Skip to main content
Log in

Intergenerational earnings mobility and divorce

  • Original Paper
  • Published:
Journal of Population Economics Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

This paper examines the potential effect of marital disruption on intergenerational earnings mobility. We observe the earnings of children born in 1960 and 1970 along with their biological fathers and mothers. The earnings mobility between sons and daughters relative to the earnings of their mothers and fathers is estimated. Our results suggest that divorce is associated with increased mobility, except between mothers’ and daughters’ earnings. Transition matrices reveal that the direction of the mobility is negative; children of divorced parents tend to move downward in the earnings distribution compared to children from intact families. Finally, we utilize information on the earnings mobility of siblings in dissolved families who grew up when the family was intact. The difference between pre- and post-divorce siblings is in turn compared with sibling differences in intact families.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. See Solon (1999) for a review.

  2. This is not an unambiguous prediction, however, as the new family structure may affect preferences for investing in children’s human capital.

  3. In Norway, the parent with child custody receives most of the public transfers plus child support from the non-custodial parent, the latter being enforced by law. This probably makes the custodial parent better off than in most other countries. See Tjøtta and Vaage (2008) for details.

  4. See Solon (1999) for a thorough exposition and Schnitzlein (2014) for a recent application.

  5. There is some evidence that intergenerational earnings elasticity changes over time; cf. Bratberg et al. (2005).

  6. The upper age limit is 65 because a significant portion of the total labour force has the opportunity to retire before the official retirement age at 67.

  7. The age intervals of parents are chosen to make the earnings averages comparable for intact and divorced families.

  8. In families with more than two children, we use siblings that are closest in age, given the earlier mentioned restrictions.

  9. The earnings records do not start before 1967, so we are not able to explore families who got divorced during the children’s first 10 years.

  10. Data limitations prevent us from checking unemployment and labour market programmes at earlier ages.

  11. It does, however, matter when we compare groups where the average age of the parents differ, as will be the case in the analysis of the sibling sample later in this section.

  12. The younger the parents, the more observations will be lost. We have chosen 41 and 51 as average ages (instead of 40 and 50) simply because it turned out that moving from 41 to 40 represented a disproportionate loss of observations.

  13. The only exception is parents divorced during the first 10 years of child’s life.

  14. Our estimates are comparable to the ones in Nilsen et al. (2012) in terms of common data sources, approximately the same average age for parents and offspring and the same size of earnings window (5 years) as a basis for the calculation of permanent earnings. The samples are different, however, in that Nilsen et al. do not condition on family type, and we do not condition on gender (in Table 11).

References

  • Amato PR, Keith B (1991) Parental divorce and the well-being of children: a meta-analysis. Psychol Bull 110:26–46

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Becker GS, Tomes N (1979) Equilibrium-theory of the distribution of income and intergenerational mobility. J Polit Econ 87:1153–1189

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Becker GS, Tomes N (1986) Human capital and the rise and fall of families. J Labor Econ 4:S1–S39

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Björklund A, Chadwick L (2003) Intergenerational income mobility in permanent and separated families. Econ Lett 80:239–246

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Björklund A, Jäntti M (1997) Intergenerational income mobility in Sweden compared to the United States. Am Econ Rev 87:1009–1018

    Google Scholar 

  • Black SE, Devereux PJ (2011) Recent developments in intergenerational mobility. In: Ashenfelter O, Card C (eds) Handbook of labor economics, vol 4b. Elsevier, Amsterdam, pp 1487–1541

    Chapter  Google Scholar 

  • Bratberg E, Nilsen OA, Vaage K (2005) Intergenerational earnings mobility in Norway: levels and trends. Scand J Econ 107:419–435

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bratberg E, Nilsen OA, Vaage K (2007) Trends in intergenerational mobility across offspring’s earnings distribution in Norway. Ind Relat 46:112–129

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bratsberg B, Røed K, Raaum O, Naylor R, Jäntti M, Eriksson T, Österbacka E (2007) Nonlinearities in intergenerational earnings mobility: consequences for cross-country comparisons. Econ J 117:C72—92

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Böhlmark A, Lindquist MJ (2006) Life-cycle variations in the association between current and lifetime income: replication and extension for Sweden. J Labor Econ 24:879–896

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cameron SV, Heckman JJ (1998) Life cycle schooling and dynamic selection bias: models and evidence for five cohorts of American males. J Polit Econ 106:262–333

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Carneiro P, Heckman JJ (2002) The evidence on credit constraints in post-secondary schooling. Econ J 112:989–1018

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Carneiro P, Heckman JJ (2003) Human capital policy. In: Heckman J J, Krueger A B (eds) Inequality in America: what role for human capital policies? MIT Press, Cambridge, pp 77–240

    Google Scholar 

  • Couch K, Lillard D (1997) Divorce, educational attainment, and the earnings mobility of sons. J Family Econ Issues 18:231–245

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fertig A (2007) Is intergenerational earnings mobility affected by divorce? Manuscript, University of Georgia

  • Gruber J (2004) Is making divorce easier bad for children? The long-run implications of unilateral divorce. J Labor Econ 22:799–833

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Haider S, Solon G (2006) Life-cycle variations in the association between current and lifetime earnings. Am Econ Rev 96:1308–1320

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Heckman JJ, Masterov DV (2007) The productivity argument for investing in young children. Rev Agr Econ 29:446–493

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Jäntti M, Bratsberg B, Roed K, Raaum O, Naylor R A, Österbacka E, Björklund A, Eriksson T (2006) American exceptionalism in a new light: a comparison of intergenerational earnings mobility in the Nordic countries, the United Kingdom and the United States. IZA Discussion Paper No. 1938

  • Lundberg SJ (2005) Sons, daughters, and parental behaviour. Oxford Rev Econ Pol 21:340–356

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mammen K (2011) Fathers’ time investments in children: do sons get more? J Popul Econ 24:839–871

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • McLanahan S (1985) Family structure and the reproduction of poverty. Am J Sociol 90:873

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • McLanahan S, Sandefur G (1994) Growing up with a single parent. What hurts, what helps. Harvard University, Cambridge

    Google Scholar 

  • Nilsen OA, Aakvik A, Jacobsen KA, Vaage K (2012) Intergenerational earnings mobility revisited: estimates based on lifetime earnings. Scand J Econ 114:1–23

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Peters HE (1992) Patterns of intergenerational mobility in income and earnings. Rev Econ Stat 74:456–466

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Schnitzlein DD (2014) How important is the family? Evidence from sibling correlations in permanent earnings in the USA, Germany, and Denmark. J Popul Econ 27:69–89

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Solon G (1992) Intergenerational income mobility in the United States. Am Econ Rev 82:393–408

    Google Scholar 

  • Solon G (1999) Intergenerational mobility in the labor market. In: Ashenfelter O, Card C (eds) Handbook of labor economics, vol 3a. Elsevier, Amsterdam, pp 1761–1800

    Chapter  Google Scholar 

  • Solon G (2002) Cross-country differences in intergenerational earnings mobility. J Econ Persp 16(3):59

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Statistics Norway (2011a) Statbank Norway. http://statbank.ssb.no/statistikkbanken/?PLanguage=1. Accessed 16 June 2011

  • Statistics Norway (2011b) One out of four children live with only one parent. http://www.ssb.no/english/subjects/02/01/20/barn_en/. Accessed 16 June 2011

  • Tjøtta S, Vaage K (2008) Public transfers and marital dissolution. J Popul Econ 21:419

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Zimmerman DJ (1992) Regression toward mediocrity in economic stature. Am Econ Rev 82:409–429

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgments

The authors would like to thank for helpful comments and suggestions from the Editor and two anonymous reviewers, Michael Lindquist and conference participants at EEA 2009 in Barcelona and SOLE 2011 in Vancouver. Financial support from the Research Council of Norway (grants 187912 and 199832) is gratefully acknowledged.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Espen Bratberg.

Additional information

Responsible editor: Erdal Tekin

All errors and opinions are the authors’ sole responsibility.

Electronic supplementary material

Below is the link to the electronic supplementary material.

(DOCX 53.9 KB)

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Bratberg, E., Elseth Rieck, K.M. & Vaage, K. Intergenerational earnings mobility and divorce. J Popul Econ 27, 1107–1126 (2014). https://doi.org/10.1007/s00148-014-0515-y

Download citation

  • Received:

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s00148-014-0515-y

Keywords

Navigation