1 Introduction

Permafrost (permanently frozen ground) is a major component of the cryosphere and occupies 24 % of the Northern Hemisphere’s land surface (Zhang et al. 2008). Observed warming in this area during the last 30 years was as high as 3 °C in parts of Northern Alaska and as high as 2 °C in parts of the Russian European North, between two to three times the global average (IPCC 2013). A reduction in permafrost thickness and surface area has been observed (Brown and Romanovsky 2008). As previously frozen soils thaw, substantial quantities of organic carbon become available for decomposition by soil microbes. Permafrost contains twice as much carbon as is currently stored in the atmosphere (Zimov et al. 2006) and the release of a small fraction - in the form of carbon dioxide (CO2) and methane (CH4) - may lead to a positive feedback and increase the rate of future climate change (Burke et al. 2012).

The first studies estimated a permafrost carbon pool of almost 1700 gigatons (Gt) (see for an overview Zimov et al. 2006 or Schuur et al. 2008). New lines of evidence (Schuur et al. 2015), based on recent observations, show that substantial amounts of carbon are also accumulated in deeper areas and that these are susceptible to future thaw. Recent evidence also suggests that the most likely process is a gradual and prolonged release of greenhouse gases (Schuur et al. 2015), but also indicating that a significant amount of carbon would be released in low emission pathways before 2100.

The extra warming caused by the permafrost carbon feedback (PCF) has been investigated (see MacDougall et al. 2012, Schneider von Deimling et al. 2012; Burke et al. 2012 and Schaefer et al. 2014). However, this feedback is not currently incorporated in economic assessment models (Stern 2016). The additional economic damage caused by permafrost carbon release was analysed (Hope and Schaefer 2015). In comparison to their study which focused on economic damages, we are interested in studying the implications of permafrost thawing within a climate change control setting. More specifically, we estimate the additional efforts required to maintain a radiative forcing of 2.6 W per m2 (Wm−2) in 2100 when adding the extra emissions from permafrost thawing.

2 Materials and methods

2.1 Climate change control scenarios

We set a radiative forcing target of 2.6 Wm−2 for the year 2100 (allowing for “overshooting” during the century) following the RCP approach used by IPCC (see IPCC 2013). We consider two scenarios: The first scenario does not consider the permafrost carbon feedback (Scenario RCP2.6) while the second one does (Scenario RCP2.6_PCF). Scenario RCP2.6 introduces the constraint that the total radiative forcing should be equal to 2.6 Wm−2 in 2100, which according to IPCC (2013) corresponds to likely Footnote 1 remaining below a 2 °C temperature increase. To be consistent with RCP scenarios from literature, we consider that the exogenous radiative forcing from non-CO2 factors increases from 0.25 to 0.4 Wm−2 and that land-use emissions are reduced progressively to zero by 2100 (IIASA 2015, Van Vuuren et al. 2011). Scenario RCP2.6_PCF corresponds exactly to Scenario RCP2.6 but includes emissions from permafrost. This scenario therefore requires that the emissions of fossil fuel and industrial CO2 need to be reduced more to achieve the same climate target.

2.2 Emissions from permafrost

We use the study from Schneider von Deimling et al. 2015 which includes the most recent available projections of CO2 and CH4 fluxesFootnote 2 from thawing permafrost under the RCP2.6 scenario (Fig. 1). In their estimation the emissions from permafrost peak during the second half of the century and then decline. The emissions continue beyond 2100, however as they are monotonously declining it is feasible to set a control target in 2100. The only source of uncertainty we include relates to the 68 % confidence interval on the permafrost emission estimates by these authors. Although many other sources of uncertainty are present, the goal of our study is not to conduct a probabilistic analysis but to estimate how the expected permafrost carbon feedback impacts climate change control all other factors being equal.

Fig. 1
figure 1

Emissions release from permafrost under the RCP 2.6 scenario (GtCO 2 -eq y −1 ). The blue lines indicate emissions of permafrost carbon feedback: median (solid), 16th percentile (dotted) and 84th percentile (dashed) pathway (Schneider von Deimling et al. 2015). The red solid line at 0 line refers to the scenario without permafrost thawing

2.3 Integrated assessment model

We use the Dynamic Integrated Climate-Economy model (DICE version 2013R, Nordhaus and Sztorc 2013), a well-known integrated assessment model (IAM) of climate-change economics (Nordhaus 1992, 2014; Butler et al. 2014; Moore and Diaz 2015). In this approach, society invests in capital goods, thereby reducing consumption today, in order to increase consumption in the future. Investing in emissions reduction reduces consumption today but prevents future damage from climate change. In our study an optimal path for fossil fuel and industrial CO2 emission reduction is sought that maximizes the net present value of cumulative economic welfare from 2010 to 2100 subject to a constraintFootnote 3 on radiative forcing (2.6 Wm−2 in 2100). In this approach economic welfare corresponds to net welfare, i.e. the damagesFootnote 4 from climate change and the mitigation costs have already been deducted. More detailed technical information on DICE can be found in Nordhaus and Sztorc (2013).

3 Results

Figure 2a depicts the resulting CO2 emission pathways to reach the 2.6 Wm−2 climate change control target5. The results indicate that in the presence of a permafrost carbon feedback the fossil fuel and industrial CO2 emissions need to peak between 5 to 10 years earlier. The carbon budget needs to be reduced from 1570 GtCO2 to 1420 [1310–1500] GtCO2, equivalent to a 10 [5.7–16.5] % reduction (Fig. 2b). The CO2 concentration in the atmosphere would be slightly lower during the entire century (Fig. 2c).

Fig. 2
figure 2

Climate change control under permafrost carbon feedback. Pathway for 2010–2100 without (red) and with permafrost thawing (blue) a) Fossil fuel and industrial CO2 emissions, b) Cumulative fossil fuel and industrial CO2 emissions, c) CO2 concentration in the atmosphere and d) Radiative forcing. The dashed and dotted line indicate the 68 % confidence interval associated with the permafrost emission estimates

The required reductions of fossil fuel and industrial CO2 emissions of 149.1 [74.6–259.0] GtCO2 are higher than the cumulative emissions generated along the century from permafrost (122.0 [61.0–211.0] GtCO2-eq). This is because the overshooting potential is reduced (see Fig. 2d) due to the presence of continued emissions from permafrost in the second half of the century.

In summary, the presence of a permafrost carbon feedback requires that the reduction of fossil fuel and industrial CO2 emissions needs to be greater and occur earlier. This implies that the price (tax) of carbon must be higher, both now and in the future (Fig. 3a). In the absence of the permafrost carbon feedback the global price of CO2 (assuming full participation) would need to rise from 36 US$/tCO2 in 2015 to 180 US$/tCO2 in 2050. In the presence of a permafrost carbon feedback the respective increase would need to be from 41[38–46] US$/tCO2 in 2015 to 210 [200–240] US$/tCO2 in 2050 (Fig. 3a).

Fig. 3
figure 3

Economic implications of permafrost carbon feedback. a Carbon price without (red) and with permafrost carbon feedback (blue). The dashed and dotted line indicate the 68 % confidence interval associated with the permafrost emission estimates. b mitigation cost without (RCP2.6) and with permafrost carbon feedback (RCP2.6_PCF)

The higher carbon price implies higher costs to society. The presence of a permafrost carbon feedback would increase the mitigation cost from US$8.1 to US$9.0 [8.5–9.8] trillion, equivalent to a 6–21 % increase (Fig. 3b). Devoting more resources to mitigation implies a reduction of consumption and investment, implying a loss in welfare. Our results show that the net present value of total welfare from 2010 to 2100 is reduced due to permafrost carbon feedback by US$ 4.2 [2–7.8] trillion.

4 Sensitivity analysis for the mitigation cost

The mitigation costs obtained in our study are in the low range of the literature (see Clarke et al. 2014). There are two important factors explaining this result: the first being the discount rateFootnote 5 and the second the cost of the backstop technology.Footnote 6 To address this, we have studied (Table 1) the sensitivity of the mitigation cost towards changes in i) the pure rate of social time preference (ρ) and ii) the cost of backstop technology (pback).

Table 1 Sensitivity analysis for the mitigation costs (Trillion USD 2005). The table shows the results for alternative values for pure rate of social time preference (ρ) and cost of backstop technology (pback). The results are shown for RCP2.6 scenario (no permafrost carbon feedback) and for RCP2.6_PCF scenario (with permafrost carbon feedback). The values in brackets refer to the 68 % confidence interval associated with the permafrost emission estimates. The column (ρ = 0.1 % Recalibrated), following Nordhaus 2014, refers to a situation where the decrease in pure rate of social time preference is compensated for by increasing the risk aversion parameter (from α = 1.45 to α = 2.1) in order to maintain the market discount rate

The results for the default values of the DICE model (pure rate of social time preference of 1.5 % and a backstop technology at $344 per ton of CO2) have been described in section 3. As expected, the mitigation costs increase for lower discount rates and for higher prices of backstop technology. In the case of a pure rate of social time preference of 0.1 % (similar to the one used in Stern 2008) and a backstop technology price of 1000 US/tCO2, the present value of mitigation cost would be US$78.2 trillion for the RCP2.6 scenario and would rise to US$84.0 [81.0–88.6] trillion when including the permafrost carbon feedback. Conversely, with a pure rate of social time preference of 3 % and with a backstop technology at 100 US$/tCO2, the present value of mitigation cost would be US$0.8 trillion in the RCP2.6 scenario and US$0.9 [0.9–1.0] trillion when including the permafrost carbon feedback.

Following Nordhaus 2014, we include an additional scenario (ρ = 0.1 % Recalibrated), which refers to a situation where the decrease in pure rate of social time preference is compensated for by increasing the risk aversion parameter in order to maintain the market discount rate. As expected, the cost of mitigation is significantly lowered through recalibration and the results are very close to those obtained with ρ = 1.5 %.

The sensitivity analysis shows that the discount rate and the price of backstop technology significantly impact the mitigation costs. However, more importantly for our study, the relative additional mitigation costs are far less affected (Table 1).

5 Conclusions

Much of the current evidence on permafrost thawing has appeared subsequently to the Fifth Assessment Report (AR5) of the Intergovernmental Panel on Climate Change (IPCC) and has therefore not yet been included in the integrated assessment models (Schaefer et al. 2014). Our study shows significant consequences for climate change control. Thus the task of keeping warming below 2 °C becomes more challenging when considering the additional emissions from thawing permafrost. It is important to realise that permafrost thawing may not be the only feedback due to rapid Arctic change (Duarte et al. 2012) currently excluded from integrated assessment models. Other examples are the possibility of an abrupt melting of hydrates beneath the East Siberian Sea (Shakhova et al. 2010 and Whiteman et al. 2013) or a possible underestimation of the albedo feedback effect due to sea ice melting (Pistone et al. 2014).