Skip to main content
Log in

Estimating a high-frequency New-Keynesian Phillips curve

  • Published:
Empirical Economics Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

This paper estimates a high-frequency New-Keynesian Phillips curve via the generalized method of moments. Allowing for higher-than-usual frequencies strongly mitigates the problems of small-sample bias and structural breaks. Applying a daily frequency allows us to obtain estimates for the Calvo parameter of nominal rigidity over a very short period—for instance for the recent financial and economic crisis—which can then be easily transformed into their low-frequency equivalences. With Argentine data from the end of 2007 to the beginning of 2011 we estimate the daily Calvo parameter and find that on average prices remain fixed for approximately two to three months which is in line with recent microeconomic evidence.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. For an empirical investigation see Fernández-Villaverde and Rubio-Ramírez (2007).

  2. See the corresponding Figure in the Appendix B and D’Amato et al. (2007).

  3. Alternatively to the purely forward-looking NKPC, we could also apply a hybrid version of the NKPC. This can be brought about either by assuming rule-of-thumb price setters à la Galí and Gertler (1999) or by assuming that non-reset prices are indexed to inflation as in Christinao et al. (2005). However, given that price changes are—in general—costly, the assumption of indexation to daily inflation rates is simply implausible. Furthermore, the estimation of a rule-of-thumb based hybrid NKPC yields the result that the share of backward-looking agents is not statistically different from zero for each estimation considered in this paper. Thus, the hypothesis of a hybrid NKPC on a daily basis—in our setting—has to be rejected. The insignificance of lagged inflation might be the result of the low autocorrelation of daily inflation, as can be seen from the Fig. 1 (lower panel) in the Appendix B. To support this presumption we perform a serial correlation Lagrange multiplier test on inflation (Godfrey 1978 and Breusch 1979) for lag lengths between 2 days and up to 1 week. In neither case we find any statistical significant lags at the 5 % confidence level. This result implies that daily inflation is not (or only very marginally) autocorrelated. Consequently, we restrict ourselves to the purely forward-looking NKPC.

  4. Note that there is no change in the price-setting behavior of the representative firm on a higher frequency, i.e., it is still the aim of the firm to minimize the (discounted) expected deviations of all its future optimal prices (defined as the real marginal costs times a mark-up) from the future market prices. Here the future is not denoted as the next quarter, but as the next day instead. In other words, due to the underlying rational expectation hypothesis firms use all information available when applying their optimization which leads to a quick adaptation to new information, i.e., changes in the economic environment. Obviously, this is in favor of the underlying Calvo (1983) price-setting scheme, which is specified in continuous time rather than discrete time.

  5. The following procedure can also be found in the modeling of search and matching processes; see, e.g., Mortensen (1986) and Rogerson et al. (2005). Anagnostopoulos and Giannitsarou (2010) analyze local stability under consideration of changes in the period length quite similar to Flaschel et al. (2008).

  6. Note that obviously the probability for not changing the price is higher at a higher frequency, i.e., at a period length of a day relative to a quarter. Furthermore, the stickiness remains the same in the sense that on average a firm is allowed to reset the price every \(1/[1-\theta (h_i)]\) periods of length \(h_i\) (say a day) which—independently of \(h_i\)—means every \(h_i/[1-\theta (h_i)]=h_i/[1-1+h_i(1-\theta (h_q))]=1/(1-\theta (h_q))\) quarters, respectively.

  7. Note that in addition neither the domestic and the foreign output gaps (as we will discuss below) nor the labor share of income stand for appropriate proxies, since both are also not available in daily magnitudes.

  8. Under the assumption of complete securities markets, Eq. (6) implies that relative consumption and hence (in a general equilibrium framework) the output gap relation across countries is proportional to the terms of trade. For a formal proof refer to Lubik and Schorfheide (2007) and Appendix A of Galí and Monacelli (2005). For an empirical discussion see Chari et al. (2002) among others.

  9. A related approach to estimate an open economy NKPC for a quarterly frequency has been applied by Mihailov et al. (2011a).

  10. Holmberg (2006) even shows that CPI data results in more realistic estimates for an open economy NKPC in Sweden compared to the use of the GDP-deflator. In empirical applications of the closed economy version of the NKPC this approach is common too due to reasons of data availability. Recent examples are, among others, Ramos-Francia and Torres (2008) and Yazgan and Yilmazkuday (2005). Moreover, Nason and Smith (2008) apply both measures to test for robustness and find the differences in performance to be negligible for the United States.

  11. In particular, the prices of 150 products are checked online every day. This methodology is sufficient since 100 % of all products in Argentine supermarkets can also be found online (Cavallo 2012a). For a thorough discussion of the methodology of the billion prices project at MIT Sloan, we refer to Cavallo (2012a, b), Cavallo and Rigobon (2011), www.inflacionverdadera.com and www.billionpricesproject.com.

  12. According to Eq. (4) the discount rate in daily magnitudes is than equal to \(\beta (h_d)=1/(1+\frac{h_d}{h_q} \rho (h_q))=0.999\) where \(h_d=1/75\) and \(h_q=1\).

  13. Following Galí and Gertler (1999), we define deviations from steady state in terms of demeaned time series. The results are robust, however, also to the use of the Hodrick-Prescott filter with \(\lambda =6{,}812{,}100\) for daily observations.

  14. For a detailed summary of the micro evidence on the frequency of price setting from CPI data for developed and developing countries we refer to Alvarez (2008) and Klenow and Malin (2010).

  15. For a general discussion of the nonlinear Anderson-Rubin-statistic we refer to Stock et al. (2002). For applications of this test statistic to the NKPC we refer to Ma (2002), Khalaf and Kichian (2004) and Yazgan and Yilmazkuday (2005).

  16. An explicit empirical investigation concerning the period length h in sticky and flexible price models can be found in Aadland (2001) and Christiano (1985). Further investigation of this issue is necessary.

  17. This result only holds for the standard flex-price model. Once we take into account for instance non-separable utility between consumption and money-in-the-utility function, shopping time models or cash-in-advance constraints, monetary policy is—although in quantitative terms very little—effective (Walsh 2010).

References

  • Aadland D (2001) High frequency real business cycles. J Monetary Econ 48:271–292

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Abe N, Tonogi A (2010) Micro and macro price dynamics in daily data. J Monetary Econ 57:716–728

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Alvarez LJ (2008) What do micro price data tell us on the validity of the New Keynesian Phillips curve? Econ: The Open-Access, Open-Assess E-J 2:1–38

    Google Scholar 

  • Anagnostopoulos A, Giannitsarou C (2010) Modeling time and macroeconomic dynamics. CEPR Discussion Paper No. 8050

  • Bils M, Klenow PJ (2004) Some evidence on the importance of sticky prices. J Polit Econ 112:947–985

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Breusch TS (1979) Testing for autocorrelation in dynamic linear models. Aust Econ Pap 17:334–355

    Google Scholar 

  • Calvo GA (1983) Staggered prices in a utility-maximizing framework. J Monetary Econ 12:383–398

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cavallo A (2010) Scraped data and sticky prices: frequency, hazards, and synchronization. MIT Sloan Working Paper

  • Cavallo A (2012a) Scraped data and sticky prices. MIT Sloan Working Paper

  • Cavallo A (2012b) Online and official price indexes: measuring Argentina’s inflation. MIT Sloan Working Paper

  • Cavallo A, Rigobon R (2011) The distribution of the size of price changes. NBER Working Paper No. 16760

  • Chari VV, Kehoe PJ, McGrattan ER (2002) Can sticky price models generate volatile and persistent real exchange rates? Rev Econ Stud 69:533–563

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Christiano LJ (1985) A method for estimating the timing interval in a linear econometric model, with an application to Taylor’s model of staggered contracts. J Econ Dyn Control 9:363–404

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Christinao LJ, Eichenbaum M, Evans CL (2005) Nominal rigidities and the dynamic effects of a shock to monetary policy. J Polit Econ 113:1–45

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Clarida R, Galí J, Gertler M (2001) Optimal monetary policy in open versus closed economies: an integrated approach. AM Econ Rev 91:248–252

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Clarida R, Galí J, Gertler M (2002) A simple framework for international monetary policy analysis. J Monetary Econ 49:879–904

    Google Scholar 

  • D’Amato L, Garegnani ML, Sotes Paladino JM (2007) Inflation persistence and changes in the monetary regime: the Argentine case. Working Paper 2007|23, Banco Central de la República Argentina

  • D’Amato L, Garegnani ML (2009) Studying the short-run dynamics of inflation: estimating a hybrid New-Keynesian Phillips curve for Argentina (1993–2007). Working Paper 2009|40, Banco Central de la República Argentina

  • Dhyne E, Alvarez LJ, Bihan HL, Veronese G, Dias D, Hoffmann J, Jonker N, Lunnemann P, Rumler F, Vilmunen J (2006) Price changes in the Euro Area and the United States: some facts from individual consumer price data. J Econ Perspect 20:171–192

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ellis C (2009) Do supermarket prices change from week to week? Bank of England Working Paper No. 378

  • Escudé GJ (2007) ARGEM: a DSGE model with banks and monetary policy regimes with two feedback rules, calibrated for Argentina. Working Paper 2007|21, Banco Central de la República Argentina

  • Escudé GJ (2009) ARGEMmy: an intermediate DSGE calibrated/estimated for Argentina: two policy rules are often better than one. Working Paper 2009|42, Banco Central de la República Argentina

  • Fernández-Villaverde J, Rubio-Ramírez JF (2007) How structural are structural parameters? NBER Working Paper No. 13166

  • Flaschel P, Franke R, Proaño CR (2008) On equilibrium determinacy in New Keynesian models with staggered wage and price setting. BE J Macroecon, Article 31

  • Franke R, Sacht S (forthcoming) Some observations in the high-frequency versions of a standard New-Keynesian model. B Econ Res

  • Fuhrer JC, Moore GR, Schuh SD (1995) Estimating the linear-quadratic inventory model: maximum likelihood versus generalized method of moments. J Monetary Econ 35:115–157

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Galí J (2008) Monetary policy, inflation and the business cycle: an introduction to the New Keynesian framework. Princeton University Press, Princeton

    Google Scholar 

  • Galí J, Gertler M (1999) Inflation dynamics: a structural econometric analysis. J Monetary Econ 44:195–222

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Galí J, Gertler M, Lopez-Salido JD (2001) European inflation dynamics. Eur Econ Rev 45:1237–1270

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Galí J, Monacelli T (2005) Monetary policy and exchange rate volatility in a small open economy. Rev Econ Stud 72:707–734

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Godfrey LG (1978) Testing against general autoregressive and moving average error models when the regressors include lagged dependent variables. Econometrica 46:1293–1301

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gouvea S (2007) Price rigidity in Brazil: evidence from CPI micro data. Working Papers Series No. 143, Central Bank of Brazil

  • Hansen LP (1982) Large sample properties of generalized method of moments estimators. Econometrica 50:1029–54

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Holmberg K (2006) Derivation and estimation of a New Keynesian Phillips curve in a small open economy. Sveriges Riksbank Working Paper Series No. 197

  • Ireland PN (2005) The monetary transmission mechanism. Working Papers No. 06–1, Federal Reserve Bank of Boston

  • Khalaf L, Kichian M (2004) Estimating New Keynesian Phillips curves using exact methods. Bank of Canada Working Papers No. 04–11

  • Kehoe PJ, Midrigan V (2007) Sales and the real effects of monetary policy. Working Papers No. 652, Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis

  • Klenow PJ, Malin BA (2010) Microeconomic evidence on price-setting. NBER Working Paper No. 15826

  • Leitemo K, Söderström U (2005) Simple monetary policy rules and exchange rate uncertainty. J Int Money Financ 24:481–507

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lindé J (2005) Estimating New-Keynesian Phillips curves: a full information maximum likelihood approach. J Monetary Econ 52:1135–1149

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lubik T, Schorfheide F (2007) Do central banks respond to exchange rate movements? A structural investigation. J Monetary Econ 54:1069–1087

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ma A (2002) GMM estimation of the New Phillips curve. Econ Lett 76:411–417

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mavroides S (2007) Testing the New Keynesian Phillips curve without assuming identification. Brown University Working Papers

  • McCallum BT (1976) Rational expectations and the natural rate hypothesis: some consistent estimates. Econometrica 44:43–52

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Medina JP, Rappoport D, Soto C (2007) Dinámica de ajuste de precios: evidencia de datos microeconómicos para Chile. J Econ Chilena 10:5–26

    Google Scholar 

  • Mihailov A, Rumler F, Scharler J (2011a) The small open-economy New Keynesian Phillips curve: empirical evidence and implied inflation dynamics. Open Econ Rev 22:317–337

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mihailov A, Rumler F, Scharler J (2011b) Inflation dynamics in the new EU member states: how relevant are external factors? Rev Int Econ 19:65–76

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Monacelli T (2004) Into the Mussa puzzle: monetary policy regimes and the real exchange rate in a small open economy. J Int Econ 62:191–217

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Morandé F, Tejada M (2008) Price stickiness in emerging economies: empirical evidence for four Latin-American countries. Working Papers wp286, University of Chile, Department of Economics, Chile

  • Mortensen DT (1986) Job search and labor market analysis. In: Ashenfelter O, Layard R (ed.) Handb Labor Econ, 1st edn. Elsevier, Amsterdam, pp 849–919

  • Nason MN, Smith GW (2008) The New Keynesian Phillips curve: lessons from single-equation econometric estimation. Econ Q 94:361–395

    Google Scholar 

  • Ramos-Francia M, Torres A (2008) Inflation dynamics in Mexico: a characterization using the New Phillips curve. N Am J Econ Financ 19:274–289

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Rogerson R, Shimer R, Wright R (2005) Search-theoretic models of the labor market: a survey. J Econ Lit 43:959–988

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Stock JH, Wright JH, Yogo M (2002) A survey of weak instruments and weak identification in generalized method of moments. J Bus Econ Stat 20:518–529

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Svensson LEO, Woodford M (2003) Indicator variables for optimal policy. J Monetary Econ 50:691–720

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Taylor JB (1999) Staggered price and wage setting in macroeconomics. In: Taylor JB, Woodford M (eds) Handbook of macroeconomics, 1st edn. Elsevier, Amsterdam, pp 1009–1050

    Chapter  Google Scholar 

  • Walsh C (2010) Monetary theory and policy. The MIT Press, Cambridge

    Google Scholar 

  • Woodford M (2003) Interest and prices: foundations of a theory of monetary policy. Princeton University Press, Princeton

    Google Scholar 

  • World Bank (2009) World development indicators.

  • World Bank (2010) Argentina trade brief. World trade indicators 2009/10: Country Trade Briefs. World Bank, Washington, DC

  • Yazgan ME, Yilmazkuday H (2005) Inflation dynamics of Turkey: a structural estimation. Stud Nonlinear Dyn E 9:1–15

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgments

We would like to thank Reiner Franke, Matthias Hartmann, Henning Weber and Hans-Werner Wohltmann as well as two anonymous referees for helpful comments. Furthermore we would like to thank the participants of the 2011 Conference on Modeling High Frequency Data in Finance III at the Stevens Institute of Technology (New Jersey, USA) and the 2011 Annual Meeting of the Swiss Society of Economics and Statistics at the University of Lucerne (Switzerland) for the discussion of this paper.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Stephen Sacht.

Appendices

Appendices

1.1 Appendix A: Household’s optimization problem

Following Woodford (2003) and Galí (2008) we consider a standard intertemporal utility function of a representative household, which is additive separable in consumption \(C_t\), in real money holding \(M_t/P_t\) (where \(P_t\) is the price level) and in leisure (labor supply \(N_t\), respectively), subject to the underlying frequency in daily magnitudes:

$$\begin{aligned} U_t=E_t \sum ^{\infty }_{k=0} \beta (h_d)^k \left[ \frac{1}{1-\sigma }C^{1-\sigma }_{t+k}+\frac{1}{1-\psi }\left( \frac{M_{t+k}}{P_{t+k}}\right) ^{1-\psi }-\frac{1}{1+\eta }N^{1+\eta }_{t+ k}\right] , \end{aligned}$$
(17)

where \(\sigma > 0\) represents the inverse intertemporal elasticity of substitution between present and future consumption of domestic goods, \(\eta > 0\) is the inverse of the substitution elasticity of labor, \(\psi >0\) stands for the inverse of the elasticity of money demand, \(\beta (h_d) >0\) is the (frequency-dependent) discount factor and \(E_t\) stands for the expectations operator.

The period-by-period budget constraint is characterized by money and bond holdings of the representative household and is given in real terms by

$$\begin{aligned} C_{t+k}&= -\frac{B_{t+k}}{P_{t+k}}-\frac{\Delta M_{t+k}}{P_{t+k}}+\frac{W_{t+k}}{P_{t+k}}N_{t+k} \nonumber \\ \qquad&+(1+i_{t+k-1})\frac{B_{t+k-1}}{P_{t+k}}+\Pi ^r_{t+k} + \frac{T^n_{t}}{P_t}, \end{aligned}$$
(18)

where \(M_t (B_t)\) is the household’s nominal holding of money (one-period bonds). Bonds pay a nominal interest rate \(i_t\) and \(1+i_t\) represents the gross nominal interest rate. \(W_t\) denotes the nominal wage. Real profits received from firms are equal to \(\Pi _t^r\) and \(T_t^n\) are nominal lump-sum taxes or transfers. Note that \(\Delta M_{t+k}=M_{t+k}-M_{t+k-1}\) holds.

The household seeks to maximize (17) subject to (18) and the following cash-in-advance constraint:

$$\begin{aligned} P_{t+k} C_{t+k} = M_{t+k}, \end{aligned}$$
(19)

i.e., nominal consumption expenditures are not allowed to exceed the nominal money holdings of the household. This expression is given in real terms and under consideration of \(y_t=c_t\) in Sect. 2. In can be easily shown that the optimality condition for the demand of real money holdings (in daily magnitudes) is given by:

$$\begin{aligned} m^r_t=\frac{M_t}{P_t}=\frac{1}{\psi } (\sigma y_t-\beta (h_d) i_t). \end{aligned}$$
(20)

1.2 Appendix B: Time series for the Argentine consumer price index (CPI)

See Fig. 1.

Fig. 1
figure 1

The upper panel depicts the development in the Argentine CPI in quarterly magnitudes from 1995Q1 until 2010Q4. The lower panel depicts the corresponding Argentine CPI in daily magnitudes (scraped data index) from 2007Q4 until 2010Q4. Quarterly data is taken from Datastream\(^\mathrm{\textregistered }\). Daily data is provided by www.inflacionverdadera.com

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Cite this article

Ahrens, S., Sacht, S. Estimating a high-frequency New-Keynesian Phillips curve. Empir Econ 46, 607–628 (2014). https://doi.org/10.1007/s00181-013-0684-7

Download citation

  • Received:

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s00181-013-0684-7

Keywords

JEL Classifications

Navigation