Skip to main content

Advertisement

Log in

The labor market effects of trade unions in an open economy: Layard meets Melitz

  • Original Paper
  • Published:
International Economics and Economic Policy Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

Trade unions are typically able to convert their industrial power into political power. We show that, depending on the constellation of parameters, stronger trade unions may improve welfare in terms of an increase in aggregate employment and output if they successfully lobby for lower trade barriers set by the government.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. The exist risk is assumed to be constant and exogenous. Pflüger and Russek (2013) analyze a scenario where high-productivity firms face a lower exit risk than low-productivity firms.

  2. The right-to-manage assumption leads to a wage-employment outcome, which lies on the labor demand curve. But points on the labor demand curve are generally inefficient. A switch to efficient contracts would allow for Pareto-improvements. One way to enforce an efficient outcome is a bargain over both wages and employment. However, even in the US, where the firm is the predominant bargaining level, employment is rarely the object of bargaining agreements (see, e.g., OECD 2004). And this does not come as a surprise. Pinning down wages and employment shifts the risk of negative product demand shocks to the firm. Firms will thus demand for an opening clause. Given such a clause each firm has the incentive to claim an unexpected low product demand, since a move to the left from the contract curve to the labor demand curve implies higher profits. In short, a stochastic environment raises problems that may prevent the achievement of efficient contracts. A different way to switch to efficient contracts is a profit sharing agreement. But even these agreements are more the exception than the rule. Jerger and Michaelis (2011) discuss some reasons why profit sharing is so hard to implement.

  3. Because of the assumption of identical workers, all firms pay the same wage. If workers are allowed to differ, for instance with respect to their abilities, firms with different ϕ will pay different wages (see de Pinto and Michaelis 2014).

  4. We thank an anonymous referee for pointing us to this result. In a dynamic modelling framework, the expansion of the export sector would have important consequences for the lobbying process, since there are now more unions that lobby for liberalization. Developing such a dynamic framework, however, is beyond the scope of this paper.

References

  • Acemoglu D (2002) Technical change, inequality, and the labor market. J Econ Lit 40(1):7–72

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bastos P, Kreickemeier U, Wright P (2009) Oligopoly, open shop unions and trade liberalisation. Int J Ind Organ 27(6):679–86

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Beaulieu E, Magee C (2004) Four simple tests of campaign contributions and trade policy preferences. Econ Polit 16(2):163–87

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Blanchard E, Willmann G (2011) Escaping a protectionist rut: Policy mechanisms for trade reform in a demogracy. J Int Econ 85(1):72–85

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Blonigen BA (2011) Revisiting the evidence on trade policy preferences. J Int Econ 85(1):129–35

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Brander J, Spencer B (1988) Unionized oligopoly and international trade policy. J Int Econ 24(3–4):217–34

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • de Pinto M, Michaelis J (2014) International trade and unemployment – the worker-selection effect. Rev Int Econ 22(2):226–52

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Eaton J, Kortum S, Kramarz F (2004) Dissecting trade: Firms, industries and export destinations. Am Econ Rev 94(2):150–54

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Egger H, Kreickemeier U (2009) Firm heterogeneity and the labor market effects of trade liberalization. Int Econ Rev 50(1):187–216

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Felbermayr G, Prat J, Schmerer H-J (2011) Globalization and labor market outcomes: Wage bargaining, search frictions, and firm heterogeneity. J Econ Theory 146(1):39–73

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Grossman GM, Helpman E (1994) Protection for Sale. Am Econ Rev 84(4):833–50

    Google Scholar 

  • Hassel A (2014) The paradox of liberalization – Understanding dualism and the recovery of the german political economy. Br J Ind Relat 52(1):57–81

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Huizinga H (1993) International market integration and union wage bargaining. Scand J Econ 95(2):249–55

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Jerger J, Michaelis J (2011) The fixed wage puzzle: Why profit sharing is so hard to implement. Econ Lett 110(2):104–6

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Layard R, Nickell S (1990) Is unemployment lower if unions bargain over employment? Q J Econ 105(3):773–87

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Layard R, Nickell S, Jackman R (2005) Unemployment – macroeconomic performance and the labour market, Oxford

  • Matschke X (2010) Do labor market imperfections increase trade protection? A theoretical investigation. B E J Econ Anal Policy 10(1):Article 50

    Google Scholar 

  • Matschke X, Sherlund SM (2006) Do labor issues matter in the determination of U.S. trade policy? An empirical reevaluation. Am Econ Rev 96(1):405–21

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mayda AM, Rodrik D (2005) Why are some individuals (and countries) more protectionist than others? Eur Econ Rev 49(6):1393–430

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Melitz MJ (2003) The impact of trade on intra-industry reallocations and aggregate industry productivity. Econometrica 71(6):1695–725

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Montagna C, Nocco A (2013) Unionization, international integration, and selection. Can J Econ 46(1):23–45

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mukherjee A (2013) Endogenous domestic market structure and the effects of a trade cost reduction in a unionised industry. Econ Model 32(1):30–3

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • OECD (2004) Wage-Setting institutions and outcomes, OECD employment outlook, Paris

  • Pflüger M, Russek S (2013) Business conditions and exit risks across countries. Open Econ Rev 24(5):963–76

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Scheve KF, Slaughter MJ (2001) What determines trade policy preferences? J Int Econ 54(2):267–92

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Streeck W, Hassel A (2003) Trade unions as political actors. In: Addison JT, Schnabel C (eds) International handbook of trade unions, Cheltenham, pp 336–65

  • Wiberg M (2014) Comparative trade policy. Rev Int Econ 22(2):410–21

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgements

We thank an anonymous referee for very insightful comments. The paper also benefited from comments by Laszlo Goerke, Xenia Matschke, Carsten Eckel, Gerald Willmann, Benjamin Jung, and from participants at conferences in Göttingen and Trier.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Jochen Michaelis.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

de Pinto, M., Michaelis, J. The labor market effects of trade unions in an open economy: Layard meets Melitz. Int Econ Econ Policy 13, 223–232 (2016). https://doi.org/10.1007/s10368-014-0301-z

Download citation

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s10368-014-0301-z

Keywords

Navigation