Skip to main content
Log in

How disclosure quality affects the level of information asymmetry

  • Published:
Review of Accounting Studies Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

We examine two potential mechanisms through which disclosure quality is expected to reduce information asymmetry: (1) altering the trading incentives of informed and uninformed investors so that there is relatively less trading by privately informed investors, and (2) reducing the likelihood that investors discover and trade on private information. Our results indicate that the negative relation between disclosure quality and information asymmetry is primarily caused by the latter mechanism. While information asymmetry is negatively associated with the quality of the annual report and investor relations activities, it is positively associated with quarterly report disclosure quality. Additionally, we hypothesize and find that that the negative association between disclosure quality and information asymmetry is stronger in settings characterized by higher levels of firm-investor asymmetry.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1
Fig. 2

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. In addition, prior studies commonly rely on the closing bid-ask spread. However, Madhavan, Richardson, and Roomans (1997) show that adverse selection costs decrease throughout the day, which suggests that the closing spread is a relatively weak proxy for information asymmetry.

  2. The PIN methodology is used frequently in the finance literature and has been used by Botosan and Plumlee (2004), Brown, Hillegeist, and Lo (2004) and Hillary (2006) in the accounting literature.

  3. The level of firm-investor information asymmetry is only relevant to the extent that it increases asymmetry among investors, such as through insider trading.

  4. Also see Fama and Laffer (1971) and Hakansson (1977) for settings where public disclosure deters traders from expending resources on information collection for speculative purposes.

  5. In assuming that the type of news is unambiguous, the EKO model does not allow for both informed buying and selling on the same day, as in Kim and Verrecchia (1991); private information is one-sided, as in Kyle (1985). In addition, the precision of the private information (vis-à-vis the precision of the public information) does not matter since informed traders are assumed to be risk neutral.

  6. The model ignores the size of each trade order. While this simplifying assumption likely results in the loss of some information, the reduction may be minor as informed investors disguise their information by mimicking the trade sizes of uninformed traders (Barclay & Warner, 1993; Chakravarty, 2001). Also, see Jones, Kaul, and Lipson (1994).

  7. The Inverse Gaussian distribution has mean =[W t ] = 1 and \({\hbox{variance}=\hbox{Var}[W_{t}]=(1/\psi^{2})}\). As the variance of the daily scaling factor W t approaches zero (or equivalently, as ψ approaches infinity), W becomes a constant equal to one. When this occurs, the extended model simply reduces to the basic EKO model. In our sample, the median (95th percentile) value of ψ is 2.7 (4.1), and only four observations have values of ψ > 8. Thus, the extended model fits the trade order data significantly better than the basic EKO model.

  8. This estimation procedure assumes that the underlying information environment, and hence parameters, remains relatively stable over an annual period. Easley et al. (2002) conclude that this assumption is reasonable as individual stocks exhibit relatively low variability in PINs across years and the cross-sectional distribution of PIN is quite stable across time. In addition, they estimated PINs using rolling 60 day sample periods and found them to be quite similar to the annual estimates. Thus, we conclude that it is reasonable to estimate PINs over an annual period.

  9. Prior studies using the AIMR disclosure scores include Botosan and Plumlee (2002), Gelb and Zarowin (2002), Healy et al. (1999), Lang and Lundholm (1993), Lang and Lundholm (1996), Lundholm and Myers (2002), Sengupta (1998), and Welker (1995). Detailed discussions of the AIMR rating process and the disclosure scores can be found in Lang and Lundholm (1993) and Healy et al. (1999).

  10. Despite these potential difficulties, we also conduct a 3SLS analysis as an alternative methodological approach. The results from this approach are consistent with our main results and are discussed in Sect. 5.6.

  11. Lang and Lundholm (1993) use the signed values of Return and Surprise rather than the absolute values. Using signed values does not alter our results qualitatively.

  12. We measure Size, InstOwn, and Owners at the end of the fiscal year as an estimate of the average level of these variables during the annual measurement periods for PIN and the AIMR scores.

  13. Consistent with heterogeneity among institutional investors, Brown et al. (2004) find that the association between institutional ownership and PIN changes from quarter to quarter.

  14. However, Jiambalvo et al. (2002) find that the number of analysts is negatively related to the extent that prices reflect future earnings, which suggests that analyst following is negatively related to the amount of informed trading.

  15. The fraction of privately informed trades on information event days = \({\nu/(\nu+2)=0.89/2.89 \approx 0.31.}\)

  16. There are four extreme values where the estimated value of ψ is around 2,000—a corner solution that occurs when the basic EKO model describes the underlying trade data reasonably well. However, diagnostic tests confirm that these cases do not result in extreme estimates of PIN or the PIN parameters.

  17. All reported t-statistics are based on clustered standard errors where outliers based on abs(dfits) >0.1 are eliminated (Belsley, Kuh, & Welsch, 1980).

  18. While Brown et al. (2004) report a significantly positive coefficient on institutional ownership in their pooled sample where PIN is estimated using the basic EKO model, institutional ownership has a significantly negative coefficient in several of their quarterly regressions.

  19. The correlation between Analysts and Size is also quite large (0.69), and this multi-collinearity could also be responsible for the lack of significance for Analysts.

  20. Malkiel and Radisich (2001) report that throughout the 1990s, 30% of institutionally managed assets were indexed, suggesting that a substantial amount of institutional trading was not based on private information.

  21. In comparing a small group of high- and low-analyst firms, Easley et al. (1998) provides univariate evidence that both uninformed and informed trading is higher in the high-analyst group than in the low-analyst group. However, they do not discuss or analyze the ratio of the two variables.

  22. Botosan and Plumlee (2002) also find a negative association between annual report quality and the estimated cost of equity capital, consistent with the negative PrAnnual coefficient we report here. However, they do not find a significant association with the IR score, in contrast with the significantly negative association we find here.

  23. The levels of statistical significance that we find on the PrQuarterly and PrIR coefficients are somewhat sensitive to deletion of outliers. However, in all cases the coefficients are negative in the ɛ and μ equation and in no case were they significantly different from zero (or from each other) in the ν equation.

  24. This supports our decision to treat the relation between them as endogenous. Untabulated results indicate that the PIN coefficient is significantly positive in the disclosure quality regression. Accordingly, we infer that managers take the level of information asymmetry into account when they make their disclosure quality choices.

  25. They also find that the negative association between the number of management forecasts and information asymmetry is significantly stronger in the post-Regulation FD period.

References

  • Aboody, D., & Lev, B. (2000). Information asymmetry, R&D, and insider gains. Journal of Finance, 55, 2747–2766.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ajinkya, B. B., & Gift, M. J. (1984). Corporate managers’ earnings forecasts and symmetrical adjustments of market expectations. Journal of Accounting Research, 22, 425–444.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Atiase, R. K. (1985). Predisclosure information, firm capitalization, and security price behavior around earnings announcements. Journal of Accounting Research, 23, 21–36.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ayers, B. C., & Freeman, R. N. (2001). Evidence that price leads of earnings increase with analyst following and institutional ownership. University of Georgia working paper.

  • Barclay, M. J., & Warner, J. B. (1993). Stealth trading and volatility: Which trades move prices. Journal of Financial Economics, 34, 281–305.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Barth, M. E., Kasznik, R., & McNichols, M. F. (2001). Analyst coverage and intangible assets. Journal of Accounting Research, 39, 1–34.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Belsley, D. A., Kuh, E., & Welsch, R. E. (1980). Regression diagnostics: Identifying influential data and sources of collinearity. New York: John Wiley.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bollen, N. P. B., & Busse, J. (2005). Short-term persistence in mutual fund performance. Review of Financial Studies, 18, 569–597.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Boot, A. W. A., & Thakor, A. V. (1993). Security design. Journal of Finance, 48, 1349–1378.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Botosan, C. A. (1997). Disclosure level and the cost of equity capital. Accounting Review, 72, 323–349.

    Google Scholar 

  • Botosan, C. A., & Plumlee, M. A. (2002). A re-examination of disclosure level and the expected cost of equity capital. Journal of Accounting Research, 40, 21–40.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Botosan, C. A., & Plumlee, M. A. (2004). Are information attributes priced? University of Utah working paper.

  • Brown, S., Hillegeist, S. A., & Lo, K. (2003). Regulation FD and voluntary disclosure practices. Northwestern University working paper.

  • Brown, S., Hillegeist, S. A., & Lo, K. (2004). Conference calls and information asymmetry. Journal of Accounting & Economics, 37, 343–366.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Brown, S., Hillegeist, S. A., & Lo, K. (2005) Management forecasts and litigation risk. INSEAD working paper.

  • Brown, S., Hillegeist, S. A., Lo, K. (2006) The effect of meeting or missing earnings expectations of information asymmetry. University of British Columbia working paper.

  • Bushee, B. J. (1998). The influence of institutional investors on myopic R&D investment behavior. Accounting Review, 73, 305–333.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bushee, B. J., Matsumoto, D. A., & Miller, G. S. (2003). Open versus closed conference calls: The determinants and effects of broadening access to disclosure. Journal of Accounting & Economics, 34, 149–180.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bushee, B., & Noe, C. (2000). Corporate disclosure practices, institutional investors, and stock return volatility. Journal of Accounting Research, 38, 171–202.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Callahan, C. M., Lee, C. M. C., & Yohn, T. L. (1997). Accounting information and bid-ask spreads. Accounting Horizons, 11, 50–60.

    Google Scholar 

  • Chakravarty, S. (2001). Stealth-trading: Which traders’ trades move stock prices. Journal of Financial Economics, 61, 289–307.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cohen, D. (2003). Quality of financial reporting choice: Determinants and economic consequences. Northwestern University working paper.

  • Coller, M., & Yohn, T. L. (1997). Management forecasts and information asymmetry: An examination of bid-ask spreads. Journal of Accounting Research, 35, 181–191.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Diamond, D. W. (1985). Optimal release of information by firms. Journal of Finance, 40, 828–862.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Diamond, D. W., & Verrecchia, R. E. (1991). Disclosure, liquidity, and the cost of capital. Journal of Finance, 46, 1325–1360.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Easley, D., Hvidkjaer, S., & O’Hara, M. (2002). Is information risk a determinant of asset returns? Journal of Finance, 57, 2185–2221.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Easley, D., Hvidkjaer, S., & O’Hara, M. (2004). Factoring information into returns. Cornell University working paper.

  • Easley, D., Kiefer, N. M., & O’Hara, M. (1997). One day in the life of a very common stock. Review of Financial Studies, 10, 805–835.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Easley, D., O’Hara, M., & Paperman, J. B. (1998). Financial analysts and information-based trade. Journal of Financial Markets, 1, 175–201.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fama, E. F., & Laffer, A. B. (1971). Information and capital markets. Journal of Business, 44, 289–298.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • FASC. (1998). Criteria for assessing the quality of an accounting standard. Accounting Horizons, 12, 161–162.

    Google Scholar 

  • FASB. (2001). Improving business reporting: Insights into enhancing voluntary disclosures. Financial Accounting Standards Board's Business Reporting Research Project. Norwalk, CT.

  • Fishman, M. J., & Hagerty, K. M. (1989). Disclosure decisions by firms and the competition for price efficiency. Journal of Finance, 44, 633–646.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Francis, J., LaFond, R., Olsson, P. M., & Schipper, K. (2005). The market pricing of accruals quality. Journal of Accounting & Economics, 39, 295–327.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Frankel, R., McNichols, M., & Wilson, G. P. (1995). Discretionary disclosure and external financing. Accounting Review, 70, 135–150.

    Google Scholar 

  • Gelb, D. S., & Zarowin, P. (2002). Corporate disclosure policy and the informativeness of stock prices. Review of Accounting Studies, 7, 33–52.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hakansson, N. (1977). Interim disclosure and public forecasts: An economic analysis and framework for choice. Accounting Review, 52, 396–416.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hausman, J. A. (1978). Specification tests in econometrics. Econometrica, 46, 1251–1271.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Healy, P., Hutton, A., & Palepu, K. (1999). Stock performance and intermediation changes surrounding sustained increases in disclosures. Contemporary Accounting Research, 16, 485–520.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Heflin, F., Shaw, K. W., & Wild, J. J. (2005). Disclosure policy and market liquidity: Impact of depth quotes and order sizes. Contemporary Accounting Research, 22, 829–866.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hillary, G. (2006). Organized labor and information asymmetry in the financial markets. Review of Accounting Studies, 11, 525–548.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Jiambalvo, J., Rajgopal, S., & Venkatachalam, M. (2002). Institutional ownership and the extent to which stock prices reflect future earnings. Contemporary Accounting Research, 19, 117–145.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Jiang, G., Lee, C. M. C., & Zhang, Y. (2005). Information uncertainty and expected returns. Review of Accounting Studies, 10, 185–222.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Jones, C. M., Kaul, G., & Lipson, M. L. (1994). Transactions, volume, and volatility. Review of Financial Studies, 7, 631–651.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ke, B., Ramalingegowda, S., & Yu, Y. (2006). The effect of investment horizon on institutional investors’ incentive to acquire private information on long-term earnings. Pennsylvania State University working paper.

  • Kim, O., & Verrecchia, R. E. (1991). Market reaction to anticipated announcements. Journal of Financial Economics, 30, 273–309.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kyle, A. (1985). Continuous auctions and insider trading. Econometrica, 53, 1315–1335.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lang, M. H., & Lundholm, R. J. (1993) Cross-sectional determinants of analyst ratings of corporate disclosures. Journal of Accounting Research, 31, 246–271.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lang, M. H., & Lundholm, R. J. (1996). Corporate disclosure policy and analyst behavior. Accounting Review, 71, 467–492.

    Google Scholar 

  • Lee, C. M. C., Mucklow, B., & Ready, M. (1994). Spreads, depths, and the impact of earnings information: An intraday analysis. Review of Financial Studies, 6, 345–374.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lee, C. M. C., & Ready, M. J. (1991). Inferring trade direction from intraday data. Journal of Finance, 46, 733–747.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Leuz, C., & Verrecchia, R. (2000). The economic consequences of increased disclosure. Journal of Accounting Research, 38, 91–124.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Levitt, A. (1998). The importance of high quality accounting standards. Accounting Horizons, 12, 79–82.

    Google Scholar 

  • Lundholm, R. J., & Myers, L. (2002). Bringing the future forward: The effect of disclosure on the returns-earnings relation. Journal of Accounting Research, 40, 809–839.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Maddala, G. S. (1983). Limited-dependent and qualitative variables in econometrics. New York, NY: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Madhavan, A., Richardson, M., & Roomans, M. (1997). Why do securities prices change? A transaction-level analysis of NYSE stocks. Review of Financial Studies, 10, 1035–1064.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Malkiel, B., & Radisich, A. (2001). The growth of index funds and the pricing of equity securities. Journal of Portfolio Management, 27(2), 8–21.

    Google Scholar 

  • Marquardt, C. A., & Wiedman, C. I. (1998). Voluntary disclosure, information asymmetry, and insider selling through secondary equity offerings. Contemporary Accounting Research, 15, 505–537.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Merton, R. C. (1987). A simple model of capital market equilibrium with incomplete information. Journal of Finance, 42, 483–510.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • O’Hara, M. (1995). Market microstructure theory. Malden, MA: Blackwell Publishers, Ltd.

    Google Scholar 

  • Piotroski, J., & Roulstone, D. (2005). The influence of analysts, institutional investors, and insiders on the incorporation of market, industry, and firm-specific information into stock prices. Accounting Review, 79, 1119–1151.

    Google Scholar 

  • Sengupta, P. (1998). Corporate disclosure quality and the cost of debt. Accounting Review, 73, 459–474.

    Google Scholar 

  • Stein, G., Zucchini, W., & Juritz, M. (1987). Parameter estimation for the Sichel distribution and its multivariate extension. Journal of the American Statistical Association, 82, 938–944.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Venter, J. H., & de Jongh, D. C. J. (2004). Extending the EKOP model to estimate the probability of informed trading. Proceedings of first african finance conference.

  • Verrecchia, R. E. (1982). The use of mathematical models in financial accounting. Journal of Accounting Research, 20, 1–46.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Waymire, G. (1985). Earnings volatility and voluntary management forecast disclosure. Journal of Accounting Research, 23, 268–295.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Welker, M. (1995). Disclosure policy, information asymmetry, and liquidity in equity markets. Contemporary Accounting Research, 11, 801–827.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Wooldridge, J. (2002). Econometric analysis of cross section and panel data. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Yan, X., & Zhang, Z. (2006). Institutional investors and equity returns: Are short-term institutions better informed? Review of Financial Studies, forthcoming.

  • Zhang, G. (2001). Private information production, public disclosure, and the cost of capital: Theory and implications. Contemporary Accounting Research, 18, 363–384.

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgements

This paper has benefited from the comments and suggestions of Eli Bartov, Sudipta Basu, George Benston, Tarun Chordia, Yonca Ertimur, Paul Fischer, Simon Gervais, Wayne Guay, Frank Heflin, Ole-Kristian Hope, Ravi Jagannathan, Stephen Monahan, Joseph Paperman, Gideon Sarr, Yong-Chul Shin, Sri Sridhar, Beverly Walther, Greg Waymire, and seminar participants at the University of Chicago, Emory University, Georgia State University, the University of Illinois at Chicago, the University of Michigan, the University of Minnesota, New York University, Northwestern University, and conference participants at the 4th Winter Accounting Conference (University of Utah) and the 2006 Review of Accounting Studies Conference (INSEAD) and anonymous referees. The second author gratefully acknowledges the financial support of the Accounting Research Center at Northwestern University. We thank Mark Finn for his efforts on an earlier version of this paper; Christine Botosan, Russell Lundholm, Marlene Plumlee, and Mark Soszek for supplying the AIMR scores; IBES for making available the analyst forecast data; and Hennie Venter for assistance in implementing the extension of the EKO model.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Stephen A. Hillegeist.

Appendix: Venter and de Jongh (2004) Extension of EKO model

Appendix: Venter and de Jongh (2004) Extension of EKO model

The extended EKO model allows for the daily level of trading intensity to vary with a daily trading intensity factor, W t . The distribution of buys (B) and sells (S) on day t is given by

  • (B t , S t ) | no-news, W t ∼ Independent Bivariate Poisson (ɛW t , ɛW t )

  • (B t , S t ) | bad-news, W t ∼ Independent Bivariate Poisson (ɛW t , ɛ(1 + ν)W t )

  • (B t , S t ) | good-news, W t ∼ Independent Bivariate Poisson (ɛ(1 + ν)W t , ɛW t ).

The likelihood function induced by the model for a trading day, conditional on the Poisson trading intensities λ Bt and λ St for buys and sells, respectively, is given by:

$$ L_t(B_t ,S_t \vert \lambda_{Bt},\lambda_{St})=f_{POISS}(B_t,S_t\vert \lambda _{Bt},\lambda _{St})=\frac{(\lambda _{Bt})^{B_t}}{B_t!}\ast \frac{(\lambda_{St})^{S_t}}{S_t !}\ast e^{-\lambda_{Bt}-\lambda _{St}}. $$
(A1)

The overall likelihood function is a “mixture” model where the weights on the three components (no news, bad news, and good news) reflect the probabilities of their occurrence in the data. Denote the trading intensity associated with a no-news day (uninformed traders only) by \({\lambda_{Nt}=\varepsilon W_{t}}\) and the joint informed and uninformed trading intensity by \({\lambda_{It}= \varepsilon(1+\nu)W_{t}}\). Thus:

$$ \begin{aligned} \;&L_t(B_t ,S_t \vert \lambda_{Nt},\lambda _{It} )=L_t (B_t,S_t\vert \varepsilon ,\mu ,W_t)\\ &= (1-\alpha )f_{POISS} (B_t ,S_t \vert \lambda _{Nt} ,\lambda _{Nt} )+\alpha \delta f_{POISS} (B_t ,S_t \vert \lambda _{Nt} ,\lambda _{It} )+\alpha (1-\delta )f_{POISS} (B_t ,S_t \vert \lambda _{It} ,\lambda_{Nt})\\ &=(1-\alpha)\frac{\lambda _{Nt}^{^{B_t}}}{B_t!}\ast \frac{\lambda _{Nt}^{^{S_t}}}{S_t !}\ast e^{(-2\lambda _{Nt})}+\alpha \delta \frac{\lambda _{Nt}^{^{B_t }}}{B_t !}\ast \frac{\lambda _{It}^{^{S_t}} }{S_t!}\ast e^{(-\lambda _{Nt}-\lambda _{It})}+\alpha (1-\delta )\frac{\lambda _{It}^{^{B_t }}}{B_t !}\ast \frac{\lambda _{Nt}^{^{S_t}} }{S_t!}\ast e^{(-\lambda _{It}-\lambda _{Nt})}. \end{aligned} $$
(A2)

The random variable W is assumed to have a unit inverse Gaussian distribution with parameter ψ > 0. The density function of W is given by

$$ f_{UIG} (w;\psi )=\frac{\psi \hbox{exp}(\psi^2)}{\sqrt{2\pi} }w^{-\frac{3}{2}}\hbox{exp}\left(-\frac{1}{2}\psi^2(w^{-1}+w)\right),\quad w > 0. $$
(A3)

The expected value of this distribution is equal to one and the variance is equal to (1/ψ2). Thus, as ψ→∞, the variance in daily trading intensities induced by general market conditions goes to zero and the extended model reduces to the basic EKO model.

The distributional assumption for W implies that the joint distribution of B t and S t is given by a multivariate Poisson inverse Gaussian distribution (Stein, Zucchini, & Juritz, 1987). If λ12) is the base level of trading intensity for buys (sells) on a particular day (i.e., λ Bt  = W t λ1 and λ St  = W t λ2), then the likelihood function for observing the mixed Poisson distribution of B t buys and S t sells is:

$$ \begin{aligned} f_{PIG} =f_{PIG}(B_t ,S_t \vert \lambda_1,\lambda _2 ,\psi)=\\ \frac{(\lambda_{1})^{B_{t}}}{B_{t}!}*\frac{(\lambda_{2})^{S_{t}}} {S_{t}!}*{\left[{\frac{\psi^{2}}{{\psi^{2}+2{\left({\lambda_{1}+ \lambda_{2}}\right)}}}}\right]}^{{\frac{B_{t}+S_{t}}{2}}}{*e}(\psi^{2}- \psi\sqrt{(\psi^{2}+2(\lambda_{1}+\lambda_{2}))} *\hat{{\mathbf K}} _{\left(B_{t}+S_{t}-\frac{1}{2}\right)}\left(\psi\sqrt{(\psi^{2}+2(\lambda_{1}+\lambda_{2}))}\right) \end{aligned} $$
(A4)

where \({\mathop{\mathbf K}\limits^\wedge{}_{n}(z)={K_n (z)}\mathord{\left/ {\vphantom {{K_n(z)}{K_{0.5} (z)}}}\right. K_{0.5}(z)}}\) and K n (z) is the modified Bessel function of the second kind. Then, the expectation of B t is given by \({\hbox{E}[B_{t}]=\hbox{E}[B_{t}\vert W_{t}]=\hbox{E}[\lambda_{1} W_{t}]=\lambda_{1}}\) and \({\hbox{Var}(B_{t})=\lambda_{1} +(\lambda _{1}/\psi^{2});}\) similarly for S t . The covariance of B t and S t is given by \({\hbox{Cov}(B_{t},S_{t})=(\lambda_{1}\lambda_{2})/\psi^{2}}\). Therefore, the expected values of B t and S t are given by λ1 and λ2—as in the basic EKO model. However, in the extended model, if \({\psi\ne\infty}\), then the dispersions of B t and S t are higher than those in the EKO model and the daily values of buys and sells are positively correlated. Therefore, the full likelihood function is given by

$$ \begin{aligned} &L_t (B_t ,S_t \vert \alpha ,\delta ,\psi ,\varepsilon ,\nu )=\\ &(1-\alpha )f_{PIG} (B_t ,S_t \vert \varepsilon ,\varepsilon ,\psi)+\alpha \delta f_{PIG} (B_t ,S_t \vert \varepsilon ,\varepsilon (1+\nu),\psi )+\alpha (1-\delta )f_{PIG} (B_t ,S_t \vert \varepsilon (1+\nu),\varepsilon ,\psi ). \end{aligned} $$
(A5)

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Cite this article

Brown, S., Hillegeist, S.A. How disclosure quality affects the level of information asymmetry. Rev Acc Stud 12, 443–477 (2007). https://doi.org/10.1007/s11142-007-9032-5

Download citation

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s11142-007-9032-5

Keywords

JEL Classifications

Navigation