Skip to main content
Log in

Mileage tax, property tax, sales tax, or fee: the best way to pay for commercial infrastructure that isn’t free

  • ORIGINAL PAPER
  • Published:
Review of Regional Research Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

The analysis in this paper uses a circular model to compare four alternatives for funding infrastructure necessitated by commercial development: a mileage tax, a sales tax, and development impact fees, to a traditional property tax. The results suggest that infrastructure funding mechanisms may influence household travel distance due to policy induced firm entry. This result complements the existing literature which finds policies affect travel costs through changes in city size while the fixed size model presented here suggests travel costs are still important. Because firms capture transport costs, in the form of higher prices, in the model, a mileage tax increases the number of firms exceeding the socially optimal number. Through a system of impact-fee financing, firms internalize infrastructure costs which reduces the number of firms and approaches the socially optimal number. Sales taxes provide an intermediate case between fees and property taxes. The model of homogeneous households and monopolistic competition between firms provides results most applicable to policy for suburban jurisdictions.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. One could think of the mileage tax as being somewhat similar to a gas tax but without explicitly modeling commute time and speed as suggested by Keeler and Small (1977), etc. to consider the two equivalent requires some strong assumptions.

  2. One could alternatively think of the n firms as shopping centers and the good as a bundle of goods purchased from a shopping center, thus relaxing the restrictive nature of the modeling assumptions.

  3. The literature examining the effect of tax policy on city size is mixed with some studies such as Brueckner and Kim (2003) finding increased property taxes may increase city size and Song and Zenou (2006) finding that increased property taxes result in decreased city size. The differences are potentially explained by differing elasticity of substitution between housing and other consumption goods. These mixed results may apply to different areas as urban residents may have a greater elasticity of substitution than suburban or rural families looking for space. The model in this paper holds population density as fixed and excludes changes in density resulting from a jurisdictions choice of revenue instrument.

  4. Matsumura (2000) demonstrates that the integer problem can be ignored with constant marginal cost of production, in this model c, and n \(\ge 3\).

  5. If no additional infrastructure were constructed, the consumer would bear the cost of the infrastructure not constructed in the form of additional congestion and service degradation. This alternative is not explicitly modeled here.

  6. A full derivation can be found in appendix  4.1.

  7. The model presented here does not incorporate a reduction in congestion from the mileage tax, a subject for future research.

  8. A full derivation can be found in appendix  4.2

  9. This assumes the tax is not a subsidy.

  10. A full derivation can be found in appendix  4.3.

  11. A full proof can be found in appendix  4.4.

  12. A full derivation can be found int he appendix.

  13. A full derivation can be found in appendix  4.6.

  14. A full proof can be found in appendix  4.7.

  15. A full derivation can be found in appendix  4.8.

  16. The model presented in this paper excludes property valuations but there is a literature examining the relationship between property values and tax rates. For example, Man and Bell (1996) find sales taxes in the Phoenix area are capitalized in home values and Yinger et al. (1988) who find property taxes to be only partially capitalized into home values.

References

  • Altshuler AA, Gomez-Ibanez JA, Howitt AM (1993) Regulation for revenue: the political economy of land use exactions. Brookings Institution Press

  • Anderson J (2004) Local development impact fees: an externality-based economic rationale. State Tax Notes 31(6)

  • Barnett E (2012) Bill would allow larger license fee, local gas tax. www.seattlemet.com

  • Bento AM, Goulder LH, Henry E, Jacobsen MR, von Haefen RH (2005) Distributional and efficiency impacts of gasoline taxes: an econometrically based multi-market study. Am Econ Rev 95(2):282–287

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Brueckner JK, Kim H-A (2003) Urban sprawl and the property tax. Int Tax Public Finance 10:5–23

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • BentoAM, Franco SF, Kaffine D (2006) The efficiency and distributional impacts of alternative anti-sprawl policies. J Urban Econ 59:121–141

  • Brueckner JK (1997) Infrastructure financing and urban development: the economics of impact fees. J Public Econ 66(3):383–407

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Brunori D (2009) Local gas taxes are a bad idea. http://www.tax.com/

  • Cutler H, Strelnikova I (April 2004) The impact of the US sales tax rate on city size and economic activity: a CGE approach. Urban Stud 41(4):875–885

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ihlanfeldt KR, Shaughnessy TM (2004) An empirical investigation of the effects of impact fees on housing and land markets. Reg Sci Urban Econ 34:639–661

  • Jones A, Snow A (2015) A normative analysis of impact fees for suburban commercial development. FinanzArchiv 71(2)

  • Keeler TE, Small KA (1977) Optimal peak-load pricing, investment, and service llevel on urban expressways. J Polit Econ 85(1):1–24

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lancaster KJ (1966) A new approach to consumer theory. J Polit Econ 74(2):13–2

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lipsey RG, Lancaster K (1956) The general theory of second best. Rev Econ Stud 24(1):11–32

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Man JE, Bell ME (1996) The impact of local sales tax on the value of owner-occupied housing. J Urban Econ 39:114–131

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mankiw NG, Whinston MD (1986) Free entry and social inefficiency. RAND J Econ 17(1):48–58

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Matsumura T (2000) Entry regulation and social welfare with an integer problem. J Econ 71(1):47–58

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mohring H, Harwitz M (1962) Highway benefits: an analytical framework. Northwestern University Press

  • Newbery DM (1990) Pricing and congestion: economic principles relevant to pricing roads. Oxford Rev Econ Policy 6(2):22–38

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Parry IWH, Oates WE (2000) Policy analysis in the presence of distorting taxes. J Policy Anal Manage 19(4):603–613

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Parry IWH (2011) US Energy Tax Policy, chapter How much should highway fuels be taxed? Cambridge 449 University Press

  • Parry IWH, Small KA (2005) Does britain or the united states have the right gasoline tax? Am Econ Rev 95(4):1276–1289

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Parry IWH, Timilsina GR (2010) How should passenger travel in mexico city be priced? J Urban Econ, 68:167–182

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Poterba JM (1991) Is the gasoline tax regressive? Tax Policy Econ 145–164

  • Salop SC (1979) Monopolistic competition with outside goods. Bell J Econ 10(1):141–156

  • Snow A, Warren RS (1996) The marginal welfare cost of public funds: theory and estimates. J Public Econ 61(2):289–305

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Song Y, Zenou Y (2006) Property tax and urban sprawl: theory and implications for us cities. J Urban Econ 60:519–534

  • Verhoef ET (2005) Second-best congestion pricing schemes in the monocentric city. J Urban Econ 58(3):367–388

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Wear B (2009) House poised to consider rise in gas tax. http://www.statesman.com/

  • Wong JD (1996) The impact of local option sales taxes on retail sales, employment, payrolls, and establishments: the case for kansas. Rev Reg Stud 26(2):166–176

    Google Scholar 

  • Yinger J, Bloom HS, Borsch-Supan A, Ladd HF (1988) Property taxes house value: the theory and estimation of intrajurisdictional property tax capitalization. Academic Press

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Adam T. Jones Ph.D..

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Jones, A. Mileage tax, property tax, sales tax, or fee: the best way to pay for commercial infrastructure that isn’t free. Rev Reg Res 36, 81–98 (2016). https://doi.org/10.1007/s10037-015-0099-3

Download citation

  • Received:

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s10037-015-0099-3

Keywords

Navigation