Skip to main content
Log in

Optimal know-how transfers in licensing contracts

  • Published:
Journal of Economics Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

This paper studies optimal licensing contracts in the presence of moral hazard associated with costly provision of know-how by the licensor. In our setting, the target market is defined as the fraction of consumers that have a positive valuation for the product that is licensed. It is shown that, no matter how thin the target market is, know-how transfer always takes place. Consistent with actual practice, the optimal licensing contract includes a royalty on sales to attenuate the moral hazard problem. However, full know-how transfer will not occur for low enough maximum willingness to pay and high enough convexity of know-how cost. Finally, it is also shown that the effective (inclusive of the royalty) marginal cost exceeds the one when know-how transfer does not occur thus showing a potential malfunction of know-how transfer specially if the recipient is a developing country.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. Rostoker (1984) reports, for a sample of 37 US firms, that royalty alone was used in 39 % of the time, fixed fee alone in 13 %, and royalty plus fixed fee licensing was employed 46 % of the time. Taylor and Silberston (1973) report similar percentages. For a sample of Spanish firms, Macho-Stadler et al. (1996) find that about 60 % of the contracts are based exclusively on royalty payments. Bousquet et al. (1998) report that the research center of France Telecom employs royalties in 78 % of the licensing contracts. Vishwasrao (2007) finds that licensing contracts are more likely to use royalties when sales are relatively high, whereas volatile sales and greater profitability favor fixed fee contracts.

  2. These arguments are backed by empirical evidence. Thus, Macho-Stadler et al. (1996) point out that royalties are used more frequently when the licensing contract includes know-how transfer, which emphasizes the relevance of moral hazard problems in technology transfer agreements. Mendi (2005) considers that payments are sensitive to contract duration, with longer contracts being more likely to include royalty payments. Finally, Vishwasrao (2007), for a sample of Indian manufacturing firms, finds that the use of royalties is associated with firms in industries where the licensor wishes to control the output levels and reputation. Her analysis also provides support for risk sharing through royalty payments.

  3. Both approaches are complementary to each other, those in which technology quality is endogenous and the one we take. The former is more appropriate when technology transmission is mainly including codified knowledge, while the latter is more appropriate when the technology requires uncodified knowledge in the form of know-how and which is firm specific.

  4. We have opted to present the analysis as three different “strategies” or options for the purpose of the presentation, although the mathematical problem is just one where the variable that defines whether there is full or partial transmission of know-how is bounded to the interval [0, 1].

  5. To be formally precise, the equilibrium is any royalty in the interval because the licensor’s profits are independent of r once \(k=0\) and \(0<m<m'\), however we choose \(r=0\) for simplicity in the exposition. But we could potentially observe positive royalties that lead to zero k because the relevant market is too thin.

  6. See the “Appendix” for more details on the derivation of the solution.

  7. The quantity \(m^*\) is the precise level of the relevant market that satisfies \(k^*(r^*)=k^{**}(r^*).\)

  8. Obviously when the corresponding equilibrium levels of know-how are above one, then partial collapses to full transfer of know-how.

  9. In order to be consistent, we need to introduce a restriction on \(\alpha \), which is \(\alpha <\frac{c}{2} \). This restriction guaranties that the case of full transmission of know-how leads to positive equilibrium outputs. Therefore, \(\alpha \) belongs to the interval \( \big ( \frac{c^2}{2a}, \frac{c}{2} \big ).\)

  10. Also notice that the lower branch in (14) is positive only if \(\alpha <\frac{c(\sqrt{4a^2+c^2}-c)}{4a}\).

  11. All proofs are in the “Appendix”.

  12. Recall that we are implicitly assuming that both exporting and FDI entail even larger costs and are thus dominated by licensing.

References

  • Arora A (1996) Contracting for tacit knowledge: the provision of technical services in technology licensing contracts. J Dev Econ 50(2):233–256

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Aulakh PS, Cavusgil ST, Sarkar MB (1998) Compensation in international licensing agreements. J Int Bus Stud 29(2): 409–419 (2nd Qtr., 1998)

  • Beggs A (1992) The licensing of patents under asymmetric information. Int J Ind Organ 10(2):171–191

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bousquet A, Crémer H, Ivaldi M, Wolkowicz M (1998) Risk sharing in licensing. Int J Ind Organ 16(5):535–554

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Choi JP (2001) Technology transfer with moral hazard. Int J Ind Organ 19(1–2):249–266

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Feess E, Hoeck M, Lorz O (2009) International technology transfers and competition. Rev Int Econ 17(5):1038–1052

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gallini N, Wright B (1990) Technology transfer under asymmetric information. Rand J Econ 21(1):147–160

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kabiraj T, Marjit S (1993) International technology transfer under potential threat of entry. A Cournot-Nash framework. J Dev Econ 42:75–88

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kamien MI (1992) Patent licensing. Handb Game Theory Econ Appl 1:331–354

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kamien MI, Tauman Y (2002) Patent licensing: the inside story. Manch Sch 70(1):7–15

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Macho-Stadler I, Pérez-Castrillo D (1991) Contrats de licence et asymétrie d’Information. Ann d’Écon Stat 24:189–208

    Google Scholar 

  • Macho-Stadler I, Martínez-Giralt X, P érez-Castrillo D (1996) The role of information in licensing contract design. Res Policy 25:43–57

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Marjit S, Mukherjee A (2001) Technology transfer under asymmetric information: the role of equity participation. J Inst Theor Econ 157:282–300

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Maskus KE (2004) Encouraging international technology transfer. In: International centre for trade and sustainable development, Geneva (issue paper no. 7)

  • Mattoo A, Olarreaga M, Saggi K (2004) Mode of foreign entry, technology transfer, and FDI policy. J Dev Econ 75(1):95–111

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mendi P (2005) The structure of payments in technology transfer contracts: evidence from Spain. J Econ Manag Strateg 14(2):403–429

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mukherjee A (2009) Technology licensing. In: Rajan RS, Reinert KA (eds) Princeton encyclopaedia of the world economy. Princeton University Press, Princeton, pp 1072–1077

    Google Scholar 

  • Mukherjee A, Pennings E (2006) Tariffs, licensing and market structure. Eur Econ Rev 50:1699–1707

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mukherjee A, Tsai Y (2015) Does two-part tariff licensing agreement enhance both welfare and profit? J Econ 116:63–76

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Rockett K (1990) The quality of licensed technology. Int J Ind Organ 8:559–574

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Rostoker MD (1984) A survey of corporate licensing. IDEA J Law Technol 20:59–92

  • Saggi K (2002) Trade, foreign direct investment, and international technology transfer: a survey. World Bank Res Obs 2:191–235

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Sen D, Tauman Y (2007) General licensing schemes for a cost-reducing innovation. Games Econ Behav 59:163–186

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Sinha UB (2010) Strategic licensing, exports, FDI, and host country welfare. Oxf Econ Pap 62:114–131

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Taylor CT, Silberston ZA (1973) The economic impact of the patent system. A study of the British experience. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge

    Google Scholar 

  • Teece DJ (1977) Technology transfer by multinational firms: the resource cost of transferring technological know-how. Econ J 87:242–261

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Vishwasrao S (2007) Royalties vs. fees: how do firms pay for foreign technology? Int J Ind Organ 25(4):741–759

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Wang XH (1998) Fee versus royalty licensing in a Cournot duopoly model. Econ Lett 60:55–62

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgments

We thank the editor and two anonymous referees for their helpful comments and suggestions. We also thank comments from seminar participants at Universidad de Navarra and Strathmore University, as well as to conference participants in the 11th International Industrial Organization Conference at Boston and XXVIII Jornadas de Economía Industrial at Segovia. Financial support from Fundación Ramón Areces (Mendi), as well as from the Spanish Ministry of Economy and Competitiveness under the Project ECO2013-45045-R, and from Generalitat Valenciana under the Project PROMETEOII/2014/054 (Moner-Colonques and Sempere-Monerris) is gratefully acknowledged. All errors are our own.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Pedro Mendi.

Appendix

Appendix

1.1 Proofs

In order to prove the propositions, it is first important to present first the three different cases that arise when there is partial transfer of know-how. As presented in the text, there are two different intervals in the royalty rate that induce partial know-how transfers. The first one, for \([a(1-2m)-c]< r \le [a(1-2m)-c]\big (\frac{2\alpha a}{2\alpha a-c^{2}}\big ) \), corresponds to \(k(r) = k^{*} \) which implies en effective marginal cost of \(\hat{c}= a(1-2m)\) and therefore all consumers in the relevant market buy the good, \(q^*(\hat{c})=m\). Thus, the licensor maximizes the following function, \(rm+ am^{2}-\frac{\alpha ( 1+( \frac{r-a(1-2m)}{c})^{2}}{2}\). The interior equilibrium royalty rate is \(r^{*}=\frac{mc^{2}}{\alpha }+ [a(1-2m)-c] \), it is decreasing in m and leads to \(k(r^{*}) = k^{*} =\frac{ mc}{\alpha }\) and \(f^*=am^2 \). Thus, for this region the licensor profits are equal to \(\Pi ^{L*}_p= \frac{(mc)^{2}}{2\alpha }+ m(a(1-m)-c)\).

Consider now, \([a(1-2m)-c](\frac{2\alpha a}{2\alpha a-c^{2}}) < r \le \frac{ 2 \alpha a}{c}\). Noticing that \(k(r) = k^{**} \) in this interval, and that \( \hat{c}(r)= c(1- \frac{r c}{2 \alpha a})+ r \), so that not all consumers in the high-end market buy the good. The licensor maximizes the following function: \(r ( \frac{ a- \hat{c}(r)}{2a} )+ \frac{ (a-\hat{c}(r))^{2}}{4a}- \frac{\alpha }{2}(\frac{r c}{2 \alpha a})^{2} \). Yielding an interior solution which equals, \(r^{**}= \frac{2 \alpha a c^{2}(a-c)}{4 \alpha ^{2} a^{2}+2 \alpha a c^{2}-c^{4}} \). Given \(r^{**}\), the equilibrium know-how, the fixed fee, licensor’s payoffs and technology payments are as follows: \( k(r^{**})=\frac{c^{3}(a-c)}{4 \alpha ^{2} a^{2}+2 \alpha a c^{2}-c^{4}}\); \(f^{**}= \frac{4 \alpha ^{4} a^{3} (a-c)^{2}}{(4 \alpha ^{2} a^{2}+2 \alpha a c^{2}-c^{4})^{2}}\); \(\Pi ^{L**}_p= \frac{\alpha (2 \alpha a + c^{2})(a-c)^{2}}{ 2(4 \alpha ^{2} a^{2}+2 \alpha a c^{2}-c^{4})}\).

Next, it must be checked whether the above interior solutions \(r^{*} \) and \(r^{**} \) are consistent with the intervals at which they apply. That is, whether \(r^{*} \in [a(1-2m)-c, (a(1-2m)-c)( \frac{2\alpha a}{2\alpha a-c^{2}})] \) and \(r^{**} \in [(a(1-2m)-c)(\frac{ 2\alpha a}{2\alpha a-c^{2}}),\frac{2\alpha a}{c}] \). Considering first \( r^{*} \), it is easy to show that it is always greater than the lower bound in the interval, but to satisfy the upper bound it is required that \(m < \frac{\alpha (a-c)}{4 \alpha a-c^{2}}=m^{*} \). Then, we conclude that the equilibrium royalty is \(r^{*} \) if \(m< m^{*}\), while it is \(\overline{r} \) if \(m > m^{*}\) where \( \overline{r} \) is precisely the upper bound in the interval, i.e. \(\overline{ r} = (a(1-2m)-c)(\frac{2\alpha a}{2\alpha a-c^{2}})=(\frac{4\alpha a^2}{2\alpha a-c^{2}})(\overline{m}-m)\). Next consider \(r^{**} \), it is easy to check that it is greater than the lower bound in the interval as long as \(m > \frac{2 \alpha ^2 a(a - c)}{4 \alpha ^2 a^2+2 \alpha a c^2-c^4}= m^{**}\). Thus, if \(m > m^{**} \) then the equilibrium royalty rate is \(r^{**} \), being \(\overline{r}\) otherwise. Finally, \(r^{**}\) is smaller than the upper bound in the interval if and only if \(\alpha > \frac{c ( \sqrt{4ac+c^2}-c)}{4 a} \).

When the equilibrium royalty is \(\overline{r}\) then \(k(\overline{r})=(\frac{2 a c}{2\alpha a-c^{2}})(m'-m), \hat{c}(\overline{r})=a(1-2m)\), also \(q(\hat{c}(\overline{r}))=m\), the fixed fee equals \(am^2\) and the licensor’s profits are \(\frac{8 \alpha ^2 a^2 m (a(1-m)-c)-c^2(\alpha (a-c)^2+2am^2(2 \alpha a-c^2)) }{2(2\alpha a-c^2)^2}\).

Finally, once the licensor knows how payoffs depend on m for each possible level of know-how transfer, it must decide which one to implement. In order to properly undertake the analysis, a first step must be done which is to rank the four thresholds on m that determine the licensor’s payoffs.

  1. (i)

    First, it is easy to find that \(m^*<m^{**}<m'\) just assuming \( \alpha > \frac{c^2}{2a}\).

  2. (ii)

    However, the position of \(\hat{m} \) depends on the relationship between maximum willingness to pay, initial marginal cost of production and efficiency in transmitting know-how as follows:

    1. (a)

      \(\hat{m} < m^*\) if either \(c<a<2c\) and \(\frac{c^2}{2a}<\alpha <\frac{c}{2} \) or \(2c<a\) and \(\frac{c}{4}<\alpha <\frac{c}{2}\).

    2. (b)

      \(\hat{m} < m^{**}\) if \(2c<a\) and \(\frac{c(\sqrt{4ac+c^2}-c)}{4a}<\alpha < \frac{c}{4}\).

    3. (c)

      \(\hat{m} \) is smaller than \(\overline{m}\) for all \(c<a\) and all \(\frac{ c^2}{2a}<\alpha <\frac{c}{2}\).

Then four different situations are identified depending on the size of both a and \(\alpha \):

  1. (Case A)

    Small maximum willingness to pay case: \(c<a<2c\), and \(\frac{c}{4}< \frac{c}{4a}(\sqrt{4ac+c^2}-c)<\frac{c^2}{2a}<\alpha <\frac{c}{2}\), implying the following threshold ordering: \(0< \hat{m} < m^*<m^{**}<m'<\frac{1}{2}\).

  2. (Case B)

    Large maximum willingness to pay case: \(2c<a\).

  3. (Case B.1)

    \(\frac{ c^2}{2a}< \frac{c}{4a}(\sqrt{4ac+c^2}-c)<\frac{c}{4}<\alpha <\frac{c}{2}\), which implies the following threshold ordering: \(0< \hat{m} < m^*<m^{**}<m'<\frac{1}{2}\).

  4. (Case B.2)

    \(\frac{c^2}{2a}< \frac{c}{4a}(\sqrt{4ac+c^2}-c)<\alpha <\frac{c}{4} <\frac{c}{2}\), which implies the following threshold ordering: \(0< m^*<\hat{m} <m^{**}<m'<\frac{1}{2}\).

  5. (Case B.3)

    \(\frac{c^2}{2a}< \alpha <\frac{c}{4a}(\sqrt{4ac+c^2}-c)<\frac{c}{4} <\frac{c}{2}\), which implies the following threshold ordering: \(0< m^*< m^{**}<\hat{m} <m'<\frac{1}{2}\).

Proof of Proposition 1

Comparing \(\Pi _{p}^{L}(m)\) with \(\Pi _{n}^{L}(m)\) we find that:

  1. (a)

    \(a(1-m)m-cm + \frac{m^2 c^2}{2 \alpha }\) is greater than \(\Pi _{n}^{L}(m)=a(1-m)m-cm\) for \(0<m<m^*\), just by inspection.

  2. (b)

    Consider now, \(m^*<m<m^{**}\), \(\frac{8 \alpha ^2 a^2 m (a(1-m)-c)-c^2(\alpha (a-c)^2+2am^2(2 \alpha a-c^2))}{2(2\alpha a-c^2)^2}\) is greater than \(\Pi _{n}^{L}(m)=a(1-m)m-cm\) iff \(m \in \big [ \frac{(a-c) \alpha }{2(3 a \alpha - c^2) }, \frac{a-c}{2a}\big ]\). But notice that \(\frac{(a-c) \alpha }{2(3 a \alpha - c^2) }<m^*<m^{**}<\frac{a-c}{2a}\) so that the result holds for the relevant interval in m,

  3. (c)

    Next, for \(m^{**}<m<m'\), \(\frac{\alpha (2 \alpha a+ c^2) (a-c)^2}{2(4 \alpha ^2 a^2+ 2\alpha a c^2-c^4)}\) is greater than \(\Pi _{n}^{L}(m)=a(1-m)m-cm\) for all \(m \in [0, m']\). Just notice that \(\Pi _{n}^{L}(m)\) is increasing in m and when evaluated at \(m'\) the expression obtained is always smaller than \(\frac{ \alpha (2 \alpha a+ c^2) (a-c)^2}{2(4 \alpha ^2 a^2+ 2\alpha a c^2-c^4)}\).

  4. (d)

    Finally for \(m'<m\), \(\frac{\alpha (2 \alpha a+ c^2) (a-c)^2}{2(4 \alpha ^2 a^2+ 2\alpha a c^2-c^4)}\) is greater than \(\Pi _{n}^{L}(m)=\frac{(a-c)^2}{4a}\), since the same argument as in (c) works.

Therefore \(\Pi _{p}^{L}(m) > \Pi _{n}^{L}(m)\) for all \(m>0\) and \( \alpha \in \big [\frac{c^2}{2a},\frac{c}{2}\big ]\). \(\square \)

Proof of Proposition 2

Proposition 2 gives the conditions for partial equilibrium to arise at equilibrium.

  1. (a)

    Consider both case (A) and (B.1) as defined above, which results in the following ordering: \(0< \hat{m} < m^*<m^{**}< m'<\frac{1}{2}\); and also implies that \( m^* <\frac{\alpha }{c}\), thus partial know-how transfer never collapses to the full know-how transfer case.

  2. (a.i)

    First, notice that for \(0< m<\hat{m}\) the relevant comparison between the profits corresponding to partial know-how transfer and those corresponding to full is whether \((a(1-m)-c)m + \frac{m^2 c^2}{2 \alpha }\) is greater than \(am(1-m)-\frac{\alpha }{2}\). This is always true since the difference is decreasing in m for \( m<\frac{\alpha }{c}\) and positive for \(m=\hat{m}\).

  3. (a.ii)

    Next for \(\hat{ m}< m< m^*\) the relevant comparison is whether \((a(1-m)-c)m + \frac{m^2 c^2}{ 2 \alpha }\) is greater than \(\frac{a}{4}(1-(\frac{2\alpha }{c})^{2}) -\frac{ \alpha }{2}\) and this occurs when \(m^2(\frac{c^2}{2 \alpha }-a)+(a-c)m+\frac{\alpha }{2}-\frac{a}{4}+\frac{a\alpha ^2}{c^2}>0\). This happens for \(m \in [m^-,m^+]\). But \(m^+=\frac{2 c^2 (a-c) \alpha +\sqrt{2} \sqrt{ a c^2 \alpha \left( 8 a \alpha ^3-4 c^3 \alpha +c^4 \right) }}{2 c^2 \left( 2 a \alpha -c^2\right) }>m'\), therefore we need \(m>m^-=\frac{2 c^2 (a-c) \alpha -\sqrt{2} \sqrt{ a c^2 \alpha \left( 8 a \alpha ^3-4 c^3 \alpha +c^4 \right) }}{2 c^2 \left( 2 a \alpha -c^2\right) }.\) Since \(m^-\) is smaller than \(\hat{ m}\) for all \(\alpha >\frac{c^2}{2a},\) then the claim is always true.

  4. (a.iii)

    Next for \(m^*< m< m^{**}\) the relevant comparison is whether the profits corresponding to partial know-how transfer, \(\frac{8 \alpha ^2 a^2 m (a(1-m)-c)-c^2(\alpha (a-c)^2+2am^2(2 \alpha a-c^2))}{2(2\alpha a-c^2)^2},\) are smaller than those for full transfer, \(\frac{a}{4}(1-(\frac{2\alpha }{c})^{2}) -\frac{\alpha }{2}\). The former are more conveniently written as: \(\frac{a[8 \alpha ^2 a^2 m m'-2 a \alpha c^2 m'^2-(4 a^2 \alpha ^2+2 a \alpha c^2-c^4)m^2)}{(2\alpha a-c^2)^2},\) which is increasing in m for all \(m<m^{**}\). The latter can also be written as \(a(\hat{m}+\frac{2\alpha }{c})\hat{m}-\frac{\alpha }{2},\) which are increasing in \(\hat{m}.\) The difference between the latter and the former is a convex quadratic function in m which is negative iff m is between the following roots and positive otherwise. The roots are \(m_{iii}^{+,-}= m^{**} \pm \frac{(2 a \alpha -c^2)(4a \alpha ^2+2c^2 \alpha -c^3)}{2c(4 a^2 \alpha ^2+2 a \alpha c^2-c^4)}\), or more precisely, \(m_{iii}^{-}= \hat{m}\) and \(m_{iii}^{+}= 2m^{**}-\hat{m}\). Then, the larger is always greater than \(m^{**}\) and the smaller root is smaller than \(m^{*}\), that is \(\hat{m}<m^{*}\) if \( \frac{\frac{a}{c}(2 a \alpha -c^2) (4 a \alpha -c^2)(4a \alpha ^2+2c^2 \alpha -c^3)-(2a \alpha (a-c)(2 a \alpha -c^2)^2 ) }{2a(4 a \alpha -c^2)(4 a^2 \alpha ^2+2 a \alpha c^2-c^4)} >0\) or equivalently iff \((4 a \alpha -c^2)(4a \alpha ^2+2c^2 \alpha -c^3)>2c \alpha (a-c)(2 a \alpha -c^2)\), which is true for \( \alpha \ge \frac{c}{4} \). Note that under the conditions of (Case A), \(c<a<2c\), and \(\frac{c}{4}< \frac{c}{4a}(\sqrt{4ac+c^2}-c)<\frac{c^2}{2a}<\alpha <\frac{c}{2}\), the \( \alpha \ge \frac{c}{4} \) is satisfied for all the range of \(\alpha \), while for (Case B.1) the condition \( \frac{c}{4}\le \alpha < \frac{c}{2}\) is required for partial know-how transfer to be preferred rather than full transfer.

  5. (a.iv)

    Finally, for \(m^{**}\!<\!m\!<\!m'\), the relevant comparison is whether \( \frac{\alpha (2 \alpha a+ c^2) (a-c)^2}{2(4 \alpha ^2 a^2+ 2\alpha a c^2-c^4)} \) is greater than \(\frac{a}{4}(1-(\frac{2\alpha }{c})^{2}) -\frac{\alpha }{2}\). It happens that the claim is always true. Therefore, we conclude that partial transfer of know-how always yields greater licensor’s profits than full transfer under the conditions stated in parts (i) and (ii.a) in the proposition.

  6. (b)

    Consider now, (Case B.2) which implies the following threshold ranking: \(0< m^*<\hat{m} <m^{**}<m'<\frac{1}{2}\); and also implies that \( \frac{\alpha }{c}<m^* \), thus partial know-how transfer collapses to the full know-how transfer case for \( \frac{\alpha }{c}<m<\hat{m} \).

  7. (b.i)

    Take, first \(0< m<\frac{\alpha }{c}<m^*<\hat{m}\). The relevant comparison is that in (a.i) and then partial transfer is preferred.

  8. (b.ii)

    Consider now \(\frac{\alpha }{c}<m<\hat{m}\), as just noted both partial and full know-how transfer are equivalent with \( k=1 \) in both cases, then full transfer of know-how is implemented.

  9. (b.iii)

    Take \(\hat{m}<m<m^{**}\). The relevant difference in profits between full and partial know-how transfer is the one in (a.iii). Since now \( \alpha \in [ \frac{c}{4a}(\sqrt{4ac+c^2}-c),\frac{c}{4}]\), we already know that \(m^*<\hat{m}<m^{**}\), therefore partial know-how is implemented if \(\hat{m}<m<m^{**}\), which is the case.

  10. (b.iv)

    Take \(m^{**}<m<m'\). The relevant comparison is that in (a.iv) and then partial transfer is preferred. Therefore, we conclude that partial transfer of know-how yields greater licensor’s profits than full transfer for either \(0< m<\frac{\alpha }{c}\) or \(\hat{m}<m\) under the conditions stated in part (ii.b) in the proposition.

  11. (c)

    Consider (Case B.3) which implies the following threshold ranking: \(0< m^*< m^{**}<\hat{m}<m'<\frac{1}{2}\), and since \( m^{**}<\hat{m}\), partial know-how transfer collapses to the full know-how transfer case for \( \frac{\alpha }{c}<m \).

  12. (c.i)

    Take, first \(0< m<\frac{\alpha }{c}\). The relevant comparison is that in (a.i) and then partial transfer is preferred.

  13. (c.ii)

    For \(\frac{\alpha }{c} <m\) both partial and full know-how transfer are equivalent with \(k=1\) in all cases.

Therefore, we conclude that partial transfer of know-how yields greater licensor’s profits than full transfer when \(0< m<\frac{\alpha }{c}\) under the conditions stated in part (ii.c) in the proposition. \(\square \)

Proof of Result 2

We first compute the effective marginal cost for any possible situation, If there is full transfer \(\hat{c}=\hat{r}=\frac{2 \alpha a}{c}\). And \(\hat{c}>c\) if \(\alpha >\frac{c^2}{2a}\) which is the case.

In case of partial know-how transfer we have three possible cases depending on the value of m.

  • If \(0<m<m^*<m'\) then \(\hat{c}=c+a(1-2m)\), once we have substituted for the precise expressions for \(r^*\) and \(k^*\). It is, then, easy to find that \(\hat{c}>c\) iff \(m<\frac{1}{2}\), which is true since \(m^*<\frac{1}{2}\).

  • If \(m^*<m<m^{**}<m'\) then \(\hat{c}=a(1-2m)\). Which is larger than c iff \(m<m'\).

  • If \(m^{**}<m\) then \(\hat{c}=r^{**}(1-\frac{c^2}{2\alpha a})+c\). And therefore \(\hat{c}>c\) iff \(\alpha >\frac{c^2}{2a}\) which is the case. \(\square \)

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Mendi, P., Moner-Colonques, R. & Sempere-Monerris, J.J. Optimal know-how transfers in licensing contracts. J Econ 118, 121–139 (2016). https://doi.org/10.1007/s00712-015-0468-y

Download citation

  • Received:

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s00712-015-0468-y

Keywords

JEL Classification

Navigation