{\partial s}}} {\text{d}}s} \right]f(x){\text{d}}x} \hfill \\ = \int_{0}^{b} {\left[ {U(q(x)) + R(x) - C(\beta ,\rho ,x,q(x)) + v(\alpha ,x) - C_{0} + \frac{{1 - F(x)}}{{f(x)}}\frac{{\partial C(\beta ,\rho ,x,q(x))}}{{\partial x}}} \right]f(x){\text{d}}x} \hfill \\ \end{aligned}$$
(P5)

Remarks

The decision vector (s(x), q(x)) in objective function is simplified as q(x) which indicates that (P5) is only decided by q(x) and is irrelevant with s(x).

Proof of Proposition 3

Let \(M(x) = U(q(x)) + R(x) - C(\beta ,\rho ,x,q(x)) + v(\alpha ,x) - C_{0} + \frac{1 - F(x)}{f(x)}\frac{\partial C(\beta ,\rho ,x,q(x))}{\partial x},\) then integrating assumption (iii) and the second-order variation of (P5) with respect to q, we can derive \(\int_{0}^{b} {\frac{{\partial^{2} M(q,x)}}{{\partial q^{2} }}(\delta q)^{2} dF(x)} < 0\). Hence, the optimal consumption of electricity under the preference satisfies ∫ b0 M(q(x), x)dF(x= 0, i.e.,

$$\frac{{\partial U(q^{**} (x))}}{{\partial q^{**} }} - \frac{{\partial C(\beta ,\rho ,x,q^{**} (x))}}{{\partial q^{**} }} + \frac{1 - F(x)}{f(x)}\frac{{\partial^{2} C(\beta ,\rho ,x,q^{**} (x))}}{{\partial x\partial q^{**} }} = 0$$
(P6)

Under the same circumstance, the optimal subsidy s**(x) can be obtained from equation (P4):

$$s^{**} (x) = \frac{{C(\beta ,\rho ,x,q^{**} (x)) - v(\alpha ,x) + C_{0} - \int_{0}^{x} {\frac{{\partial C(\beta ,\rho ,s,q^{**} (s))}}{\partial s}} {\text{d}}s}}{{q^{**} (x)}}$$
(P7)

Let \(G(x) = \frac{1 - F(x)}{f(x)}\), the derivation of (P6) with respect to x can be written as,\(\begin{aligned}&\left[\frac{{\partial^{2} U(q^{**} (x))}}{{\partial q^{**2} }} -\frac{{\partial^{2} C(\beta ,\rho ,s,q^{**} (s))}}{{\partial q^{**2}}} + G(x)\frac{{\partial^{3} C(\beta ,\rho ,s,q^{**}(s))}}{{\partial x\partial q^{**2} }}\right]\frac{{dq^{**}(x)}}{{{\text{d}}x}}=\frac{{\partial^{2} C(\beta ,\rho ,s,q^{**} (s))}}{{\partial x\partial q^{**} }} - \frac{\partial G}{\partial x}\frac{{\partial^{2} C(\beta ,\rho ,s,q^{**} (s))}}{{\partial x\partial q^{**} }} - G(x)\frac{{\partial^{3} C(\beta ,\rho,s,q^{**} (s))}}{{\partial x^{2} \partial q^{**} }} \end{aligned}\), according to the assumption part (ii) and (iii) \(\frac{\partial G}{\partial x} < 0\), we can obtain that \(\frac{{dq^{**} (x)}}{{{\text{d}}x}} > 0\). Consequently, the optimal and feasible solutions in model (3) is (s**(x), q**(x)). Therefore, all the proofs are completed.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Chen, W., Yin, H. Optimal subsidy in promoting distributed renewable energy generation based on policy benefit. Clean Techn Environ Policy 19, 225–233 (2017). https://doi.org/10.1007/s10098-016-1216-x

Download citation

  • Received:

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s10098-016-1216-x

Keywords

Navigation