Skip to main content
Log in

The university department as a non-profit labor cooperative

  • Symposium On Collective Choice In Education
  • Part IV ‘Clubs’, Negotiations, And Decision Processes
  • Published:
Public Choice Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Conclusion

In summary, we have characterized the academic department at a university as a non-profit faculty collective that engages in the ‘production’ of large profitable introductory classes in order to finance its ‘consumption’ of bright advanced students in small classes, as well as research. The implications of this model help to answer a number of questions regarding institutional behavior in higher education, including the following:

  1. 1.

    Why do people make donations of discretionary resources to universities, despite the economist's expectation that fixed costs or revenues (i.e., costs and revenues that are not tied to specific activities) will not influence behavior?

  2. 2.

    Why are faculty members paid less than people with comparable training in government or private industry?

  3. 3.

    Why is a large proportion of faculty time devoted to research, even where this is not separately funded?

  4. 4.

    Why do we observe huge cost variations across institutions, even when level and discipline are held constant?

  5. 5.

    Why is undergraduate education carried out in a more cost-intensive way at colleges than at universities?

  6. 6.

    Why are graduate training and research (G and R) (almost) always found in conjunction with undergraduate education (U), while U is often found without G and R?

  7. 7.

    Why is non-price rationing used extensively by academic institutions?

  8. 8.

    Why do universities typically face a pressure for departmental expansion, a perpetual need for ‘more’ resources?

  9. 9.

    Why do elaborate recruitment mechanisms, probationary periods with value indoctrination, segmented and committee decision-making prevail in academia?

  10. 10.

    How can the theory of the labor-managed firm help explain the prevalence of tenure and uniform teaching loads at universities?

This has been primarily an exercise in positive analysis; in a more normative approach to the subject we would have to specify the criteria for evaluation and the viewpoint we were adopting — that of students, faculty, university administrators and taxpayers. As we have seen above, there may well be conflicts among all of these interests so the assignment of decision-making power also implies an assignment of property rights and real income which, therefore, influences resource allocation. Potential sources of divergent interests between the department and the broader university of which it is one component, are explored in the Appendix.

In comparing the output levels of the non-profit collective such as an academic department, with that in the competitive PMO or the Illyrian firm, we have found that some goods (e.g., graduate education and research) will be ‘overproduced’ by the NPO, way beyond the point where total or per capita profits are maximized, because of the positive utility which they yield, often on a ‘collective goods’ basis, to the NPO managers. On the other hand, profitable products that yield negative utility will be ‘underproduced’ relative to the PMO and (as in the Illyrian firm but for a different reason) may have a backward-bending supply curve and an unstable equilibrium. This may be the case for undergraduate instruction. Attempts to increase the quantity of such products by increasing lump sum revenues or price may actually have a contrary effect.

We have also found that input-output relationships or total and marginal costs of each product, may be treated as choice variables, entering into the objective function, rather than as exogenously determined technological constraints. Moreover, interdependencies among activities exist for a multi-product NPO such as an academic department, even if production and demand functions are completely separable.

In general, since the choice of product mix and factor mix depends on subjective utility functions of the faculty-managers, these may vary from one department to another and the response to parametric changes may also vary. This means that the central administration at the university or the state planner overseeing it is clearly limited in his ability to influence resource allocation when decisions about product and factor mix are in the hands of the departmental non-profit collective. If the planner wishes to achieve his ends by manipulating the incentive structure facing the department, rather than by direct controls, he must first understand which activities are regarded by the faculty-managers as production, which are utility-yielding consumption, and which are a mixture of production and negative consumption. The group decision process, cycling possibilities, and monitoring and enforcement impediments further complicate the situation. Unless he is aware of these difficulties, he may find income effects, backward-bending supply curves, nonzero cross elasticities, intransitivities and free-rider problems that were not predicted by the traditional theory of the firm and that may yield an input-output mix which differs from his expectations or intent.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Similar content being viewed by others

References

  • Alchian, A., and Demsetz, H. (1972). Production, information costs, and economic organization. American Economic Review 62: 777–795.

    Google Scholar 

  • Alchian, A., and Kessel, R. (1962). Competition, monopoly and the pursuit of pecuniary gain. In Aspects of labor economics. Princeton: NBER.

    Google Scholar 

  • Balderston, F. (1974). Managing today's university. San Francisco: Jossey-Bass.

    Google Scholar 

  • Baumol, W.J. (1959). Business behavior, value and growth. New York: Macmillan.

    Google Scholar 

  • Baumol, W., and Bowen, W. (1966). Performing arts — The economic dilemma. New York: Twentieth Century Fund.

    Google Scholar 

  • Ben Ner, A., and Neuberger, E. (1979). On the economics of self-management: The Israeli kibbutz and the Yugoslav enterprise. Economic Analysis and Workers' Management 13: 47–71.

    Google Scholar 

  • Breneman, D.W. (1971). An economic theory of Ph.D. production. Berkeley: Ford Foundation Program for Research in University Administration, Report P-8.

    Google Scholar 

  • Clarkson, K. (1972). Some implications of property rights in hospital management. Journal of Law and Economics 15: 363–385.

    Google Scholar 

  • Domar, E. (1966). The Soviet collective farm. American Economic Review 56: 734–757.

    Google Scholar 

  • Freeman, R. (1973). Demand for labor in a nonprofit market. University Faculty. Discussion Paper 300, Harvard Institute of Economic Research.

  • Furubotn, E. (1976). The long-run analysis of the labor-managed firm: An alternative interpretation. American Economic Review 66: 104–123.

    Google Scholar 

  • Ginzberg, E., Hiestand, D.L., and Reubens, B.J. (1965). The pluralist economy. New York: McGraw-Hill.

    Google Scholar 

  • Graaf, J. V. de (1950–51). Income effects and the theory of the firm. Review of Economic Studies 18: 54–86.

    Google Scholar 

  • James, E. (1978). Product mix and cost disaggregation: A reinterpretation of the economics of higher education. Journal of Human Resources 13: 157–186.

    Google Scholar 

  • James, E. (1979). A contribution to the theory of the non-profit organization. Presented at the Conference on Institutional Choice, Madison, Wisconsin.

  • James, E. (1980). Job-based lending and insurance: Wage structure in tenurian labor markets. Discussion Paper No. 12-80 Pinkas Sapir Center for Development, Tel-Aviv University.

  • Layard, R., and Jackman, K. (1973). University efficiency and university finance. In M. Paskin (Ed.), Essays in modern economics. London: Longman.

    Google Scholar 

  • Leibenstein, H. (1979). ‘The missing link’ — micro-micro theory? Journal of Economic Literature 17: 477–503.

    Google Scholar 

  • Neuberger, E., and Duffy, W.J. (1976). Comparative economic systems: A decision-making approach. Boston: Allyn and Bacon.

    Google Scholar 

  • Neuberger, E., and James, E. (1973). The Yugoslav self-managed enterprise. In M. Bornstein (Ed.), Plan and market: Economic reform in eastern Europe. New Haven: Yale University Press. 245–284.

    Google Scholar 

  • Newhouse, J.P. (1970). Toward a theory of nonprofit institutions: An economic model of a hospital. American Economic Review 60: 64–75.

    Google Scholar 

  • O'Donoghue, M. (1971). Economic dimensions in education. Chicago: Aldine.

    Google Scholar 

  • Pauly, M., and Redisch, M. (1973). The not-for-profit hospital as a physician's cooperative. American Economic Review 63: 87–100.

    Google Scholar 

  • Scitovsky, T. (1943). A note on profit maximization and its implications. Review of Economic Studies 11: 57–60.

    Google Scholar 

  • Vanek, J. (1970). The general theory of labor-managed market economies. Ithaca: Cornell University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Ward, B. (1958). The firm in Illyria: Market syndicalism. American Economic Review 48: 566–589.

    Google Scholar 

  • Weisbrod, B. (1975). Toward a theory of the voluntary non-profit sector in a three-sector economy. In E. Phelps (Ed.), Altruism, morality, and economic theory. N.Y.: Russel Sage Foundation. 171–195.

    Google Scholar 

  • Weisbrod, B. (1977). The voluntary non-profit sector. Lexington, Mass.: Heath and Co.

    Google Scholar 

  • Williamson, O. (1967). The economics of discretionary behavior. Chicago: Markham.

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Cite this article

James, E., Neuberger, E. The university department as a non-profit labor cooperative. Public Choice 36, 585–612 (1981). https://doi.org/10.1007/BF00128741

Download citation

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/BF00128741

Keywords

Navigation