Skip to main content

Advertisement

Log in

Sectoral productivity gains in two regional economies: key sectors from a supply-side perspective

  • Original Paper
  • Published:
The Annals of Regional Science Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

The traditional literature to identify key sectors, based on an input–output demand-side approach, evaluates the impact on sectoral production of the exogenous inflows to activities. This approach has been the centre of an important debate, based on the lack of robustness of the results provided, that questions their usefulness for planning decisions. In this paper, we propose a novel method to analyse the key sectors of an economy that differs from the traditional approach in two aspects. First, we use a supply-side approach comprising exogenous increases in sectoral productivity. Second, we use a computable general equilibrium model that captures the complete relations between the economic agents and their optimisation behaviour. The computable general equilibrium model, which assumes perfect competition and cleared markets of goods and factors, allows to identify those sectors with the greatest impact on consumer’s welfare, which will be considered the key sectors of the economy. In particular, we apply our method to detect key sectors in two regional Spanish economies (Catalonia and Extremadura).

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. See Pyatt and Round (1979) for the conventional SAM multiplier analysis and Cardenete and Sancho (2006), for the extraction method in the SAM framework. Additionally, Los (2004) used the hypothetical extraction approach in a dynamic multisectoral model to analyse the impact caused by the disappearance of a sector of the economy.

  2. See, among others, Hewings (1982) and Hewings et al. (1989).

  3. The first study analyses the productivity gains of 85 sectors in the US economy during the period 1960–2005. The second quantifies the productivity gains of 27 sectors in Spain, Germany, France, Italy, the United Kingdom, the European Union and the US between 1995 and 2007.

  4. In particular, the communications technology sector and those other that have bought into this technological sector have made a large contribution to total productivity gains during the last decade.

  5. The analysis showed a sectoral ranking in terms of the impacts caused by each sector on the consumption price index of the regional economy. No other variables were considered in the study.

  6. These authors used a multisectoral computable general equilibrium model that was adapted to the characteristics of the towns under study. For each sector of production, they simulated increases in factor productivity, capital and labour.

  7. Catalonia is located in the north-east of Spain and is a highly industrialised region. It represents around 7 % of the national territory, 16 % of population (7,500,000 inhabitants) and 20 % of Spanish GDP. Extremadura is located in the south-west of Spain and has an important agricultural sector. It represents around 8 % of the national territory, 2.4 % of population (1,108,000 inhabitants) and 2 % of Spanish GDP.

  8. Llop et al. (2002) compared the regions of Catalonia and Extremadura by means of a linear and demand-driven model of SAM multipliers.

  9. Shoven and Whalley (1972).

  10. A complete description of the model, with a list of the equations and the variables involved, can be found in De Miguel-Vélez et al. (2009).

  11. The model distinguishes between production goods and consumption goods. Consumption goods are obtained through a conversion matrix of fixed coefficients that defines a direct (and linear) relationship between production prices and consumption prices.

  12. Acemoglu (2009) contains a formal analysis of these possibilities.

  13. Llop (2012) describes the construction and characteristics of the social accounting matrix of Catalonia. De Miguel-Vélez et al. (2009) describe the structure of the social accounting matrix of Extremadura.

  14. The SAMEXT is for 2000 and the SAMCAT is for 2001. Given that the statistical availabilities in each region concern different years, the same temporal reference could not be used. However, the results can be directly compared given that there is only one year’s difference between the two SAMs, and the patterns of revenues and expenditures have practically no variation over short periods of time.

  15. This analysis is a simplification of the complex relationship between unemployment and productivity gains, which certainly deserves greater attention than it is possible to give within the scope of this paper. Nevertheless, we have also used a labour supply as in Oswald (1982) to analyse a situation with rigidities in a labour market with endogenous unemployment. The fact that the results obtained in this way do not differ substantially from the ones showed here is proof of the robustness of the conclusions.

  16. According to the Banco de España (2006), in the year 2000 a typical Spanish home set aside 32 % of its disposable income to purchase a house.

References

  • Acemoglu D (2009) Introduction to modern economic growth. Princeton University Press, Princeton

    Google Scholar 

  • Banco de España (2006) Informe Anual 2005. Madrid

  • Cardenete MA, Sancho F (2006) Missing links in key sector analysis. Econ Syst Res 18(3):319–326

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cardenete MA, Sancho F (2012) The role of supply constraints in multiplier analysis. Econ Syst Res 24(1):21–34

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cardenete MA, Lima C, Sancho F (2014) Are there key sectors? A policy appraisal using applied general equilibrium, Rev Reg Stud, forthcoming

  • Chenery HB, Watanabe T (1958) International comparisons of the structure of production. Econometrica 26:487–521

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cutler H, Davies S (2010) The economic consequences of productivity changes: a computable general equilibrium (CGE) analysis. Reg Stud 44:1415–1426

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • De Miguel-Vélez FJ, Cardenete-Flores MA, Pérez-Mayo J (2009) Effects of the tax on retail sales of some fuels on a regional economy: a computable general equilibrium approach. Ann Reg Sci 43(3):781–806

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dietzenbacher E (1992) The measurement of interindustry linkages. Key sectors in the Netherlands. Econ Model 9:419–437

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dietzenbacher E (2005) More on multipliers. J Reg Sci 45(2):421–426

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • García AS, Morillas A, Ramos C (2008) Key sectors: a new proposal from network theory. Reg Stud 42(7):1013–1030

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • González-Calvet J, Manresa A (2007) Increments de productivitat sectorial i variacions de preus a l’economia catalana: simulació amb la TIOC-2001. Nota d’Economia 87:119–132

    Google Scholar 

  • Hanson K, Rose A (1997) Factor productivity and income inequality: a general equilibrium analysis. Appl Econ 29:1061–1071

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hewings GJD (1982) The empirical identification of key sectors in an economy: a regional perspective. Dev Econ 20:173–195

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hewings GJD, Fonseca M, Guilhoto J, Sonis M (1989) Key sectors and structural change in the Brazilian economy: a comparison of alternative approaches and their policy implications. J Policy Model 11(1):67–90

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Jorgenson DW, Ho MS, Samuels JD, Stiroh KJ (2007) Industry origins of the American productivity resurgence. Econ Syst Res 19:229–252

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Llop M, Manresa A, De Miguel FJ (2002) Comparación de Cataluña y Extremadura a través de matrices de contabilidad social. Investigaciones Económicas XXVI 3:573–587

    Google Scholar 

  • Llop M (2012) The role of saving and investment in a SAM price model. Ann Reg Sci 48(1):339–357

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Los B (2004) Identification of strategic industries: a dynamic perspective. Pap Reg Sci 83:669–698

    Google Scholar 

  • Mas Ivars M, Robledo JC (2010) Productividad. Una perspectiva Internacional y Sectorial. Fundación BBVA, Monografía

  • Oswald A (1982) The microeconomic theory of the trade union. Econ J 22:576–595

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Pyatt G, Round J (1979) Accounting and fixed price multipliers in a social accounting matrix framework. Econ J 89:850–873

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Rasmussen PN (1956) Studies in intersectoral relations. North-Holland, Amsterdam

  • Shoven JB, Whalley J (1972) Applied general equilibrium analysis of taxation and trade. J Econ Lit 22(3):1007–1051

    Google Scholar 

  • Solow R (1956) A contribution to the theory of economic growth. Q J Econ 70(1):65–94

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Strassert G (1968) Zur Bestimmung stretegischer Sektoren mit Hilfe von Input–Output Modelen. Jahrbucher fur Nationalokonomie und Statistik 182:211–215

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgments

The authors acknowledge the financial support of the Spanish Ministry of Culture (grant ECO2013-41917, ECO2012-34046 and SGR2014-299) and of the Catalan Government (grant SGR2009-322). Useful comments and suggestions by Erik Dietzenbacher and Ferran Sancho have substantially improved an earlier draft. The paper has also benefited from the suggestions by an anonymous referee and by the editor of the journal.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Maria Llop.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

De Miguel, F.J., Llop, M. & Manresa, A. Sectoral productivity gains in two regional economies: key sectors from a supply-side perspective. Ann Reg Sci 53, 731–744 (2014). https://doi.org/10.1007/s00168-014-0641-1

Download citation

  • Received:

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s00168-014-0641-1

JEL Classification

Navigation