Skip to main content
Log in

The beat of the economic heart

Joseph Schumpeter and Arthur Spiethoff on business cycles

  • Regular Article
  • Published:
Journal of Evolutionary Economics Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

The paper discusses the silimar, but in some respects different explanations of business cycles by Schumpeter and Arthur Spiethoff, his elderly friend and colleague. Spiethoff brought Schumpeter back into academics after the latter’s not very successful careers as a politician and a banker. Both insisted that cycles are endogenous and cannot possibly be eliminated without eliminating the dynamismof the capitalist economy. They thought that theoretical and historical studies were not mutually exclusive, but complementary. The gulf separating pure theory and historical studies since the so-called Methodenstreit was detrimental to the development of economics.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. Schumpeter’s life has been meticulously researched. See, in particular, Swedberg (1991) and McCraw (2007); for a short account, see Kurz (2005).

  2. On Spiethoff’s life and work, see Clausing (1958) and Kamp (1969).

  3. Salin (1951: 159 and 157) evaluates Spiethoff’s work as a “full and living amalgamation of rational and historical theory”. Spiethoff is said to have been keen to bridge the gap between the “observational” (anschaulich) and the “rational” point of view (ibid.: 188–9). (Unless otherwise stated, translations from German texts are mine.)

  4. In his Business Cycles, Schumpeter (1939: 220 n.) called Spiethoff’s essay one of “the peak achievements” in the literature on histories of “crises”. The essay was translated into Japanese in 1936 and into English in 1953 (Spiethoff 1953).

  5. In the preface to the English version of his essay on “Krisen”, Spiethoff stresses that “Unfortunately there is no generally accepted name for this method. Some call it ‘empirical-realistic’, others ‘concrete’, yet others ‘observational’ (anschaulich)” (Spiethoff 1953: 75).

  6. He defined such styles in terms of five characteristics: economic spirit, natural and technical basis, economic constitution, social constitution and dynamism; see Schefold (1994).

  7. Interestingly, Spiethoff was the only editor of a German economic journal whom the Nazis in 1933 permitted to stay in office. There is evidence that Spiethoff was also responsible for severe changes in an article by Keynes on “National Self-Sufficiency” that appeared in German in Schmollers Jahrbuch in 1933, changes obviously designed to please the Nazis. In a letter to Spiethoff Keynes protested against what he called “pure concessions to barbarism”, but in the end grudgingly accepted the publication of the distorted text. In regard to this event Borchardt speaks aptly of “cooperative self-censorship”. For details, see Borchardt (1988) and Hagemann (2008: 78–9); see also McCraw (2007: 288). Christian Scheer has drawn my attention to two interesting works: Höpfner (1999: 253–4) argues that Spiethoff cooperated with the Nazis in the hope and expectation that they would foster the revival of historicism. Blesgen (2001) provides additional evidence regarding the German “translation” of Keynes’s paper. He shows that Spiethoff, instigated by his brother, a professor of dermatology and member of the NSDAP, sent the correspondence with Keynes to the director of the Foreign Office of the Nazi party and proposed to reply harshly to Keynes’s accusations in Der Völkische Beobachter, the Nazi propaganda paper.

  8. As early as February 1926 Schumpeter wrote to Gustav Stolper that the monitoring of business cycles published since January of the same year in Der Wirtschaftsdienst based on Spiethoff’s theory involved a big step forward (see Schumpeter 2000: 107; similarly: 123–4).

  9. Schumpeter (1939: 224–5) basically agrees: “it is not only true but obvious that before and even during the eighteenth century crops, wars, plagues, and so on were absolutely and relatively very much more important. The impact of innovation will evidently be felt differently in a small capitalist milieu which is surrounded by a noncapitalist world of much greater quantitative importance, little affected by what happens in the former and acting as a cushion.” See also Schumpeter (1939: 254).

  10. For a discussion of Spiethoff’s ideal type of a cycle, see Schweitzer (1941: 3–14), Borchardt (1982) and Rieter (1994: 158–60).

  11. The idea of a co-evolution of both economic style (or “mode of production”) and cycle is foreshadowed in Marx.

  12. This idea is foreshadowed in a letter to Spiethoff dated 8 January 1931, composed shortly after the foundation of the Econometric Society in Cleveland (see Schumpeter 2000: 183–4). He also stresses that to him “trend analysis” was becoming “more and more a quantitative theory of evolution” (ibid.: 184; emphasis added). (The idea of an “evolutionary schema” recurs in a letter written on 22 April:1949; see ibid.: 374.) See in this context also his letter to Wesley Clair Mitchell of 6 May 1937, in which Schumpeter informs him that “the longest cycle of my schema I call the Kondratieff.” For the U.S., the U.K. and Germany he dates the Kondratieff’s as follows: “1782–1842, 1843–1897, 1898–?.” This is said to agree “roughly, though not entirely,” with the periodisation suggested by others, including Kondratieff and Spiethoff (Schumpeter 2000: 301–302; for differences between them, see Schumpeter 1939: 164–5, 471n. and 475n.). On Spiethoff’s periodisation, see Haberler (1939: 272–4).

  13. Employment and income are not counted among the relevant characteristic facts. They are considered derived facts.

  14. To Spiethoff the circular flow or general equilibrium was a purely fictitious state; the actual system was never in such a state.

  15. The first edition of the Theorie does not yet contain the disagreement, although Spiethoff’s papers to which Schumpeter refers were published two years earlier.

  16. The question of which indicator should be used in order to forecast the economic development was one of the points in dispute between Spiethoff and several of his colleagues, including Ernst Wagemann, founder of the Berlin Institut für Konjunkturforschung (Institute of Business Cycle Research) in 1925; see Kulla (1996: 115–121).

  17. Spiethoff was anticipated in this regard by Tugan-Baranovsky, who had investigated iron production in England over the cycle and had identified it as the leading sector (see also Spiethoff 1903, Hagemann and Landesmann 1998: 98–104 and Beckmann 2005). In his critical discussion of Marx’s analysis, Tugan had assumed with Marx a system composed of three departments, with department I producing means of production, department II wage goods and department III luxuries, on which capitalists live. Means of production, represented by iron, enter directly each department, wage goods enter each department via the employment of workers, whereas luxuries are pure consumption goods and are nowhere needed as inputs.

  18. The mechanism Spiethoff sees at work is similar to the one contemplated by Richard Goodwin in his famous Marx inspired predator-prey model.

  19. As several financial crises in more recent times, including the current one, show, Spiethoff was unduly optimistic in this regard. Speeding up the flow of information may also increase the vulnerability of the financial system.

  20. Spiethoff’s idea of disproportionalities derives from Marx and Tugan-Baranovsky; he actually illustrates it with the help of Marx’s schemes of reproduction.

  21. Some of Spiethoff’s reasoning may be said to foreshadow somewhat Irving Fisher’s concept of debt deflation.

  22. The question of whether or not the business cycle is obsolete has cropped up repeatedly in the history of economics; see, for example, Bronfenbrenner (1969) and the recent talk about the “Great Moderation”.

References

  • Beckmann U (2005) Der Einfluß von Michail Tugan-Baranowsky auf die deutsche Konjunkturforschung im ersten Drittel des 20. Jahrhunderts. In: Rieter H, Širokorad LD, Zweynert J (eds) Deutsche und russische Ökonomen im Dialog. Wissenstransfer in historischer Perspektive. Marburg, Metropolis

    Google Scholar 

  • Blesgen DJ (2001) Konzessionen an den Barbarismus – John M. Keynes, Arthur Spiethoff und die Kanzlei Rosenberg. Schmollers Jahrbuch 121:603–624

    Google Scholar 

  • Borchardt K (1961) Albert Schäffle als Wirtschaftstheoretiker. Zeitschrift für die gesamte Staatswissenschaft 117:610–34

    Google Scholar 

  • Borchardt K (1982) Changes in the phenomenon of the business cycle over the last hundred years. In: Borchardt K (ed) Perspectives on modern German economic history and policy. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge, pp 59–83 and pp 224–229

    Google Scholar 

  • Borchardt K (1988) Keynes’ “Nationale Selbstgenügsamkeit” von 1933. Ein Fall von kooperativer Selbstzensur. Zeitschrift für Wirtschafts- und Sozialwissenschaften 108:271–284

    Google Scholar 

  • Bronfenbrenner M (ed) (1969) Is the business cycle obsolete? Based on a conference of the social science research council committee on economic stability. Wiley-Interscience, New York

    Google Scholar 

  • Clausing G (1958) Arthur Spiethoff’s wissenschaftliches Lebenswerk. Schmollers Jahrbuch für Gesetzgebung. Verwaltung und Volkswirtschaft 78:257–90

    Google Scholar 

  • Haberler G (1939) Prosperity and depression. A theoretical analysis of cyclical movements, 1st edn. 1937, new revised and enlarged edn. 1939. George Allen & Unwin Ltd., London

    Google Scholar 

  • Hagemann H (2008) Zur frühen Rezeption der General Theory durch deutschsprachige Wirtschaftswissenschaftler. In: Hagemann H, Horn G, Krupp H-J (eds) Aus gesamtwirtschaftlicher Sicht. Festschrift für Jürgen Kromphardt. Marburg, Metropolis, pp 71–104

    Google Scholar 

  • Hagemann H, Landesmann M (1998) Lowe and structural theories of the business cycle. In: Hagemann H, Kurz HD (eds) Political economics in retrospect. Essays in memory of Adolph Lowe. Edward Elgar, Cheltenham, pp 95–130

    Google Scholar 

  • Höpfner H-P (1999) Die Universität Bonn im Dritten Reich. Akademische Biographien unter nationalsozialistischer Herrschaft. Bouvier, Bonn

    Google Scholar 

  • Kamp ME (1969) Arthur Spiethoff. In: Bonner Gelehrte. Beiträge zur Geschichte der Wissenschaften in Bonn. Staatswissenschaften. H. Bouvier und Co. Verlag – Ludwig Röhrscheid Verlag, Bonn

  • Kulla B (1996) Die Anfänge der empirischen Konjunkturforschung in Deutschland 1925–1933. Duncker and Humblot, Berlin

    Google Scholar 

  • Kurz HD (2005) Joseph A. Schumpeter. Ein Sozialökonom zwischen Marx und Walras, 2nd edn. 2009. Marburg, Metropolis

    Google Scholar 

  • Kurz HD (2008) Innovations and profits. Schumpeter and the classical heritage. J Econ Behav Organ 67:263–78

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lucas RE (2004) My Keynesian education. In: de Vroey M, Hoover K (eds) The IS-LM model: its rise, fall and strange persistence, annual supplement of History of Political Economy, vol 36. Duke University Press, Durham

    Google Scholar 

  • Marx K (1959) Capital, vol 3. International Publishers, New York

    Google Scholar 

  • Marx K (1972) Theories of surplus value, part 3. Lawrence and Wishart, London

    Google Scholar 

  • McCraw TK (2007) Prophet of innovation: Joseph Schumpeter and creative destruction. The Belknap Press of Harvard University Press, Cambridge

    Google Scholar 

  • Rieter H (1994) Historische Schulen. In: Issing O (ed) Geschichte der Nationalökonomie, 3rd edn. Franz Vahlen, Munich, pp 127–162. (4th edn Munich: Franz Vahlen 2002, pp 131–168)

    Google Scholar 

  • Rieter H (1998) Der deutsche Volkswirt 1926 bis 1933. Eine Fallstudie zur publizistischen Umsetzung wirtschaftspolitischer Konzeptionen. In: Streissler EW (ed) Die Umsetzung wirtschaftspolitischer Grundkonzeptionen in die kontinentaleuropäische Praxis des 19. und 20. Jahrhunderts, II. Teil, in Studien zur Entwicklung der ökonomischen Theorie, vol 17. Duncker & Humblot, Berlin, pp 95–154

    Google Scholar 

  • Salin E (1951) Geschichte der Volkswirtschaftslehre, 4th edn. A. Francke AG – Verlag, Bern and J.C.B. Mohr, Tübingen

  • Schefold B (1994) Wirtschaftsstile, vol 1: Studien zum Verhältnis von Ökonomie und Kultur. Fischer Taschenbuch Verlag, Frankfurt am Main

    Google Scholar 

  • Schumpeter JA (1908) Das Wesen und der Hauptinhalt der theoretischen National-ökonomie. Duncker & Humblot, Leipzig

    Google Scholar 

  • Schumpeter JA (1910) Über das Wesen der Wirtschaftskrisen. Zeitschrift für Volkswirtschaft, Sozialpolitik und Verwaltung 19:271–325. Reprint in Schumpeter (1987), pp 227–274

    Google Scholar 

  • Schumpeter JA (1911) Theorie der wirtschaftlichen Entwicklung (the impressum gives wrongly 1912 as the year of publication). Duncker & Humblot, Munich and Leipzig

    Google Scholar 

  • Schumpeter JA (1914) Die Wellenbewegung des Wirtschaftslebens. Archiv für Sozialwissenschaften und Sozialpolitik 39:1–32

    Google Scholar 

  • Schumpeter JA (1926a) Theorie der wirtschaftlichen Entwicklung, 2nd edn. Duncker & Humblot, Munich and Leipzig

    Google Scholar 

  • Schumpeter JA (1926b) Gustav v. Schmoller und die Probleme von heute. Jahrbuch für Gesetzgebung, Verwaltung und Volkswirtschaft im Deutschen Reich 50:337–388. Reprinted in J. A. Schumpeter, Dogmenhistorische und biographische Aufsätze (1954), edited by E. Schneider and A. Spiethoff. J.C.B. Mohr, Tübingen

    Google Scholar 

  • Schumpeter JA (1934) The theory of economic development. An inquiry into profits, capital, credit, interest, and the business cycle, English translation of Schumpeter (1926). Harvard University Press, Cambridge

    Google Scholar 

  • Schumpeter JA (1939) Business cycles. A theoretical, historical, and statistical analysis of the capitalist process, vol 2. McGraw-Hill, New York

    Google Scholar 

  • Schumpeter JA (1942) Capitalism, socialism and democracy, edn. of 1975. Harper, New York

    Google Scholar 

  • Schumpeter JA (1954) History of economic analysis. Allen & Unwin, London

    Google Scholar 

  • Schumpeter JA (1985) Aufsätze zur Wirtschaftspolitik. In: Seidl Ch, Stolper WF (eds) J.C.B. Mohr, Tübingen

  • Schumpeter JA (1993) Joseph Alois Schumpeter. Aufsätze zur Tagespolitik. In: Seidl Ch, Stolper WF (eds) J.C.B. Mohr, Tübingen

  • Schumpeter JA (2000) Briefe/Letters. In: Hedtke U, Swedberg R (eds) J.C.B. Mohr, Tübingen

  • Schweitzer A (1941) Spiethoff’s theory of the business cycle. University of Wyoming Publications (Continuation of University of Wyoming Publications in Science) 8(1):1–30

    Google Scholar 

  • Smith A (1976) An inquiry into the nature and causes of the wealth of nations. In: Campbell RH, Skinner AS, Todd WB (eds) The Glasgow edition of the works and correspondence of Adam Smith, vol 2, 1st edn. In the text quoted as WN, book number, chapter number, section number, paragraph number. Oxford University Press, Oxford

    Google Scholar 

  • Spiethoff A (1902) Vorbemerkungen zu einer Theorie der Überproduktion, Schmollers Jahrbuch für Gesetzgebung, Verwaltung und Volkswirtschaft im Deutschen Reiche 26:721–59

  • Spiethoff A (1903) Die Krisentheorien von M. v. Tugan-Baranowski und L. Pohle. Schmollers Jahrbuch für Gesetzgebung, Verwaltung und Volkswirtschaft im Deutschen Reiche 27:679–708

  • Spiethoff A (1914) Untersuchungen über Preisbildung, Abteilung D, Der Einfluss der Golderzeugung auf die Preisbildung 1890–1913. Part 1. Die allgemeine Preisbewegung 1890–1913. Duncker & Humblot, Munich and Leipzig

    Google Scholar 

  • Spiethoff A (1925) Krisen. Handwörterbuch der Sozialwissenschaften 6:8–91. English translation, see Spiethoff (1953)

    Google Scholar 

  • Spiethoff A (1934) Boden und Wohnung in der Martkwirtschaft, insbes. im Rheinland. Fischer, Jena

    Google Scholar 

  • Spiethoff A (1953) Business cycles, with a preface by the author. In: International economic papers, vol 3. London and New York, pp 75–171

  • Spiethoff A (1955) Die wirtschaftlichen Wechsellagen. Aufschwung, Krise, Stockung, with a preface by Edgar Salin, vol 2. Polygraph, Tübingen and Zürich

    Google Scholar 

  • Swedberg R (1991) Joseph A. Schumpeter. His life and work. Polity Press, Cambridge

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgments

I am grateful to Ingo Barens, Daniele Besomi, Stephan Böhm, Knut Borchardt, Kurt Dopfer, Christian Gehrke, Harald Hagemann, Geoff Harcourt, Ulrich Hedtke, Hauke Janssen, Heinz Rieter, Christian Scheer, Bertram Schefold and Christian Seidl for useful comments on an earlier draft of this paper. Any remaining errors and omissions are, of course, entirely my responsibility.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Heinz D. Kurz.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Cite this article

Kurz, H.D. The beat of the economic heart. J Evol Econ 25, 147–162 (2015). https://doi.org/10.1007/s00191-013-0329-1

Download citation

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s00191-013-0329-1

Keywords

JEL Classifications

Navigation