Skip to main content

Advertisement

Log in

A real options approach to environmental R&D project evaluation

  • Research Article
  • Growth and the Environment
  • Published:
Environmental Economics and Policy Studies Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

With the immense evolution of technology and consumers’ maturing anticipations, novel products’ development becomes the primary way that companies adapt to survive in the growing international contention. Creation or innovation can allow the organization to stand one step forward of the competition and to conduct the competition in the direction it selects. We examined the evaluation system of real options approach to a biomimicry R&D project together with conventional R&D and environmental R&D projects. This model considers uncertainties of investment cost and cash flow of the new product in each project. We find that investment on environmental and biomimicry technologies will achieve promising expectations in Asian area when certain environmental demands increase.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1
Fig. 2
Fig. 3
Fig. 4
Fig. 5
Fig. 6
Fig. 7

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. In this paper, all the units of the product values (e.g., sales, profits) are million Yen if there is no attached explanation.

References

  • Amram M, Kulatilaka N (1999) Real options: managing strategic investment in an uncertain world, vol 4. Harvard Business School Press, Boston, p 3

    Google Scholar 

  • Angel D, Rock MT (2009) Environmental rationalities and the development state in East Asia: prospects for a sustainability transition. Technol Forecast Soc Chang 76(2):229–240

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Arora S, Gangopadhyay S (1995) Toward a theoretical model of voluntary over compliance. J Econ Behav Organ 28(3):289–309

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bloomberg (2013) Bloomberg. http://www.bloomberg.co.jp

  • Bohm M, Collen B, Baillie JE, Bowles P, Chanson J, Cox N, Cheylan M (2013) The conservation status of the world’s reptiles. Biol Conserv 157:372–385

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Borison A (2005) Real options analysis: where are the emperor’s clothes? J Appl Corp Financ 17:17–31

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Brennan MJ, Schwartz ES (1985) Evaluating natural resource investments. J Bus 58:135–157

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Chow LCH (2003) Themes in current Asian energy. Energy Policy 31:1047–1049

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Copeland T, Antikarov V (2005) Meeting the Georgetown challenge. J Appl Corp Financ 17(2):32–51

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Detert N, Kotani K (2013) Real options approach to renewable energy investments in Mongolia. Energy Policy 56:136–150

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dixit AK, Pindyck RS (1994) Investment under uncertainty. Princeton UP, Princeton

    Google Scholar 

  • Dorian JP (2006) Central Asia: a major emerging energy player in the 21st century. Energy Policy 34:544–555

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Eisenhardt KM, Tabrizi BN (1995) Accelerating adaptive processes: product innovation in the global computer industry. Adm Sci Q 40:84–110

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • FA (2013) Financial-analysis. http://www.financial-analysis.jp

  • Fujii H, Iwata K, Kaneko S, Managi S (2013) Corporate environmental and economic performance of Japanese manufacturing firms: empirical study for sustainable development. Bus Strategy Environ 22(3):187–201

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Goldenberg J, Lehmann DR, Mazursky D (2001) The idea itself and the circumstances of its emergence as predictors of new product success. Manage Sci 47(1):69–84

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Guerrero R (2007) The case for real options made simple. J Appl Corp Financ 19:38–49

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hamamoto M (2006) Environmental regulation and the productivity of Japanese manufacturing industries. Resour Energy Econ 28(4):299–312

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • IMF (2013) International monetary fund. http://www.imf.org/external/pubs/ft/weo/2013/01/weodata/index.aspx

  • Kenyon C, Cheliotis G (2002) Dark fiber valuation. Eng Econ 47(3):264–307

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kim HJ, Weiss MB, Morel B (2009) Real options and technology management: assessing technology migration options in wireless industry. Telemat Inform 26(2):180–192

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kjaerland F (2007) A real option analysis of investments in hydropower—the case of Norway. Energy Policy 35(11):5901–5908

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kometani M (1998) Product development behavior of Japanese firms: an empirical investigation. Asian Econ Rev 56(4):471–509

    Google Scholar 

  • Kreft H, Jetz W (2007) Global patterns and determinants of vascular plant diversity. Proc Natl Acad Sci 104(14):5925–5930

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kulatilaka N (1988) Valuing the flexibility of flexible manufacturing systems. IEEE Trans Eng Manag 35(4):250–257

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lee SC (2011) Using real option analysis for highly uncertain technology investments: the case of wind energy technology. Renew Sustain Energy Rev 15(9):4443–4450

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lee SC, Shih LH (2009) The policy planning for renewable energy: a real option based analysis. 2009 Cross-straits energy economic conference

  • Lieberman M, Montgomery D (1988) First mover advantages. Strateg Manag J 9:41–58

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lint O, Pennings E (2001) An option approach to the new product development process: a case study at Philips Electronics. R&D Manag 31(2):163–172

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Majd S, Pindyck RS (1987) Time to build, option value, and investment decisions. J Financ Econ 18(1):7–27

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Maxwell JW, Decker CS (2005) Voluntary environmental investment and responsive regulation. Environ Resour Econ 33(4):425–439

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Maxwell JW, Lyon TP, Hackett SC (2000) Self-regulation and social welfare: the political economy of corporate environmentalism. J Law Econ 43(2):583–618

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • McDonald R, Siegel D (1986) The value of waiting to invest. Q J Econ 101(4):707–727

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • MOF (2013) Ministry of finance Japan. http://www.mof.go.jp/jgbs/reference/interest_rate/data/jgbcm_2010.csv

  • Myers S (1977) Determinants of corporate borrowing. J Financ Econ 5:147–175

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Myers SC, Maid S (2001) Abandonment value and project life. In: Schwartz ES, Trigeorgis L (eds) Real options and investment under uncertainty: classical readings and recent contributions, papers presented in conferences. MIT Press, MA, pp 295–313

  • Newton D, Paxson DA, Widdick M (2004) Real R&D options. Int J Manag Rev 5/6(2):113–130

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • NISTEP (2013) National Institute of Science and Technology Policy. http://www.nistep.go.jp/research/rd-and-innovation/surveys-on-rd-activities-by-private-corporations

  • Pindyck RS (1993) Investments of uncertain cost. J Financ Econ 34(1):53–76

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Porter ME, Van der Linde C (1995) Toward a new conception of the environment-competitiveness relationship. J Econ Perspect 9(4):97–118

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Robinson WT (1988) Sources of market pioneer advantages: the case of industrial goods industries. J Mark Res 25:87–94

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Schwartz ES (2004) Patents and R&D as real options. Econ Notes 33(1):23–54

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Schwartz ES, Moon M (2000) Evaluating research and development investments. In: Brennan MJ, Trigeorgis L (eds) Innovation, infrastructure and strategic options. Oxford University Press, Oxford, pp 85–106

    Google Scholar 

  • Segerson K, Miceli TJ (1998) Voluntary environmental agreements: good or bad news for environmental protection? J Environ Econ Manag 36(2):109–130

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Shimomura S (2010) The new trends in next generation biomimicry material technology: learning from biodiversity. Q Rev 37:53–75

    Google Scholar 

  • Short F, Carruthers T, Dennison W, Waycott M (2007) Global seagrass distribution and diversity: a bioregional model. J Exp Mar Biol Ecol 350(1):3–20

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Srivastava L, Misra N (2007) Promoting regional energy co-operation in South Asia. Energy Policy 35:3360–3368

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Thavasi V, Ramakrishna S (2009) Asia energy mixes from socio-economic and environmental perspectives. Energy Policy 37(11):4240–4250

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Toyo (2011) Corporate social responsibility database, Toyo Keizai Inc

  • Trigeorgis L (1996) Real options: managerial flexibility and strategy in resource allocation. The MIT Press, Cambridge

    Google Scholar 

  • Trigeorgis L, Mason SP (1987) Valuing managerial flexibility. Midl Corp Financ J 5(1):14–21

    Google Scholar 

  • Verdu AJ, Tamayo I, Ruiz-Moreno A (2012) The moderating effect of environmental uncertainty on the relationship between real options and technological innovation in high-tech firms. Technovation 32(9):579–590

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Walter L, Isenmann R, Moehrle MG (2011) Bionics in patents—semantic-based analysis for the exploitation of bionic principles in patents. Proc Eng 9:620–632

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Zhu L (2012) A simulation based real options approach for the investment evaluation of nuclear power. Comput Ind Eng 63(3):585–593

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgments

This work was conducted under Grant-in-Aid for Specially Promoted Research (26000001) by the Japan Society for the Promotion of Science.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Shunsuke Managi.

Appendices

Appendix 1: Proof of the modeling valuation

When the investment of the R&D project has been successfully accomplished, the value of the project depends only on the generated net cash flows. Assume that the product loses its uniqueness at time, where \(T = {\raise0.7ex\hbox{$Y$} \!\mathord{\left/ {\vphantom {Y {\Delta t}}}\right.\kern-0pt} \!\lower0.7ex\hbox{${\Delta t}$}}\) and ∆t is the step size; also assume that the residuary value of the project, represented by the possible cash flows created after the singularity disappears, is a multiple M of the cash flows at time, and r stands for the risk-free rate, the value V must satisfy the following Bellman equation (dynamic programming equation):

$$V = C{\text{d}}t + e^{{ - r{\text{d}}t}} \left[ {V + E\left( {{\text{d}}V} \right)} \right]$$
(9)

The first term shows the obtained cash flow during, and the second term represents the discounted value of the project after the period of. Then, use Ito’s Lemma to divide:

$${\text{d}}V = V_{t} {\text{d}}t + V_{C} {\text{d}}C + \frac{1}{2}V_{\text{CC}} ({\text{d}}C)^{2}$$
(10)

Put Eqs. (4) and (10) into Eq. (9):

$$V = Cd + e^{{ - r{\text{d}}t}} \left\{ {V + E\left[ {V_{t} {\text{d}}t + V_{C} \left( {\left( {\alpha - \eta } \right)C{\text{d}}t + \sigma C{\text{d}}z} \right) + \frac{1}{2}V_{\text{CC}} ( {\left({\alpha - \eta } \right)^{2} C^{2} \left( {{\text{d}}t} \right)^{2} + \sigma^{2} C^{ 2} \left( {{\text{d}}z} \right)^{2} + 2\left( {\alpha - \eta } \right)\sigma^{2} C^{2} {\text{d}}t{\text{d}}z})} \right]} \right\}$$
(11)

E(dw) = 0 for dz is subject to Wiener distribution; E(dw)2 = dt because of Ito’s Lemma. Let:

$$\left[ {e^{{ - r{\text{d}}t}} \left( {\frac{1}{2}\sigma^{2} C^{2} V_{\text{CC}} + \left( {\alpha - \eta } \right)CV_{C} + V_{t} } \right) + C} \right]{\text{d}}t - \left( {1 - e^{{ - r{\text{d}}t}} } \right)V = 0$$
(12)

Dividing Eq. (12) by the partial differential equation (PDE) of the project value is:

With boundary condition:

$$V(C,T) = M \times C$$
(13)

Therefore, the solution of the PDE is:

$$V\left( {C,t} \right) = \frac{C}{{r - \left( {\alpha - \eta } \right)}}\left\{ {1 - e^{{ - \left[ {r - \left( {\alpha - \eta } \right)} \right]\left( {T - t} \right)}} } \right\} + MCe^{{ - \left[ {r - \left( {\alpha - \eta } \right)} \right]\left( {T - t} \right)}}$$
(14)

Using Ito’s Lemma and putting Eq. (3) to Eq. (14), the true stochastic process for the value of the successful R&D project can be represented by:

$$\frac{{{\text{d}}V}}{V} = \left( {r + \eta } \right){\text{d}}t + \sigma {\text{d}}z$$
(15)

Before the accomplishment of the investment, the value of R&D project depends on the expected total investing cost K and the possible cash flow after completion. Also, it must satisfy the following Bellman equation:

$$F\left( {C,K,t} \right) = - I{\text{d}}t + e^{{ - (r + \lambda ){\text{d}}t}} \left[ {F\left( {C,K,t} \right) + E\left( {{\text{d}}F\left( {C,K,t} \right)} \right)} \right]$$
(16)

The first term stands for the cost to invest during at the time point of, and the second term means the discounted value of the project after the period of λ donates for the Possion probability of failure. According to Schwartz and Moon (2000), it can be directly put into the discounted rate. Then, use Ito’s Lemma to divide:

$${\text{d}}F = F_{t} {\text{d}}t + F_{C} {\text{d}}C + F_{K} {\text{d}}K + \frac{1}{2}F_{\text{CC}} ({\text{d}}C)^{2} + \frac{1}{2}F_{\text{KK}} ({\text{d}}K)^{2} + F_{\text{CK}} {\text{d}}C{\text{d}}K$$
(17)

Put Eqs. (2), (3), and (10) into Eq. (17). Afterwards, by letting and removing the terms of dt with high order, the PDE of F(C, K, T) can be shown to be:

$${\text{Max}}_{I} \left[ {\frac{1}{2}\sigma^{2} C^{2} F_{\text{CC}} + \frac{1}{2}\rho^{2} (IK)F_{\text{KK}} + \sigma \rho \varphi C(IK)^{{\frac{1}{2}}} F_{\text{CK}} + (a - \eta )CF_{C} - IF_{K} + F_{t} - (r + \lambda )F - 1} \right] = 0$$
(18)

And the boundary condition for this PDE is:

$$F\left( {C,0,\tau } \right) = V\left( {C,\tau } \right)$$
(19)

Appendix 2: Progress of the LSM solution

The LSM method applied for valuing options is based on Monte Carlo simulation and least squares regression. The decision for project abandonment is evaluated at discrete points in time, instead of continuously. This seems to be a more reasonable assumption on R&D projects’ analysis (Schwartz 2004).

In the simulations, the discrete approximation to remaining investment cost process and cash flow process in risk-neutral version is:

$$K(t + \Delta t) = K(t) - I\Delta t + \rho \left[ {IK} \right]^{1/2} \Delta t^{1/2} \varepsilon_{x}$$
(20)
$$C\left( {t + \Delta t} \right) = C\left( t \right)\exp \left[ {\left( {\alpha - \frac{1}{2}\sigma^{2} - \eta } \right)\Delta t + \sigma \left( {\Delta t} \right)^{1/2} \varepsilon_{z} } \right]$$
(21)

where φ donates for the correlation between cost and cash flow uncertainty. In these simulations, ε x and ε c can be calculated as ε x = u 1 and \(\varepsilon_{Z} = \phi u_{1} + u_{2} \left( {1 - \phi^{2} } \right)^{{\frac{1}{2}}}\), where u 1 and u 2 are independent random drawings from a standardized normal distribution. These two parameters can be obtained with the pertinent function of the MATLAB™.

If Y is the time to the expiration of the uniqueness and ∆t is the step size, \(T = {\raise0.7ex\hbox{$Y$} \!\mathord{\left/ {\vphantom {Y {\Delta t}}}\right.\kern-0pt} \!\lower0.7ex\hbox{${\Delta t}$}}\) is the number of periods per path in the simulation. Equations (20) and (21) are used to generate G paths of T periods each of costs to completion and cash flows. Each path is then described by each parameter (K, C). During the duration of R&D project, the cash flows represent the occurred value if the investment is terminated.

If the project has not been abandoned before, at the final observation date of a given period (time, the last stage of operational period), the value of the R&D project is given by the boundary condition:

$$W\left( {g,j} \right) = \left\{ {\begin{array}{*{20}l} { M \cdot C\left( {g,T} \right), \quad K\left( {g,T} \right) = 0 } \hfill \\ {0,\quad \qquad \qquad K\left( {g,T} \right) > 0} \hfill \\ \end{array} } \right.$$
(22)

where K(g, T) = 0 means the R&D project is finished; K(g, T) > 0 means the project is still ongoing.

At any period, if investment has been terminated in those paths, the value of the project will be computed recursively by:

$$W\left( {g,j} \right) = e^{ - r\Delta t } \Delta W\left( {g,j + 1} \right) + C\left( {g,j} \right)\Delta t$$
(23)

If investment has not been finished in those paths, the conditional expected value of duration will be estimated by regression. The dependent variable is the discounted value of R&D project at j + 1 period defined as e rΔt W(gj + 1), and the independent variable is the awaited cash flow of the new product at period. The fitted value \(\overset{\lower0.5em\hbox{$\smash{\scriptscriptstyle\frown}$}}{W} \left( {g,f} \right)\) can be calculated by polynomial regression. By comparing the conditional expected value of the new product \(\overset{\lower0.5em\hbox{$\smash{\scriptscriptstyle\frown}$}}{W} \left( {g,j} \right)\) with the investment expenditure, we can obtain the following expression:

$$W\left( {g,j} \right) = \left\{ {\begin{array}{*{20}l} { 0, \quad \qquad \qquad \overset{\lower0.5em\hbox{$\smash{\scriptscriptstyle\frown}$}}{W} \left( {g,j} \right) < I(g,j) } \hfill \\ {\overset{\lower0.5em\hbox{$\smash{\scriptscriptstyle\frown}$}}{W} \left( {g,j} \right) - I\left( {g,j} \right),\quad \overset{\lower0.5em\hbox{$\smash{\scriptscriptstyle\frown}$}}{W} \left( {g,j} \right) \ge I(g,j)} \hfill \\ \end{array} } \right.$$
(24)

The recursion continues by rolling back in time and repeating the procedure until the decisions at each possible exercise time for all paths have been determined.

The computation starts from time zero, proceeding along each path until the final observation date of a given period or the first stopping time. Then by discounting the resultant cash flows to time zero, and taking the average value over all the G paths, we can eventually work out the value of the R&D project with abandonment option (RV). More detail information and discussion on this methodology can be found in the study of Schwartz (2004).

Appendix 3: Tables that describe inputs and outputs of each firm

See Tables 6 and 7.

Table 6 Parameters of each firm
Table 7 Project values of each firm for five scenarios

Appendix 4: Tables of sensitivity analysis for each firm

See Tables 8, 9, 10 and 11.

Table 8 Sensitivity analysis of success rate for each firm (Scenario ENV2)
Table 9 Sensitivity analysis of cash flow for each firm (Scenario ENV2)
Table 10 Sensitivity analysis of success rate for each firm (Scenario BIO2)
Table 11 Sensitivity analysis of cost for each firm (Scenario BIO2)

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Managi, S., Zhang, Z. & Horie, S. A real options approach to environmental R&D project evaluation. Environ Econ Policy Stud 18, 359–394 (2016). https://doi.org/10.1007/s10018-016-0147-4

Download citation

  • Received:

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s10018-016-0147-4

Keywords

JEL classification

Navigation