Skip to main content
Log in

Internalization of externalities and local government consolidation: empirical evidence from Japan

  • Published:
Empirical Economics Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

The fact that jurisdictional consolidation overcomes externality problems in the provision of local public goods is one of the best-known benefits of consolidation in the theoretical literature. Nevertheless, previous studies provide little evidence of how public service spillover effects influence consolidation decisions. This study empirically tests the hypothesis that spillovers induce consolidation, using voting data on the consolidation of Japanese municipalities. The extent of spillovers is measured by estimating the demand function for public goods with externalities. It is found that residents of the municipalities that can internalize a large amount of public goods spillovers through municipal consolidation tend to favor consolidation. This result supports the theoretical inference that spillovers in local public goods affect utility gains from jurisdiction integration, thus serving as one of the key impetuses for boundary reform. Moreover, after controlling for the spillover effects, economies of scale, population share, differences in median income, and unconditional grants can help explain consolidation preference.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1

Source: MIC (2010)

Fig. 2
Fig. 3

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. Bradford and Oates (1974) provide a well-structured survey.

  2. See, for example, Anselin (1988) or Lesage and Pace (2009). On the application of the spatial econometric method, see Brueckner (2003).

  3. Total public spending in Japan was 24% of its gross domestic product (GDP) in 2010, while municipal spending was 7% of GDP.

  4. Akizuki (2001) described the relationship between the central and local governments as “controlled decentralization.”

  5. See, for example, Council of Local Authorities for International Relations (CLAIR 2009), MIC (2006, p. 41), and Yokomichi (2007).

  6. One of the objectives of the “Great Heisei Merger” was to deal with residents’ demands for the provision of public services beyond traditional boundaries.

  7. They included a grace period for local governments to avoid unconditional grant reduction resulting from a merger and a subsidy for the principal and interest of local bonds issued by municipalities to finance additional costs stemming from a consolidation.

  8. As this approach indirectly measures publicness and the obtained results are problematic in terms of jurisdiction size, alternative approaches have been developed to rigorously estimate price elasticity and congestion (Reiter and Weichenrieder 1997). Nevertheless, subsequent studies mostly agree with the results presented by Bergstrom and Goodman (1973) and Borcherding and Deacon (1972) and show that the approach remains adequate for estimating the demand for local public services.

  9. By minimizing a cost function subject to the Cobb–Douglas production function \({G_i} = aL_i^\beta K_i^{1 - \beta }\) , where denotes labor and denotes capital, and briefly rearranging, Eq. (5) is obtained. The Cobb–Douglas assumption is standard in this literature. See, for example, Bergstrom and Goodman (1973), Borcherding and Deacon (1972), and Reiter and Weichenrieder (1997).

  10. “Spatial lag,” introduced by Anselin (1988), is a weighted average of random variables (dependent variables, in many cases) at neighboring locations.

  11. Another econometric approach that provides consistent estimates is the instrumental variable method developed by Kelejian and Prucha (1998) and Kelejian and Robinson (1993). See, for example, Brueckner (2003).

  12. Many previous studies of mergers show that economies of scale frequently prevail in public schooling and that efficiency gains are a typical driving force behind local government mergers (e.g., Austin 1999; Gordon and Knight 2009).

  13. See, for example, CLAIR (2009).

  14. Several empirical studies have addressed behavior akin to economies of scale with regard to population, called “economies of size” (e.g., Andrews et al. 2002; Duncombe and Yinger 1993), based on the fact that the larger the population size of a municipality, the more it could reduce its costs for public service production, for example, by efficiently utilizing its own public facilities. Among them, some studies have drawn attention to this type of economies of scale attained through jurisdictional integration (e.g., Brasington 1999, 2003b; Brink 2004; Gordon and Knight 2009). In these studies, economies of scale in population are defined by a decrease in per capita expenditure after consolidation. For our theoretical model, this aspect can be represented as \(\partial {e_i}/\partial {N_i} = \partial \left( {{c_i}{G_i}/Ni} \right) /\partial {N_i} < 0\).

    Our empirical model basically follows the methodology proposed by Gordon and Knight (2009, p. 761), which assumes that average expenditure is simply composed of scale economy and diseconomy factors in terms of population and defines efficiency gains as the difference between pre- and post-consolidation expenditures per capita. Note, however, that our average expenditure specification is slightly different from theirs, to reflect the fact that the log of per capita expenditure is almost U-shaped in the log of population for Japan. However, there is some similarity too, from the viewpoint of allowing the possibility of scale economies and diseconomies. In this setting, including logs of population and squared population as controls in the second step of the regression makes it impossible to identify the coefficient of scale economy effects; for this specification, the coefficient of efficiency gain in the second step cannot be determined uniquely using the estimates of the differences in the logs of population and in the logs of squared population. Accordingly, we approximately estimate the size of efficiency gains due to consolidation by utilizing the fitted values of average expenditure.

  15. Although racial composition is an important feature that may affect preference for local public goods (Brasington 2003b), it is not taken into account here because Japan is composed mostly of people of the same ethnic group.

  16. See Miyazaki (2014) for theoretical background for using these covariates.

  17. “Generated regressor” is defined as an imputed value from an auxiliary statistical model. Wooldridge (2002), for example, referred to estimations using a generated regressor.

  18. There are primarily two approaches to correct the biases. The first is the two-step econometric model, in which unobserved variables are replaced by their estimates or predictions from an auxiliary model and standard errors in the second step are calculated from the correct asymptotic covariance matrix for the two-step procedure. The other is the full information maximum likelihood (FIML) model, in which auxiliary and main models are jointly estimated, yielding efficient estimates and asymptotically non-biased estimates of standard errors. Although efficient, the FIML model suffers disadvantages of complex and costly computation, and more specifically, a specific joint distribution of the disturbances of the auxiliary and main models. Hence, this study utilizes the two-step procedure to estimate the consolidation-decision model with the fitted values of the ATS.

  19. The median ratio of taxable income is used as a proxy for the median tax ratio.

  20. See, for example, Reiter and Weichenrieder (1997).

  21. The government census is collected at 5-year intervals.

  22. Financial support for mergers was subtly reviewed almost annually from 1999 to 2006 in order to encourage municipal mergers.

  23. Measurements and units of the political proximity variables are provided in Panel B of Table 1.

References

  • Akizuki K (2001) Partnership in controlled decentralization: local governments and the Ministry of Home Affairs. In: Muramatsu M, Iqbal F, Kume I (eds) Local government development in post-war Japan. Oxford University Press, New York, pp 63–84

    Google Scholar 

  • Alesina A, Spolaore E (1997) On the size and number of nations. Q J Econ 112:1027–1056

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Alesina A, Spolaore E (2003) The size of nations. MIT Press, Cambridge

    Google Scholar 

  • Alesina A, Baqir R, Hoxby C (2004) Political jurisdictions in heterogeneous communities. J Polit Econ 112:348–396

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Andrews M, Duncombe W, Yinger J (2002) Revising economies of size in American education: Are we any closer to a consensus? Econ Educ Rev 21(3):245–262

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Anselin L (1988) Spatial econometrics: methods and models. Kluwer Academic Publishers, Dordrecht

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Austin DA (1999) Politics vs. economics: evidence from municipal annexation. J Urban Econ 45:501–532

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Banzhaf SH, Walsh RP (2008) Do people vote with their feet? An empirical test of Tiebout’s mechanism. Am Econ Rev 98:843–863

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bergstrom TC, Goodman RP (1973) Private demand for public goods. Am Econ Rev 63:280–296

    Google Scholar 

  • Besley T, Coate S (2003) Centralized vs. decentralized provision of local public goods: a political economy approach. J Public Econ 87:2611–2637

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bolton P, Roland G (1997) The breakup of nations: a political economy analysis. Q J Econ 112:1057–1089

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Borcherding TE, Deacon RT (1972) The demand for the services of non-federal governments. Am Econ Rev 62:891–901

    Google Scholar 

  • Bradford DF, Oates WE (1974) Suburban exploitation of central cities and governmental structure. In: Hochman HM, Peterson GE (eds) Redistributions through public choice. Columbia University Press, New York, pp 44–90

    Google Scholar 

  • Brasington D (1999) Joint provision of public goods: the consolidation of school districts. J Public Econ 73:373–393

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Brasington D (2003a) Size and school district consolidation: Do opposites attract? Economica 70:673–690

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Brasington D (2003b) Snobbery, racism, or mutual distaste: What promotes and hinders cooperation in local public good provision? Rev Econ Stat 85:874–883

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Brink A (2004) The breakup of municipalities: voting behavior in local referenda. Econ Gov 5:119–135

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Brueckner JK (2003) Strategic interaction among governments: an overview of empirical studies. Int Reg Sci Rev 26:175–188

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Case A, Hines J, Rosen H (1993) Budget spillovers and fiscal policy interdependence: evidence from the States. J Public Econ 52:285–307

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • CLAIR (2009) Municipal mergers in Japan. CLAIR Fact Sheet, CLAIR, Tokyo

  • Duncombe W, Yinger J (1993) An analysis of returns to scale in public production, with an application to fire protection. J Public Econ 52:49–72

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dur R, Staal K (2008) Local public good provision, municipal consolidation, and national transfers. Reg Sci Urban Econ 38:160–173

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Edwards JHY (1990) Congestion function specification and the ’publicness’ of local public goods. J Urban Econ 27:80–96

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ellingsen T (1998) Externalities vs. internalities: a model of political integration. J Public Econ 68:251–268

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Foucault M, Madies T, Paty S (2008) Public spending interactions and local politics. Empirical evidence from French municipalities. Public Choice 137:57–80

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gordon N, Knight B (2009) A spatial merger estimator with an application to school district consolidation. J Public Econ 93:752–765

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hinnerich BT (2009) Do merging local governments free ride on their counterparts when facing boundary reform? J Public Econ 93:721–728

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Japan Research Institute for Local Government (2002–2005) Zenkoku Kubicho Meibo (List of mayors over all municipalities in Japan)

  • Kelejian H, Prucha I (1998) A generalized spatial two stage least squares procedure for estimating a spatial autoregressive model with autoregressive disturbances. J Real Estate Financ Econ 17:99–121

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kelejian HH, Robinson DP (1993) A suggested method of estimation for spatial interdependent models with autocorrelated errors, and an application to a county expenditure model. Pap Reg Sci 72:297–312

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Konishi S (2003) Shi-cho-son Gappei to Chiho Zaisei Seido, Shi-cho-son no Zaisei Unei (Municipal amalgamations, local public finance and municipalities’ management of public finance). Jichi Kenkyu 79:22–46

    Google Scholar 

  • Lesage J, Pace R (2009) Introduction to spatial econometrics. CRC Press, Boca Raton

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Lockwood B (2002) Distributive politics and the costs of centralization. Rev Econ Stud 69:313–337

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lorz O, Willmann G (2005) On the endogenous allocation of decision powers in federal structures. J Urban Econ 57:242–257

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • MIC (2002a-2005a) Shichoson Kessan Jokyo Shirabe (Settlement of Municipality Finances)

  • MIC (2002b-2005b) Shichoson Zei Kazei Jokyo Tou no Shirabe (Taxation of Municipal Taxes)

  • MIC (2006) White Paper on Local Public Finance

  • MIC (2010) Heisei no Gappei ni Tsuite (On Heisei Municipality Consolidation), Report

  • MIC (Ministry of Internal Affairs and Communications) (2000) Kokusei Chosa (Population Census of Japan)

  • Miyazaki T (2014) Municipal consolidation and local government behavior: evidence from Japanese voting data on merger referenda. Econ Gov 15:387–410

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Murphy KM, Topel RH (1985) Estimation and inference in two-step econometric models. J Bus Econ Stat 3:370–379

    Google Scholar 

  • Nelson M (1990) Decentralization of the subnational public sector: an empirical analysis of the determinants of local government structure in metropolitan areas in the US. South Econ J 57:443–457

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Oates W (1972) Fiscal federalism. Harcourt Brace Jovanovich, New York

    Google Scholar 

  • Reiter M, Weichenrieder A (1997) Are public goods public? A critical survey of the demand estimates for local public services. FinanzArchiv 54:374–408

    Google Scholar 

  • Reiter M, Weichenrieder A (1999) Public goods, club goods and the measurement of crowding. J Urban Econ 46:69–79

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Revelli F (2003) Reaction or interaction? Spatial process identification in multi-tiered government structures. J Urban Econ 53:29–53

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Revelli F (2005) On spatial public finance empirics. Int Tax Public Financ 12:475–492

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Solé-Ollé A (2006) Expenditure spillovers and fiscal interactions: empirical evidence from local governments in Spain. J Urban Econ 59:32–53

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Sorensen R (2006) Local government consolidations: the impact of political transaction costs. Public Choice 127:75–95

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Todd S, Tschirhart JT (1980) The economic theory of clubs: an evaluation survey. J Econ Lit 18:1481–1519

    Google Scholar 

  • Weese E (2015) Political mergers as coalition formation: an analysis of the Heisei municipal amalgamations. Quant Econ 6:257–307

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Wooldridge JM (2002) Econometric analysis of cross section and panel data. MIT Press, Cambridge

    Google Scholar 

  • Yokomichi K (2007) The development of municipal mergers in Japan—COSLOG up-to-date documents on local autonomy in Japan. No. 1, CLAIR, Tokyo

  • Zax JS (1989) Is there a leviathan in your neighborhood. Am Econ Rev 79:560–567

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgements

I would like to thank Nobuo Akai, Haruaki Hirota, Kazuko Nakata, and the participants at the seminar at Doshisha University, Kyoto (February, 2012), the 68th Congress of the International Institute of Public Finance at Technische Universitat, Dresden (August, 2012), and the 2012 Autumn Japanese Economic Association Meeting at Kyushu Sangyo University, Fukuoka (October, 2012) for their helpful comments. This work was supported by the Japan Society for the Promotion of Science Grant-in-Aid for Young Scientists (B) 22730256.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Takeshi Miyazaki.

Electronic supplementary material

Below is the link to the electronic supplementary material.

Supplementary material 1 (docx 48 KB)

Appendix

Appendix

Referendum data were collected from the homepage of the MIC, specifically from the Digital Archives of Mergers (DAM) (http://www.gappei-archive.soumu.go.jp/, accessed on November 20, 2013). However, because the DAM covers only those referendum cases in which consolidation is realized after the referendum, all the referendum data could not be collected from this source. Information on other referendum cases is obtained from each of the homepages established by the merger consulting committees or municipalities, or from offline documents such as newspaper articles and municipal public documents. More details on the referendum data are presented in Section 2 of Miyazaki (2014). All the municipalities employed in the estimation are listed in Online Resource 1 with the referendum data and the ATS.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Miyazaki, T. Internalization of externalities and local government consolidation: empirical evidence from Japan. Empir Econ 54, 1061–1086 (2018). https://doi.org/10.1007/s00181-017-1242-5

Download citation

  • Received:

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s00181-017-1242-5

Keywords

JEL Classification

Navigation