Skip to main content

Advertisement

Log in

Nudge Versus Boost: How Coherent are Policy and Theory?

  • Published:
Minds and Machines Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

If citizens’ behavior threatens to harm others or seems not to be in their own interest (e.g., risking severe head injuries by riding a motorcycle without a helmet), it is not uncommon for governments to attempt to change that behavior. Governmental policy makers can apply established tools from the governmental toolbox to this end (e.g., laws, regulations, incentives, and disincentives). Alternatively, they can employ new tools that capitalize on the wealth of knowledge about human behavior and behavior change that has been accumulated in the behavioral sciences (e.g., psychology and economics). Two contrasting approaches to behavior change are nudge policies and boost policies. These policies rest on fundamentally different research programs on bounded rationality, namely, the heuristics and biases program and the simple heuristics program, respectively. This article examines the policy–theory coherence of each approach. To this end, it identifies the necessary assumptions underlying each policy and analyzes to what extent these assumptions are implied by the theoretical commitments of the respective research program. Two key results of this analysis are that the two policy approaches rest on diverging assumptions and that both suffer from disconnects with the respective theoretical program, but to different degrees: Nudging appears to be more adversely affected than boosting does. The article concludes with a discussion of the limits of the chosen evaluative dimension, policy–theory coherence, and reviews some other benchmarks on which policy programs can be assessed.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1
Fig. 2
Fig. 3
Fig. 4

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. According to the accuracy–effort trade-off, the less information, computation, or time a decision maker uses, the less accurate his or her judgments will be (see Payne et al. 1993). From this perspective, heuristics are construed to be less effortful, but never more accurate, than more complex strategies.

  2. Some authors have suggested the term “educate” for these kinds of policies (Bond 2009; Katsikopolous 2014). In our view, boosting goes beyond education and the provision of information. For example, in order to boost decision makers’ skills, policy designers need to identify information representations that match the cognitive algorithms of the human mind, thus using the environment (e.g., external representations) as an ally to foster insight and decision-making skills. We therefore prefer the term “boost” to “educate”.

  3. In the interest of full disclosure, let us point us that the second author has contributed to the SH program (see, e.g., Hertwig et al. 2013).

  4. To be precise, the original Save More Tomorrow™ program consisted of two stages. In the first, a consultant discussed possible retirement plans with the employees, based on their own stated preferences. Only if they were reluctant to accept the consultant’s advice did the consultant switch to the program (Thaler and Benartzi 2004, p. 172).

  5. Natural frequencies refer to the outcomes of natural sampling—that is, the acquisition of information by updating event frequencies without artificially fixing the marginal frequencies. Unlike probabilities and relative frequencies, natural frequencies are raw observations that have not been normalized with respect to the base rates of the event in question.

  6. It could be argued that the collective approach is consistent with the legal approach of a hierarchy of nearest relatives to the extent that the legally assigned (or patient-designated) surrogate can always consult others. This is correct, but the surrogate is not obliged to consult anybody else, nor does he or she need to take others’ opinion into account should their opinion differ from his or hers.

  7. The SH program does not endorse the strong language used by (some) proponents of the H&B approach to suggest that human reasoning is at times severely deficient (see Lopes 1991). One reason is that terms such as “cognitive illusions” presuppose the existence of a clear and unambiguous normative benchmark—an issue that has been hotly debated between the two programs (e.g., Gigerenzer 1996; Kahneman and Tversky 1996). Here, we use the more descriptive term “error” instead of “illusion” or “bias”.

  8. Some proponents of nudge policies consider the possibility that some people may be immune to certain errors, thus admitting a kind of population heterogeneity. Asymmetric paternalism (Camerer et al. 2003), for example, assumes that some members of a population may be fully rational, and hence not need a nudge that others require. Consequently, it seeks to devise policies that affect only those whose judgments are erroneous. Yet even asymmetric paternalism assumes that those who are subject to error are affected in such a way that a uniform nudge can steer them toward their optimal option.

References

  • Akl, E. A., Oxman, A. D., Herrin, J., Vist, G. E., Terrenato, J., Sperati, F., Costiniuk C, Blank D., & Schünemann H. (2011). Using alternative statistical formats for presenting risks and risk reductions. Cochrane Database of Systematic Reviews, 3, CD006776.

    Google Scholar 

  • Anderson, B. L., Gigerenzer, G., Parker, S., & Schulkin, J. (2012). Statistical literacy in obstetricians and gynecologists. Journal for Healthcare Quality, 36(1), 5–17.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Arkes, H. R., Gigerenzer, G., & Hertwig, R. (2014). Coherence cannot be a universal criterion for rational behavior: An ecological perspective. Manuscript submitted for publication.

  • Bargh, J. A. (1994). The four horsemen of automaticity: Awareness, intention, efficiency, and control in social cognition. In R. S. Wyer Jr & T. K. Srull (Eds.), Handbook of social cognition (pp. 1–40). Hillsdale, NJ: Lawrence Erlbaum Associates.

    Google Scholar 

  • Beglinger, B., Rohacek, M., Ackermann, S., Hertwig, R., Karakoumis-Ilsemann, J., Boutellier, S., Geigy, N., Nickel, C., & Bingisser, R. (2015). The physician’s first clinical impression of emergency department patients with non-specific complaints is associated with morbidity and mortality. Medicine, 94(7), e374. doi:10.1097/MD.0000000000000374

  • Berwick, D. M., Fineberg, H. V., & Weinstein, M. C. (1981). When doctors meet numbers. American Journal of Medicine, 71, 991–998.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Beshears, J., Choi, J. J., Laibson, D., & Madrian, B. C. (2009). The importance of default options for retirement saving outcomes: Evidence from the United States. In J. R. Brown, J. B. Liebman, & D. A. Wise (Eds.), Social security policy in a changing environment (pp. 167–195). Chicago, IL: University of Chicago Press.

    Chapter  Google Scholar 

  • Bond, M. (2009). Risk school. Nature, 461, 1189–1192.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bornstein, B. H., & Emler, A. C. (2001). Rationality in medical decision making: A review of the literature on doctors’ decision-making biases. Journal of Evaluation in Clinical Practice, 7, 97–107.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Börsch-Supan, A. (2004). Mind the gap: The effectiveness of incentives to boost retirement saving in Europe. OECD Economic Studies, 39, 111–144.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bovens, L. (2008). The ethics of nudge. In T. Grüne-Yanoff & S. O. Hansson (Eds.), Preference change: Approaches from philosophy, economics and psychology (pp. 207–219). Berlin: Springer.

    Google Scholar 

  • Brunswik, E. (1956). Perception and the representative design of psychological experiments. Berkeley, CA: University of California Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Camerer, C., Issacharoff, S., Loewenstein, G., O’Donoghue, T., & Rabin, M. (2003). Regulation for conservatives: Behavioral economics and the case for “asymmetric paternalism”. University of Pennsylvania Law Review, 151(3), 1211–1254.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cialdini, R. B. (2001). Influence: Science and practice (4th ed.). Boston: Allyn & Bacon.

    Google Scholar 

  • Covey, J. (2007). A meta-analysis of the effects of presenting treatment benefits in different formats. Medical Decision Making, 27, 638–654.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • European Commission. (2011). Attitudes of European citizens towards the environment. (Special Eurobarometer 365). Retrieved from http://ec.europa.eu/environment/pdf/ebs_365_en.pdf.

  • Fateh-Moghadam, B., & Gutmann, T. (2013). Governing [through] autonomy: The moral and legal limits of “soft paternalism”. Ethical Theory and Moral Practice, 17, 383–397.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fischer, J. E., Steiner, F., Zucol, F., Berger, C., Martignon, L., Bossart, W., et al. (2002). Use of simple heuristics to target macrolide prescription in children with community-acquired pneumonia. Archives of Pediatrics and Adolescent Medicine, 156, 1005–1008.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fodor, J. A. (1983). The modularity of mind. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Fox, C. R., Rogers, B. A., & Tversky, A. (1996). Options traders exhibit subadditive decision weights. Journal of Risk and Uncertainty, 13, 5–17.

    Article  MATH  Google Scholar 

  • Frederick, S. (2005). Cognitive reflection and decision making. Journal of Economic perspectives, 19(4), 25–42.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Freeman, A. M, I. I. I. (1993). The measurement of environmental and resource values. Washington, DC: Resources for the Future.

    Google Scholar 

  • Frey, R., Hertwig, R., & Herzog, S. M. (2014). Surrogate decision making: Do we have to trade off accuracy and procedural satisfaction? Medical Decision Making, 34, 258–269.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • García-Retamero, R., Galesic, M., & Gigerenzer, G. (2010). Do icon arrays help reduce denominator neglect? Medical Decision Making, 30, 672–684.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gerend, M. A., & Cullen, M. (2008). Effects of message framing and temporal context on college student drinking behavior. Journal of Experimental Social Psychology, 44(4), 1167–1173.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gigerenzer, G. (1996). On narrow norms and vague heuristics: A reply to Kahneman and Tversky (1996). Psychological Review, 103, 592–596.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gigerenzer, G. (2005). I think, therefore I err. Social Research: An International Quarterly, 72(1), 1–24.

    Google Scholar 

  • Gigerenzer, G. (2010). Collective statistical illiteracy. Archives of Internal Medicine, 170, 468–469.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gigerenzer, G. (2014). Breast cancer screening pamphlets mislead women: All women and women’s organisations should tear up the pink ribbons and campaign for honest information. British Medical Journal, 348, g2636.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gigerenzer, G., & Brighton, H. (2009). Homo heuristicus: Why biased minds make better inferences. Topics in Cognitive Science, 1(1), 107–143.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gigerenzer, G., & Edwards, A. (2003). Simple tools for understanding risks: From innumeracy to insight. British Medical Journal, 327, 741–744.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gigerenzer, G., Gaissmaier, W., Kurz-Milcke, E., Schwartz, L. M., & Woloshin, S. (2007). Helping doctors and patients make sense of health statistics. Psychological Science in the Public Interest, 8(2), 53–96.

    Google Scholar 

  • Gigerenzer, G., Hertwig, R., & Pachur, T. (Eds.). (2011). Heuristics: The foundations of adaptive behavior. Oxford, UK: Oxford University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Gigerenzer, G., & Hoffrage, U. (1995). How to improve Bayesian reasoning without instruction: Frequency formats. Psychological Review, 102(4), 684–704.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gigerenzer, G., & Muir Gray, J. A. (Eds.). (2011). Better doctors, better patients, better decisions: Envisioning health care 2020. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Gigerenzer, G., Todd, P. M., & the ABC Research Group. (1999). Simple heuristics that make us smart. New York, NY: Oxford University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Gilovich, T., Griffin, D., & Kahneman, D. (Eds.). (2002). Heuristics and biases: The psychology of intuitive judgment. Cambridge, UK: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Glaeser, E. L. (2006). Paternalism and psychology. University of Chicago Law Review, 73, 133–156.

    Google Scholar 

  • Goldstein, D. G., & Gigerenzer, G. (2002). Models of ecolological rationality: The recognition heuristic. Psychological Review, 109, 75–90.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Grüne-Yanoff, T. (2012). Old wine in new casks: Libertarian paternalism still violates liberal principles. Social Choice and Welfare, 38(4), 635–645.

    Article  MathSciNet  MATH  Google Scholar 

  • Hausman, D. M., & Welch, B. (2010). Debate: To nudge or not to nudge. Journal of Political Philosophy, 18(1), 123–136.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hautz, W. E., Kämmer, J. E., Schauber, S. K., Spies, C. D., & Gaissmaier, W. (2015). Diagnostic performance by medical students working individually or in teams. JAMA, 313, 303–304.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Heath, C., Larrick, R. P., & Klayman, J. (1998). Cognitive repairs: How organizational practices can compensate for individual shortcomings. Research in Organizational Behavior, 20, 1–37.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hertwig, R. (2012). Tapping into the wisdom of the crowd: With confidence. Science, 336(6079), 303–304.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hertwig, R., Buchan, H., Davis, D. A., Gaissmaier, W., Härter, M., Kolpatzik, K., Légaré, F., Schmacke, N., & Wormer, H. (2011). How will health care professionals and patients work together in 2020? A manifesto for change. In G. Gigerenzer & J. A. Muir Gray (Eds.), Better doctors, better patients, better decisions: Envisioning health care 2020 (pp. 317–337). Cambridge, MA: MIT Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hertwig, R., & Erev, I. (2009). The description–experience gap in risky choice. Trends in Cognitive Sciences, 13, 517–523.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hertwig, R., & Gigerenzer, G. (1999). The “conjunction fallacy” revisited: How intelligent inferences look like reasoning errors. Journal of Behavioral Decision Making, 12, 275–305.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hertwig, R., Hoffrage, U., & the ABC Research Group. (2013). Simple heuristics in a social world. New York, NY: Oxford University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Herzog, S. M., & Hertwig, R. (2009). The wisdom of many in one mind: Improving individual judgments with dialectical bootstrapping. Psychological Science, 20, 231–237.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Herzog, S. M., & Hertwig, R. (2013). The crowd-within and the benefits of dialectical bootstrapping: A reply to White and Antonakis (2013). Psychological Science, 24, 117–119.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Herzog, S. M., & Hertwig, R. (2014). Think twice and then: Combining or choosing in dialectical bootstrapping? Journal of Experimental Psychology: Learning, Memory, and Cognition, 40, 218–232.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hoffrage, U., Lindsey, S., Hertwig, R., & Gigerenzer, G. (2000). Communicating statistical information. Science, 290, 2261–2262.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • House of Lords Science and Technology Select Committee. (2011). Behaviour change (2nd report of session 2010–12, HL paper 179). London, UK: The stationary office. Retrieved from http://www.publications.parliament.uk/pa/ld201012/ldselect/ldsctech/179/179.pdf.

  • Jenny, M. A., Pachur, T., Williams, S. L., Becker, E., & Margraf, J. (2013). Simple rules for detecting depression. Journal of Applied Research in Memory and Cognition, 2, 149–157.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Johnson, E. J., Bellman, S., & Lohse, G. L. (2002). Defaults, framing and privacy: Why opting in-opting out. Marketing Letters, 13(1), 5–15.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Johnson, E., & Goldstein, D. (2003). Do defaults save lives? Science, 302, 1338–1339.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kahneman, D. (2003). Maps of bounded rationality: Psychology for behavioral economics. The American Economic Review, 93, 1449–1475.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kahneman, D. (2011). Thinking, fast and slow. New York, NY: Farrar, Straus & Giroux.

    Google Scholar 

  • Kahneman, D., Diener, E., & Schwarz, N. (Eds.). (1999). Well-being: The foundations of hedonic psychology. New York, NY: Russell Sage Foundation.

    Google Scholar 

  • Kahneman, D., & Krueger, A. B. (2006). Developments in the measurement of subjective well-being. Journal of Economic Perspectives, 20, 3–24.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kahneman, D., & Renshon, J. (2007). Why hawks win. Foreign Policy, 158, 34–38.

  • Kahneman, D., Slovic, P., & Tversky, A. (Eds.). (1982). Judgment under uncertainty: Heuristics and biases. New York, NY: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Kahneman, D., & Tversky, A. (1972). Subjective probability: A judgment of representativeness. Cognitive Psychology, 3, 430–454.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kahneman, D., & Tversky, A. (1979). Prospect theory: An analysis of decision under risk. Econometrica, 47, 263–291.

    Article  MATH  Google Scholar 

  • Kahneman, D., & Tversky, A. (1996). On the reality of cognitive illusions: A reply to Gigerenzer’s critique. Psychological Review, 103, 582–591.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Katsikopoulos, K. (2014). Bounded rationality: The two cultures. Journal of Economic Methodology,. doi:10.1080/1350178X.2014.965908.

    Google Scholar 

  • Klein, J. G. (2005). Five pitfalls in decisions about diagnosis and prescribing. British Medical Journal, 330, 781–783.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Koehler, J. J. (1996). The base rate fallacy reconsidered: Descriptive, normative and methodological challenges. Behavioral and Brain Sciences, 19, 1–53.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kruglanski, A. W., & Gigerenzer, G. (2011). Intuitive and deliberate judgments are based on common principles. Psychological Review, 118, 97–109.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kunreuther, H., & Michel-Kerjan, E. (2011). People get ready: Disaster preparedness. Issues in Science and Technology, 28, 1–7.

    Google Scholar 

  • Kurz-Milcke, E., Gigerenzer, G., & Martignon, L. (2008). Transparency in risk communication: Graphical and analog tools. Annals of the New York Academy of Sciences, 1128, 18–28.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kurz-Milcke, E., Gigerenzer, G., & Martignon, L. (2011). Risiken durchschauen: Grafische und analoge Werkzeuge [Understanding risk: Graphical and analog tools]. Stochastik in der Schule, 31, 8–16.

    Google Scholar 

  • Latten, S., Martignon, L., Monti, M., & Multmeier, J. (2011). Die Förderung erster Kompetenzen für den Umgang mit Risiken bereits in der Grundschule: ein Projekt von RIKO-STAT und dem Harding Center [Teaching risk literacy in elementary school: A project of RIKO-STAT and the Harding Center]. Stochastik in der Schule, 31, 17–25.

    Google Scholar 

  • Levin, I. P., & Gaeth, G. J. (1988). How consumers are affected by the framing of attribute information before and after consuming the product. Journal of Consumer Research, 15, 374–378.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lindsey, S., Hertwig, R., & Gigerenzer, G. (2003). Communicating statistical DNA evidence. Jurimetrics: The Journal of Law, Science, and Technology, 43, 147–163.

    Google Scholar 

  • Loewenstein, G., & Prelec, D. (1992). Anomalies in intertemporal choice: Evidence and an interpretation. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 107, 573–597.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lopes, L. L. (1991). The rhetoric of irrationality. Theory & Psychology, 1, 65–82.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Luan, S., Schooler, L. J., & Gigerenzer, G. (2011). A signal detection analysis of fast-and-frugal trees. Psychological Review, 118, 316–338.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Malmendier, U., & Tate, G. (2005). CEO overconfidence and corporate investment. Journal of Finance, 60, 2661–2700.

  • Marewski, J. N., & Schooler, L. J. (2011). Cognitive niches: An ecological model of strategy selection. Psychological Review, 118, 393–437.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Martignon, L., Katsikopoulos, K. V., & Woike, J. K. (2008). Categorization with limited resources: A family of simple heuristics. Journal of Mathematical Psychology, 52, 352–361.

    Article  MathSciNet  MATH  Google Scholar 

  • Martignon, L., Vitouch, O., Takezawa, M., & Forster, M. (2003). Naïve and yet enlightened: From natural frequencies to fast and frugal decision trees. In D. Hardman & L. Macchi (Eds.), Thinking: Psychological perspectives on reasoning, judgment, and decision making (pp. 189–211). Chichester, UK: Wiley.

    Google Scholar 

  • Mata, J., Frank, R., & Gigerenzer, G. (2014). Symptom recognition of heart attack and stroke in nine European countries: A representative study. Health Expectations, 17, 376–387.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • McKenzie, C. R. M., Liersch, M. J., & Finkelstein, S. R. (2006). Recommendations implicit in policy defaults. Psychological Science, 17, 414–420.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • McLeod, P., & Dienes, Z. (1996). Do fielders know where to go to catch the ball, or only how to get there? Journal of Experimental Psychology: Human Perception and Performance, 22, 531–543.

    Google Scholar 

  • Meyvis, T., Ratner, R. K., & Levav, J. M. (2010). Why don’t we learn to accurately forecast feelings? How misremembering our predictions blinds us to forecasting errors. Journal of Experimental Psychology: General, 139, 579–589.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mitchell, G. (2005). Libertarian paternalism is an oxymoron. Northwestern University Law Review, 99(3), 1245–1277.

    Google Scholar 

  • Nelson, W., Reyna, V. F., Fagerlin, A., Lipkus, I., & Peters, E. (2008). Clinical implications of numeracy: Theory and practice. Annals of Behavioral Medicine, 35(3), 261–274.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Pachur, T., & Hertwig, R. (2006). On the psychology of the recognition heuristic: Retrieval primacy as a key determinant of its use. Journal of Experimental Psychology: Learning, Memory, and Cognition, 32, 983–1002.

    Google Scholar 

  • Park, C. W., Jun, S. Y., & MacInnis, D. J. (2000). Choosing what I want versus eliminating what I don’t want: The effects of additive versus subtractive product option framing on consumer decision making. Journal of Marketing Research, 37(2), 187–202.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Payne, J. W., Bettman, J. R., & Johnson, E. J. (1993). The adaptive decision maker. Cambridge, UK: Cambridge University.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Payne, J. W., Bettman, J. R., & Schade, D. A. (1999). Measuring constructed preferences: Towards a building code. Journal of Risk and Uncertainty, 19, 243–270.

    Article  MATH  Google Scholar 

  • Pichert, D., & Katsikopoulos, K. V. (2008). Green defaults: Information presentation and pro-environmental behavior. Journal of Environmental Psychology, 28, 63–73.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Posner, R. A. (1979). Some uses and abuses of economics in law. The University of Chicago Law Review, 46(2), 281–306.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Rebonato, R. (2012). Taking liberties: A critical examination of libertarian paternalism. New York, NY: Palgrave Macmillan.

    Google Scholar 

  • Reyna, V. F., Nelson, W. L., Han, P. K., & Dieckmann, N. F. (2009). How numeracy influences risk comprehension and medical decision making. Psychological Bulletin, 135(6), 943–973.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Rieskamp, J., & Otto, P. E. (2006). SSL: A theory of how people learn to select strategies. Journal of Experimental Psychology: General, 135, 207–236.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Rothman, A. J., Bartels, R. D., Wlaschin, J., & Salovey, P. (2006). The strategic use of gain-and loss-framed messages to promote healthy behavior: How theory can inform practice. Journal of Communication, 56(s1), S202–S220.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Rottenstreich, Y., & Tversky, A. (1997). Unpacking, repacking, and anchoring: Advances in support theory. Psychological Review, 104, 406–415.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Saghai, Y. (2014). Salvaging the concept of nudge. Journal of Medical Ethics, 38, 487–493.

    Google Scholar 

  • Sarfati, D., Howden-Chapman, P., Woodward, A., & Salmond, C. (1998). Does the frame affect the picture? A study into how attitudes to screening for cancer are affected by the way benefits are expressed. Journal of Medical Screening, 5, 137–140.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Sedlmeier, P., & Gigerenzer, G. (2001). Teaching Bayesian reasoning in less than two hours. Journal of Experimental Psychology: General, 130, 380–400.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Sedrakyan, A., & Shih, C. (2007). Improving depiction of benefits and harms: Analyses of studies of well-known therapeutics and review of high-impact medical journals. Medical Care, 45, 523–528.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Simon, H. A. (1956). Rational choice and the structure of the environment. Psychological Review, 63, 129–138.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Simon, H. A. (1978). Rationality as process and as product of thought. American Economic Review, 68, 1–16.

    Google Scholar 

  • Simon, H. A. (1990). Invariants of human behavior. Annual Review of Psychology, 41, 1–19.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Skinner, B. F. (1971). Beyond freedom and dignity. New York, NY: Knopf.

    Google Scholar 

  • Skinner, B. F. (1975). Walden two. Indianapolis, IN: Hackett.

  • Smith, N. C., Goldstein, D. G., & Johnson, E. J. (2013). Choice without awareness: Ethical and policy implications of defaults. Journal of Public Policy & Marketing, 32, 159–172.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Staddon, J. (1995) On responsibility and punishment. The Atlantic Monthly, 275(2), 88–94.

  • Sunstein, C. R. (2014). Why nudge? The politics of libertarian paternalism. New Haven, CN: Yale University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Thaler, R. H. (1991). Quasi rational economics. New York, NY: Sage.

    Google Scholar 

  • Thaler, R., & Benartzi, S. (2004). Save more tomorrow: Using behavioral economics to increase employee savings. Journal of Political Economy, 112, 164–187.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Thaler, R. H., & Sunstein, C. R. (2008). Nudge: Improving decisions about health, wealth, and happiness. New Haven, CT: Yale University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Todd, P. M., Gigerenzer, G., & the ABC Research Group. (2012). Ecological rationality: Intelligence in the world. New York, NY: Oxford University Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Tversky, A. (1996). Contrasting rational and psychological principles in choice. In R. J. Zeckhauser, R. L. Keeny, & J. K. Sebenius (Eds.), Wise choices: Decisions, games and negotiations (pp. 5–21). Boston, MA: Harvard Business School Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Tversky, A., & Kahneman, D. (1971). Belief in the law of small numbers. Psychological Bulletin, 76(2), 105.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Tversky, A., & Kahneman, D. (1974). Judgment under uncertainty: Heuristics and biases. Science, 185(4157), 1124–1131.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Tversky, A., & Kahneman, D. (1992). Advances in prospect theory: Cumulative representation of uncertainty. Journal of Risk and Uncertainty, 5, 297–323.

    Article  MATH  Google Scholar 

  • Veetil, V. P. (2011). Libertarian paternalism is an oxymoron: An essay in defence of liberty. European Journal of Law and Economics, 31(3), 321–334.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Volz, K. G., Schooler, L. J., Schubotz, R. I., Raab, M., Gigerenzer, G., & von Cramon, D. Y. (2006). Why you think Milan is larger than Modena: Neural correlates of the recognition heuristic. Journal of Cognitive Neuroscience, 18(11), 1924–1936.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Wegwarth, O., & Gigerenzer, G. (2013). Trust-your-doctor: A simple heuristic in need of a proper social environment. In R. Hertwig, U. Hoffrage, & the ABC Research Group (Eds.), Simple heuristics in a social world (pp. 67–102). New York, NY: Oxford University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • White, M. (2013). The manipulation of choice. Ethics and libertarian paternalism. New York, NY: Palgrave MacMillan.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Wilkinson, T. M. (2013). Nudging and manipulation. Political Studies, 61(2), 341–355.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • World Health Organization. (2013). Obesity and overweight. Factsheet N°311. Geneva, Switzerland: Author. Retrieved from http://www.who.int/mediacentre/factsheets/fs311/en/.

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Till Grüne-Yanoff.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Grüne-Yanoff, T., Hertwig, R. Nudge Versus Boost: How Coherent are Policy and Theory?. Minds & Machines 26, 149–183 (2016). https://doi.org/10.1007/s11023-015-9367-9

Download citation

  • Received:

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s11023-015-9367-9

Keywords

Navigation