Skip to main content
Log in

Financial liberalization and the selection of emigrants: a cross-national analysis

  • Published:
Empirical Economics Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

This paper explores the impact of financial liberalization on the migration of high skilled labor from 46 countries to the Organization for Economic Cooperation and Development, taken at 5-year intervals over the period 1985–2000. Using an exploratory factor analysis, we are able to distinguish between two dimensions of financial liberalization, namely the robustness of the markets and their freedom from direct government control. We find that a standard deviation improvement in the robustness of the source country financial sector magnifies the extent of skilled emigration by a factor of about 3.9–5.1 % points on the average. However, a corresponding increase in the freedom of the source country financial sector from government control has a statistically insignificant impact. Further, the impact of improved financial sector robustness on selection is more pronounced for countries with a better quality of institutions in terms of the perceived credibility of the regime in terms of its ability to protect property rights.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. It should be mentioned that evidence on the investment impact of financial liberalization is ambigu- ous and most studies find that it stimulates growth primarily by increasing total factor productivity (Bekaert et al. 2011). At the same time, it bears repetition that the impact of financial integration on economic growth depends critically on the existing quality of institutions (Chinn and Ito 2006; Claessens and Perotti 2007). In fact, there has been a concern that financial liberalization may promote economic growth only in economies that have attained a certain level of institutional and financial development (Kose et al. 2009). However, while the literature is fairly unanimous in emphasizing the role of institutions in determining the ultimate impact of financial liberalization, the existence of threshold effects with respect to the existing level of financial development is by no means a consensus in the field.

  2. Research has also emphasized the importance of the bequest motive in migration. Since financial development makes it easier for the poor to educate their children and reduces labor market discrimination that disproportionately affects poor minority groups (Levine 2008), it reduces the need to migrate for the poor (Docquier and Rapoport 2003).

  3. Focusing on the six major OECD destinations is less restrictive than it may appear to be: The six countries considered accounted for 77 % of the OECD skilled immigration stock in the year 2000 (Beine et al. 2011a, b). This is significant considering that 90 percent of all high skilled international migrants were found to be living in the OECD in that year (Docquier et al. 2007). Further, the United States, Germany, France, Canada, and the United Kingdom were, in descending order, the five largest remittance-sending countries in 2005; together accounting for approximately half of the global remittance flow (Ratha and Shaw 2007). Australia was the ninth largest, being further superseded by Saudi Arabia, Spain, and Hong Kong in descending order. For other studies based on the Defoort (2008) dataset that gives us our dependent variable, see Beine et al. (2011a, b) and Bang and Mitra (2013).

  4. The original dataset accounts for migration from 147 source countries at 5-year intervals over the period 1975–2000 and may be accessed from http://perso.uclouvain.be/frederic.docquier/oxlight.htm. The unavailability of financial and institutional variables restricts our sample to 52, 60, 53, and 59 countries for the years 1985, 1990, 1995, and 2000, respectively. Leaving out countries that emerged as autonomous political entities over the sample period and others with intermittent availability of data on the control variables gives us our present balanced sample comprising 46 countries in each of the four periods. It should, however, be mentioned that all of our results are confirmed with an unbalanced sample of 66 countries that yields 229 observations for the OLS and 220 observations for the 2SLS model.

  5. On one hand, an increase in GDP in the source country reduces international income differentials and hence the incentive to migrate. On the other hand, it increases the ability to incur the costs of migration and hence, increases the incentive to migrate. Together, the two effects induce a non-monotonic response of skilled migration to GDP per capita that typically takes the form of an inverted U-shaped relationship. See Vogler and Rotte (2000) for more on the issue.

  6. See Marshall et al. (2009) for a description of the Polity IV variables and the underlying methodology. The document can be accessed at http://www.systemicpeace.org/inscr/p4manualv2009.pdf. Corresponding information for the ICRG variables can be found at the homepage of the PRS Group: http://www.prsgroup.com/ICRG_Methodology.aspx.

  7. See Beck et al. (2001) for a description of the variables and the underlying methodology.

  8. The risk of expropriation is perhaps the most commonly used measure of property rights used in the literature (Acemoglu et al. 2005; Knack and Keefer 1995; Rodrik et al. 2004).

  9. We could alternatively include credit ceilings rather than the combined credit controls variable, but this leads to a considerable reduction of our sample. Nevertheless, both our exploratory factor analysis and the final regression exercise yield identical results when we replace (20) with credit ceiling \(s\). These results are available on request.

  10. The Basel I Accord of 1988 was a set of recommendations on banking sector regulation published by a committee of central bank governors from the Group of Ten nations, called the Basel Committee on Banking Supervision. It was replaced by the more comprehensive Basel II in 2004 and the recent financial crisis has resulted in further modifications in the form of Basel III, though this remains a work in progress. See http://www.bis.org/publ/bcbsca.htm for the original Basel document and subsequent updates.

  11. Given the inherent problem of heteroskedasticity in cross-country growth regressions (Durlauf et al. 2005), we compute robust standard errors of our estimated coefficients, making the Hansen J-test the appropriate test for over-identification.

  12. Other contributions (Acemoglu et al. 2005; Hall et al. 2010; Rodrik et al. 2004) focus on the subset of institutions that preserve the security of property rights.

  13. Highlighting this problem, Langbein and Knack (2010) undertake a confirmatory factor analysis of the World Governance Indicators (WGI) to determine if these measures are causally related to single latent variable good governance and fail to confirm this hypothesis.

  14. Beck and Levine (2004) consider the impact of stock market development; Bekaert et al. (2005) the impact of equity market liberalization; while Bekaert et al. (2011) and Chinn and Ito (2006) consider both capital and equity market liberalization. See Levine (2005) for a survey of the finance and growth literature.

  15. See Abiad and Mody (2005) for a dissenting view on the role of institutions as determinants of financial liberalization.

  16. For studies using EFA, see Bang and Mitra (2011) and Langbein and Knack (2010) in the context of institutions and Jong-A-Pin (2009) in the context of political instability.

  17. This is why the latent financial factors described subsequently have a different range than the observed financial indices which range between 0 and 3.

  18. As demonstrated subsequently, this may not be an appropriate assumption in our context.

  19. Recall that Credit Controls combines the directed credit variable with the absence of credit ceilings. Since the variation induced by the former is already accounted for by including it separately from the combined variable, the weight of the combined variable is essentially capturing the impact of credit ceilings. Including these variables in tandem does not seriously compromise the stability of our EFA specification, even though they are very highly correlated for some countries. As an example, consider the most extreme case, in which two variables are perfectly correlated. In this case, the solution to the EFA that includes both of these will simply report a duplicate set of factor loadings corresponding to the correlated variables. In our case, the credit controls variable captures the additional impact on financial freedom that derives from the absence of credit ceilings.

  20. A Heywood case occurs if the variance in an observed variable accounted for by the common factors or the communality of that variable equals or exceeds 1.

  21. We are grateful to an anonymous referee for this suggestion.

  22. It should be mentioned, however, that we get closely comparable results even when we exclude these dummies.

  23. This is not surprising since the financial principle factors obtained from the EFA are highly orthogonal.

References

  • Abiad A, Mody A (2005) Financial reform: what shakes it? what shapes it? Am Econ Rev 95(1):63–88

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Abiad A, Detragiache E, Tressel T (2010) A new database of financial reforms. IMF Staff Pap 57(2):281–302

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Acemoglu D, Johnson S, Robinson JA (2005) Institutions as the fundamental cause of long-run growth. In: Aghion P, Durlauf SH (eds) Handbook of economic growth vol 1. Elsevier, Amsterdam, pp 385–472

  • Alesina A, Perotti R (1996) Income distribution, political instability, and investment. Eur Econ Rev 40(5):1203–1228

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ang JB (2010) Finance and inequality: the case of India. South Econ J 76(3):738–761

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ang JB (2011) Financial development, liberalization and technological deepening. Eur Econ Rev 55(5): 688–701

    Google Scholar 

  • Apergis N, Payne JE (2010) Energy consumption and growth in South America: evidence from a panel error correction model. Energy Econ 32(6):1421–1426

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bang JT, Mitra A (2011) Brain drain and institutions of governance: educational attainment of immigrants to the US 1988–1998. Econ Syst 35(3):335–354

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bang JT, Mitra A (2013) Civil war, ethnicity, and the migration of skilled labor. Eastern Econ J 39:387–401

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Barro RJ, Lee JW (2001) International data on educational attainment: updates and implications. Oxford Econ Pap 53(3):541–563

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Beck T, Levine R (2004) Stock markets, banks, and growth: panel evidence. J Bank Financ 28(3):423–442

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Beck T, Demirgüç-Kunt A, Levine R (2007) Finance, inequality, and the poor. J Econ Growth 12(1):27–49

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Beck T, Clarke G, Groff A, Keefer P, Walsh P (2001) New tools in comparative political economy: the database of political institutions. World Bank Econ Rev 15(1):165–176

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Beine M, Docquier F, Ozden C (2011) Diasporas. J Dev Econ 95(1):30–41

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Beine M, Docquier F, Rapoport H (2008) Brain drain and human capital formation in developing countries: winners and losers. Econ J 118(528):631–652

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Beine M, Defoort C, Docquier F, Ozden C (2011) A panel data analysis of the brain gain. World Dev 39(4):523–532

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bekaert G, Harvey CR, Lundblad C (2005) Does financial liberalization spur economic growth? J Fin Econ 77(1):3–55

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bekaert G, Harvey CR, Lundblad C (2011) Financial openness and productivity. World Dev 39(1):1–19

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bessey D (2012) International student migration to Germany. Empir Econ 42(1):345–361

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bertocchi G, Strozzi C (2008) International migration and the role of institutions. Public Choice 137(1): 81–102

    Google Scholar 

  • Borjas G (1994) The economics of immigration. J Econ Lit 32:1667–717

    Google Scholar 

  • Canning D, Pedroni P (2008) Infrastructure, long-run economic growth and causality tests for cointegrated panels. Manch Sch 76(5):504–527

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Chiswick B (2000) Are immigrants favorably self-selected? an economic analysis. In: Brettell CD, Hollifield JF (eds) Migration theory: talking across disciplines. Routledge, New York, pp 61–76

    Google Scholar 

  • Chinn MD, Ito H (2006) What matters for financial development? capital controls, institutions, and interactions. J Dev Econ 81(1):163–192

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Claessens S, Perotti E (2007) Finance and inequality: channels and evidence. J Comp Econ 35(4):748–773

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Clarke GRG, Xu LC, Zou HF (2006) Finance and income inequality: what do the data tell us? South Econ J 72(3):578–596

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Costello AB, Osborne JW (2005) Best practices in exploratory factor analysis: four recommendations for getting the most from your analysis. Prac Assess Res Eval 10(7):1–9

    Google Scholar 

  • Defoort C (2008) Long-term trends in international migration: an analysis of the six main receiving countries. Popul E 63(2):285–318

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Docquier F, Lodigiani E (2010) Skilled migration and business networks. Open Econ Rev 21(4):565–588

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Docquier F, Rapoport H (2003) Ethnic discrimination and the migration of skilled labor. J Dev Econ 70:159–72

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Docquier F, Rapoport H (2008) Skilled migration: the perspective of developing countries. In: Bhagwati J, Hansen G (eds) Skilled migration: prospects, problems and policies. Russell Sage Foundation, New York

    Google Scholar 

  • Docquier F, Rapoport H (2011) Globalization, brain drain and development. J Econ Lit 50(3):681–730

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Docquier F, Lohest O, Marfouk A (2007) Brain drain in developing countries. World Bank Econ Rev 21(2):193–218

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Durlauf SN, Johnson PA, Temple JRW (2005) Growth econometrics. In: Aghion P, Durlauf SH (eds) Handbook of economic growth vol 1. Elsevier, Amsterdam, pp 555–677

    Chapter  Google Scholar 

  • Eichengreen B (2001) Capital account liberalization: what do the cross-country studies tell us? World Bank Econ Rev 15(3):341–365

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Eichengreen B, Leblang D (2003) Capital account liberalization and growth: was Mr. Mahathir right? Int J Financ Econ 8:205–224

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Glaeser E, La Porta R, Lopez-de-Silanes F, Shleifer A (2004) Do institutions cause growth? J Econ Growth 9:271–303

    Google Scholar 

  • Hair JF Jr, Anderson RE, Tatham RL, Black WC (1998) Multivariate data analysis, 5th edn. Prentice Hall, Upper Saddle River

    Google Scholar 

  • Hall JC, Sobel RS, Crowley GR (2010) Institutions, capital, and growth. South Econ J 77:385–405

    Google Scholar 

  • Hatton TJ, Williamson JG, (2002) What fundamentals drive world migration? NBER working paper no w9159, NBER

  • Jayachandran S, Lleras-Muney A (2009) Life expectancy and human capital investments: evidence from maternal mortality declines. Q J Econ 124(1):349–398

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Jong-A-Pin R (2009) On the measurement of political instability and its impact on economic growth. Eur J Pol Econ 25:15–29

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Keeling D (2007) Costs, risks, and migration networks between Europe and the United States, 1900–1914. Res Maritime Hist 33:113–173

    Google Scholar 

  • Keeling D (2008) The voyage abstracts of the cunard line as a source of transatlantic passenger fares. 1883–1914. Bus Arch Sour Hist 96:15–36

    Google Scholar 

  • Knack S, Keefer P (1995) Institutions and economic performance: cross-country tests using alternative institutional measures. Econ Pol 7(3):207–227

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kose MA, Prasad E, Rogoff K, Wei SJ (2009) Financial globalization: a reappraisal. IMF Staff Papers 56:8–62

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kugler M, Rapoport H (2007) International labor and capital flows: complements or substitutes? Econ Lett 94(2):155–162

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • La Porta R, Lopez-de-Silanes F, Shleifer A, Vishny R (1999) The quality of government. J Law Econ Organ 15(1):222–279

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Langbein L, Knack S (2010) The worldwide governance indicators: six, one, or none? J Dev Stud 46(2): 350–370

    Google Scholar 

  • Lee CC, Chang CP (2005) Structural breaks, energy consumption, and economic growth revisited: evidence from Taiwan. Energy Econ 27(6):857–872

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Levine R (2001) International financial liberalization and economic growth. Rev Int Econ 9(4):688–702

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Levine R (2005) Finance and growth: theory and evidence. In: Aghion P, Durlauf SH (eds) Handbook of economic growth vol 1. Elsevier, Amsterdam, pp 865–934

    Chapter  Google Scholar 

  • Levine R (2008) Finance and the poor. Manch Sch 76(1):1–13

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Li X, McHale J (2006) Does brain drain lead to institutional gain? A cross country empirical investigation. University of British Columbia.http://leonardo3.dse.univr.it/espe/documents/Papers/D/5/D5_3.pdf

  • Lorentzen P, McMillan J, Wacziarg R (2008) Death and development. J Econ Growth 13(2):81–124

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Marshall MG, Gurr TR, Jaggers K (2009) Polity \(\text{ IV }^{\rm TM}\) Project dataset users’ manual. Center for Systemic Peace. http://www.systemicpeace.org/polity/polity4.htm

  • Perez-Moreno S (2011) Financial development and poverty in developing countries: a causal analysis. Empir Econ 41:57–80

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Perotti R (1996) Growth, income distribution, and democracy: what the data say. J Econ Growth 1:149–187

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Rajan RG, Zingales L (2003) The great reversals: the politics of financial development in the twentieth century. J Fin Econ 69(1):5–50

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ratha D, Shaw W (2007) South-south migration and remittances. World Bank Working Paper No 102 The World Bank, Washington, DC

  • Rodrik D, Subramanian A, Trebbi F (2004) Institutions rule: the primacy of institutions over geography and integration in economic development. J Econ Growth 9(2):131–165

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Sahu P, Dash RK (2012) Economic growth in South Asia: role of infrastructure. J Int Trade Econ Dev 21(2):217–252

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Vogler M, Rotte R (2000) The effects of development on migration: theoretical issues and new empirical evidence. J Pop Econ 13(3):485–508

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgments

We are grateful to two anonymous referees and the editor of this journal for their insightful suggestions that helped to improve the paper considerably. We would also like to thank Robert Prasch for his thoughtful comments and advice; and Sarah B. King, Christian A. Johnson summer intern at Middlebury College, for her able research assistance. Earlier version of this paper was circulated as an IZA (Institute for the Study of Labor, Bonn, Germany) discussion paper # 5953, and as an Employment Policy Research Network research paper. The usual caveat applies.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Phanindra V. Wunnava.

Appendixis

Appendixis

See the Tables 6, 7, 8 and 9.

Table 6 List of countries
Table 7 Rotated factor loadings (principle factor method; orthomax rotation)
Table 8 Rotated factor loadings (iterated principle factor method; oblique promax rotation)
Table 9 Rotated factor loadings (maximum likelihood method; oblique promax rotation)

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Cite this article

Mitra, A., Bang, J.T. & Wunnava, P.V. Financial liberalization and the selection of emigrants: a cross-national analysis. Empir Econ 47, 199–226 (2014). https://doi.org/10.1007/s00181-013-0735-0

Download citation

  • Received:

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s00181-013-0735-0

Keywords

JEL Classification

Navigation