Skip to main content
Log in

The Impact of Downward Rating Momentum

  • Published:
Journal of Financial Services Research Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

Rating downgrades are known to make subsequent downgrades more likely. We analyze the impact of this “downward momentum” on credit portfolio risk and bond portfolio management. Using Standard&Poor’s ratings from 1996 to 2005, we apply a novel approach to estimate a transition matrix that is sensitive to previous downgrades and contrast it with an insensitive benchmark matrix. First, we find that, under representative economic conditions, investors who rely on insensitive transition matrices underestimate the momentum-sensitive Value-at-Risk (VaR), on average, by 107 basis points. Second, we show that bond portfolio managers should use our downgrade-sensitive probabilities of default as they seem to be better calibrated than momentum-insensitive estimates.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1
Fig. 2
Fig. 3
Fig. 4
Fig. 5
Fig. 6

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. There are further factors which would appear to influence transition probabilities: time since issuance of a bond, business sector, and issuer’s domicile. However, these factors are of rather minor importance.

  2. Mählmann (2006) and Krüger et al. (2005) find no evidence of downward momentum for internal ratings and a sample of purely scoring-based ratings.

  3. An additional reason might be that we include non-US domiciled companies in our sample. These companies experienced many downgrades during our observation period.

  4. The “R” rating indicates that an obligor is under regulatory supervision owing to its financial condition. Using D, SD and R ratings as defaults, we follow the approach used by S&P in its annual default reports (e.g. S&P 2007).

  5. The choice of five-day intervals as opposed to daily observations serves to reduce computational burden and does not alter our results qualitatively. Longer intervals should be taken with care.

  6. In our example, a rating b proves to be non-excited if it has been stable over the previous two periods or if the last rating change within theses two periods has been an upgrade. If that change was a downgrade, however, state b1 or b2 is assigned, depending on the time elapsed since the downgrade.

  7. A brute-force matrix approach would lead to very large matrices of which high powers would have to be calculated. To avoid such effort, we exploit the facts that many matrix elements are zero and that many of the non-zero elements are identical.

  8. If the hidden-Markov model is used for portfolio simulation, given a certain bond with a certain time since its last downgrade (and no rating change since), it is not known whether the bond is still excited. There is some probability of excitement. Consequently, before the simulation can start, transition probabilities for this bond must be calculated that are a function of its current rating and the time since its last downgrade, just as in our approach.

  9. Importance sampling is based on a change of measure. Applying this idea to the calculation of extreme quantiles such as the 99.9% VaR means performing simulations not under the valid probability law but under another law that has more mass around the range of interest. The distortion is corrected for by giving the simulation draws different weights. Concretely, we replace the N(0,1) distribution of the single systematic factor by a N(–3,1) distribution. For an introduction to importance sampling, see Glasserman (2004).

  10. Refer to “Section 4.1” for an explanation of this finding.

  11. We find a smooth, but non-linear, development of the PDs from newly downgraded to unexcited bonds. Results are not shown but are available upon request.

  12. This counterintuitive finding may result from the small number of excited rating observations in these two rating classes.

  13. Christensen et al. (2004) already find, in some rating classes, unconditional PDs that are smaller than non-excited and excited PDs but they do not explain this finding.

  14. Zeng and Zhang (2001) employ a data set of weekly returns for more than 27,000 firms from 40 countries covering the period 1988−1996. Our base case asset correlation is the mean value from Zeng and Zhang’s sub-sample of firms with the fewest missing weekly returns. It is close to the “representative” asset correlation of 20% that is used, for example, by Löffler (2003) and Kupiec (2007). It is also in the range of correlations reported by Grundke (2007), who gives a comprehensive survey of correlation estimates.

  15. We thus assume independence between the LGD and our transition probabilities. Refer to Kupiec (2008) for how a non-zero correlation between the LGD and the PD affects credit portfolio risk in the Vasicek one-factor model.

  16. Simulation in rating class CCC begins in 1999 because there were too few observations in the years 1996-1998 to build a portfolio of 100 bonds (without relying on multiple draws of bonds from one company, which we opt to avoid).

  17. Additionally, bond portfolio managers might be interested in the momentum-sensitive probabilities for investment-grade rated bonds to become downgraded to junk bond status because, in these instances, bond prices suffer heavily. However, differences between momentum-sensitive and insensitive are not substantial.

  18. A popular measure for discriminatory power, the area under the ROC curve, where higher values signify a higher power, does not show a significant difference between the momentum-sensitive PDs (91.5%) and the insensitive PDs (91%), but at least, we do not lose power in this dimension.

  19. For instance, Krämer and Güttler (2008) use the Brier score to compare ratings from Moody’s and S&P.

  20. We do not differentiate excited one-period transition probabilities according to τ. Note, however, that τ does influence transition probabilities over longer horizons, e.g. annual probabilities. Our decision is motivated mainly by insufficient data for a more detailed estimation.

References

  • Altman EI, Kao DL (1992) The implications of corporate bond ratings drift. Financ Anal J 48:64–67

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Altman EI, Kishore VM (1996) Almost everything you wanted to know about recoveries on defaulted bonds. Financ Anal J 52:57–64

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bangia A, Diebold F, Kronimus A, Schagen C, Schuermann T (2002) Ratings migration and the business cycle, with applications to credit portfolio stress testing. J Bank Finance 26:445–474

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • BCBS (2006) International convergence of capital measurement and capital standards. A revised framework. Comprehensive version

  • Blume ME, Lim F, MacKinlay AC (1998) The declining credit quality of U.S. corporate debt: Myth or reality? J Finance 53:1389–1414

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Christensen JHE, Hansen E, Lando D (2004) Confidence sets for continuous-time rating transition probabilities. J Bank Finance 28:2575–2602

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Glasserman P (2004) Monte Carlo methods in financial engineering. Springer, New York

    Google Scholar 

  • Grundke P (2007) Regulatory treatment of the double default effect under the New Basel Accord: how conservative is it? Working Paper, University of Cologne

  • Gupton GM, Finger CC, Bhatia M (1997) CreditMetrics technical document. J.P. Morgan

  • Hanson S, Schuermann T (2006) Confidence intervals for probabilities of default. J Bank Finance 30:2281–2301

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Krämer W, Güttler A (2008) On comparing the accuracy of default predictions in the rating industry. Empir Econ 34:343–356

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Krüger U, Stötzel M, Trück S (2005) Time series properties of a rating system based on financial ratios. Deutsche Bundesbank Discussion Paper

  • Kupiec PH (2007) Capital allocation for portfolio credit risk. J Finan Serv Res 32:103–122

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kupiec PH (2008) A generalized single common factor model of portfolio credit risk. J Derivatives 15:25–40

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kuritzkes A, Schuermann T, Weiner SM (2005) Deposit insurance and risk management of the US banking system: What is the loss distribution faced by the FDIC? J Finan Serv Res 27:217–242

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lando D, Skødeberg TM (2002) Analyzing rating transitions and rating drift with continuous observations. J Bank Finance 26:423–444

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Löffler G (2003) The effects of estimation error on measures of portfolio credit risk. J Bank Finance 27:1427–1453

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lopez JA (2004) The empirical relationship between average asset correlation, firm probability of default, and asset size. J Financ Intermed 13:265–283

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mählmann T (2006) Estimation of rating class transition probabilities with incomplete data. J Bank Finance 30:3235–3256

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Merton RC (1974) On the pricing of corporate debt: The risk structure of interest rates. J Finance 29:449–470

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Nickell P, Perraudin W, Varotto S (2000) Stability of rating transitions. J Bank Finance 24:203–227

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Redelmeier DA, Block DA, Hickam DH (1991) Assessing predictive accuracy: How to compare Brier scores. J Clin Epidemiol 44:1141–1164

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • S&P (2007) Annual 2006 global corporate default study and ratings transitions

  • Zeng B, Zhang J (2001) An empirical assessment of asset correlation models. KMV Working Paper

Download references

Acknowledgments

We thank the editor Paul Kupiec, an anonymous referee, Albert L. Chun, Klaus Düllmann, Axel Eisenkopf, Ulrich Krüger and participants at the annual meeting of the German Academic Association for Business Research, the German Finance Association, and the Swiss Society for Financial Market Research for their helpful comments. All errors and opinions expressed in this paper are, of course, our own. Financial support from the E-Finance Lab Frankfurt is gratefully acknowledged.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Andre Güttler.

Additional information

The opinions expressed in this paper are the personal opinions of the authors and do not necessarily reflect the views of the Deutsche Bundesbank.

Appendices

Appendix I: General modeling framework

Let \( \left\{ {1,...,N} \right\} \) be the set of ratings where 1 denotes the best rating and N the default state, which we formally consider a rating. Time t is measured in discrete periods, which are 5 days long in our application. For a given time t (in periods), let τ t be the time evolved since the last rating change if that was a downgrade and if it is not more than ε periods ago. If more time has elapsed since or if the last transition was an upgrade or if the rating was stable throughout, set \( {\tau_t} \equiv {\text{nex}} \), where the abstract element nex represents the non-excited state. To reconcile rating downward momentum with the Markov property, we formally extend the state space from \( \left\{ {1,...,N} \right\} \) to \( \left\{ {1,...,N} \right\} \times \left\{ {1,...,\varepsilon, {\text{nex}}} \right\} \), where \( \left\{ {1,...,\varepsilon, {\text{nex}}} \right\} \) denotes the set of possible values for τ t . On the extended state space, we observe the process (R t , τ t ). We call a realization at time t excited if τ t  ≤ ε and non-excited otherwise. To specify the distribution of the process, we assume the Markov property

$$ \Pr \left( {\left( {{R_{t + 1}},{\tau_{t + 1}}} \right) \in {A_{t + 1}}\left| {\begin{array}{*{20}{c}} {\left( {{R_t},{\tau_t}} \right) \in {A_t},} \hfill \\ {\left( {{R_{t - 1}},{\tau_{t - 1}}} \right) \in {A_{t - 1}},...} \hfill \\ \end{array} } \right.} \right) = \Pr \left( {\left( {{R_{t + 1}},{\tau_{t + 1}}} \right) \in {A_{t + 1}}|\left( {{R_t},{\tau_t}} \right) \in {A_t}} \right), $$
(6)

which has to hold for deliberate sets \( {A_{t + 1}},{A_t},{A_{t - 1}},... \subset S \), and define rating transition probabilities separately for excited and non-excited ratings.Footnote 20 In addition to rating transitions, there are transitions of τ t . This variable can be thought as a timer that starts to tick after a downgrade and rings when the excited rating is to be set back to normal state. This mechanism is implemented by the following formal steps. Let \( \lambda_{i,j}^{nex} \) and \( \lambda_{i,j}^{ex} \) be real numbers between 0 and 1 for i ≠ j such that \( \lambda_{i,i}^{ex} \equiv \sum\limits_{j \ne i} {\lambda_{i,j}^{ex}} \) and \( \lambda_{i,i}^{nex} \equiv \sum\limits_{j \ne i} {\lambda_{i,j}^{nex}} \) lie between 0 and 1, too. These numbers are one-period transition probabilities. Their precise meaning is as follows. We set

$$ \Pr \left( {{R_{t + 1}} = j,{\tau_{t + 1}} = 1|{R_t} = i,{\tau_t} = {\text{nex}}} \right) = \lambda_{i,j}^{nex}\;{\text{for}}\;j > i, $$
(7)

which defines the downgrade probability of a non-excited rating (the timer τ t is reset and switched on);

$$ \Pr \left( {{R_{t + 1}} = j,{\tau_{t + 1}} = 1|{R_t} = i,{\tau_t}\kern1.5pt<\kern1.5pt\varepsilon } \right) = \lambda_{i,j}^{ex}\;{\text{for}}\;j > i $$
(8)

(downgrade of an excited rating; the—already ticking—timer is reset to 1 and ticks on);

$$ \Pr \left( {{R_{t + 1}} = j,{\tau_{t + 1}} = {\text{nex}}|{R_t} = i,{\tau_t}\kern1.5pt<\kern1.5pt\varepsilon } \right) = \lambda_{i,j}^{ex}\;{\text{for}}\;j\kern1.5pt<\kern1.5pti $$
(9)

(upgrade of an excited rating; timer is switched off);

$$ \Pr \left( {{R_{t + 1}} = j,{\tau_{t + 1}} = {\text{nex}}|{R_t} = i,{\tau_t} = {\text{nex}}} \right) = \lambda_{i,j}^{nex}\;{\text{for}}\;j\kern1.5pt<\kern1.5pti $$
(10)

(upgrade of a non-excited rating; timer remains off). Furthermore, expiration after ε excited periods (timer rings) is implemented by

$$ \Pr \left( {{R_{t + 1}} = i,{\tau_{t + 1}} = {\text{nex}}|{R_t} = i,{\tau_t} = \varepsilon } \right) = 1 - \lambda_{i,i}^{ex}. $$
(11)

The probability of persistence in an excited rating (timer is ticking), is given by

$$ \Pr \left( {{R_{t + 1}} = i,{\tau_{t + 1}} = {\tau_t} + 1|{R_t} = i,{\tau_t}\kern1.5pt<\kern1.5pt\varepsilon } \right) = 1 - \lambda_{i,i}^{ex} $$
(12)

and, finally, for a non-excited rating (timer off throughout), by

$$ \Pr \left( {{R_{t + 1}} = i,{\tau_{t + 1}} = {\text{nex}}|{R_t} = i,{\tau_t} = {\text{nex}}} \right) = 1 - \lambda_{i,i}^{nex}. $$
(13)

Equations 11, 12, 13 do not follow from the preceding equations but ensure that all other formally possible transition probabilities are zero.

The maximum-likelihood estimator for one-period transition probabilities has been defined by (2) in the main text.

Appendix II: Efficient calculation of long-term transition matrices

The goal of this exercise is the calculation of momentum-sensitive transition matrices over a horizon of M periods. We first present how the distribution of \( \left( {{R_{t + 1}},{\tau_{t + 1}}} \right) \) is efficiently obtained from the distribution of \( \left( {{R_t},{\tau_t}} \right) \). Let \( p_{i,s}^t \) denote this time-t distribution, where 1 ≤ i ≤ N and \( s \in \left\{ {1,...,\varepsilon, {\text{nex}}} \right\} \). Define, furthermore,

$$ p_i^{t,ex} \equiv \sum\limits_{i = 1}^\varepsilon {p_{i,s}^t} . $$
(14)

The distribution of the next period is then obtained from (7) through (13), which can be simplified to

$$ p_{i,1}^{t + 1} = \sum\limits_{j\kern1.5pt<\kern1.5pti} {\left( {p_j^{t,ex}\lambda_{j,i}^{ex} + p_{j,{\text{nex}}}^t\lambda_{j,i}^{nex}} \right)\;{\text{for}}\;{\text{2}} \leqslant i \leqslant N,} $$
(15)

which covers downgrades;

$$ p_{i,{\text{nex}}}^{t + 1} = \sum\limits_{j > i} {\left( {p_j^{t,ex}\lambda_{j,i}^{ex} + p_{j,{\text{nex}}}^t\lambda_{j,i}^{nex}} \right)} + p_{i,{\text{nex}}}^t\left( {1 - \lambda_{i,i}^{nex}} \right) + p_{i,\varepsilon }^t\left( {1 - \lambda_{i,i}^{ex}} \right)\;{\text{for}}\;{\text{1}} \leqslant i \leqslant N, $$
(16)

which covers upgrades (left-hand sum), plus persistence of non-excited ratings (middle term) and expiration (right-hand term), and, finally,

$$ p_{i,s}^{t + 1} = p_{i,s - 1}^t\left( {1 - \lambda_{i,i}^{ex}} \right)\;{\text{for}}\;1 \leqslant i \leqslant N\;{\text{and}}\;2 \leqslant s \leqslant \varepsilon, $$
(17)

which covers persistence in an excited rating while τ t is shifted.

For the transition over M periods, this calculation is repeated M times. To obtain a full M-period matrix, the whole procedure has to be performed for each initial distribution concentrated on a single initial state.

In total, the calculation requires floating point operations at the order of N 2 ε 2 M, given that N should be substantially lower than ε. In contrast, a brute-force matrix multiplication would require floating point operations at the order of N 3 ε 3 M.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Cite this article

Güttler, A., Raupach, P. The Impact of Downward Rating Momentum. J Financ Serv Res 37, 1–23 (2010). https://doi.org/10.1007/s10693-009-0075-6

Download citation

  • Received:

  • Revised:

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s10693-009-0075-6

Keywords

JEL classification

Navigation