1 Introduction

There is no doubt that renewable energy investments represent a new frontier in the pursuit of sustainability goals. Projects that involve wind farms, biomass, solar panels, tidal or hydro power are some of the most widespread investments in the renewable energy sector. Another important renewable energy process is the conversion of corn to fuel ethanol (Commodity Research Bureau, 2007). Although this conversion process has received many criticisms related to the excessive amount of energy required to produce fuel ethanol (Kim & Dale, 2005; Patzek et al., 2005) or related to the increase of food prices as a consequence of production change from food to fuel (Pimentel, 2003), it has become environmentally attractive as renewable investment.

However, in general the valuation of renewable investments is not a simple task since they are characterized by various types of uncertainties according to the different technologies used. For example, solar panels performance depends on solar irradiation, materials and technology of cells, and location of cells (Duong et al., 2019). Wind farm investments suffer from the difficult predicting wind power availability, as power cannot be produced when the wind does not blow (Boyle, 2007) making them unreliable power producers. Corn ethanol plant performance depends on the uncertain nature of process input (corn) and output (gasoline) prices. If input prices fluctuate to exceed the price to be received for the corresponding output, conversion becomes financially attractive and can be halted.

For these reasons, the classical valuation approaches such as Net Present Value (NPV) are not adequate to make a reliable valuation of these projects characterized by uncertainty (Ross, 1995). Conversely, the Real Options Approach (ROA) has spread as one of the most useful approaches to price uncertain projects by including in the valuation managerial flexibility, also called optionality (Trigeorgis, 1993). This managerial flexibility allows certain project risks to be mitigated and gives a potential investor the possibility of changing investment decisions during the project lifetime. For example, Di Bari (2020) applied the ROA to value solar energy projects by considering the uncertainty of meteorological conditions, the unpredictable behavior of government that could encourage or not these renewable investments and managerial flexibility. Venetsanos et al. (2002) combined a framework with ROA to assess the wind farm investments affected by the unstable conditions of the deregulated energy market by explaining the case of Greece. Again, Pederson and Zou (2009) applied real options analysis and Monte Carlo simulation to valuate ethanol plant projects by considering historical price data and representative operational parameters. Maxwell and Davison (2014) used the ROA as support to valuate the impact of model variables on the decision of pursuing the project given its financial performance and on the decision of switching between an idled an operating facility states, focusing on the cost of switching between these states.

In the current paper, we propose a valuation methodology to price a corn ethanol plant project by considering the particular stochastic nature of corn and gasoline prices that represent respectively the input and the output prices of the plant, since sometimes the historical prices of some commodities follow skew-t distributions rather than having normal returns (Orlando & Bufalo, 2021). The skew Brownian motions can represent the best solution to provide a realistic study of corn ethanol plant performance during its lifetime. Pasricha and He (2022) formulated a closed-form pricing formula for European Exchange Options, introduced by Margrabe (1978) under skew-Brownian motion. Moreover, since the corn ethanol plant project can be viewed as a multi-stage process from the engineering of the plant to its operation stage, we adopt the compound ROA to valuate this project. In fact, the compound ROA is often used in the literature to price renewable investments characterized by sequential stages. For example, Loncar et al. (2017)) adopted the compound ROA to assess a wind farm in Serbia by using a reliable wind farm project valuation to divide the investment from the operating period. This work contributes to the existing literature by using the compound ROA to valuate a corn ethanol plant project considering that corn and gasoline prices follow a skew-geometric Brownian motion. The paper is organized as follows: Sect. 2 provides the methodology to valuate a typical corn ethanol plant project. Section 3 provides a case study by using representative data. Section 4 provides the conclusive remarks.

1.1 Contributions and novelties

A strand of literature applies real options models to biofuels (corn-ethanol plant) production investment. Our main novelty on this topic is the use of skew-Brownian motions that makes more realistic the corn ethanol plant evaluation differently from the quoted literature. In fact, in contrast to real option models that use a geometric Brownian motion, in our case we have verified that corn and gasoline prices follow a skew-Brownian motion that performs a more realistic evaluation about the corn ethanol plants.

Now, we explicitly discuss and compare our paper with the most relevant ones on this topic. Pederson and Zou (2009), using the binomial option pricing approach, state that the investment decision of a corn-ethanol plant can be valued as an American option assuming the production capacity plant constant. In addition, Pederson and Zou (2009) use a two-period plan start-up, where the investor has the right to start it any time before period 2. We connect to Pederson and Zou (2009) for the sequential investment approach but we differ form them since we provide a generalization assuming \(n+1\) engineering-construction investments and then m operational phases. We improve their approach since we introduce a time-dependent efficiency function \(\gamma _t\), that describes how the plant can lose efficiency over time in converting corn into gasoline. In addition, we consider the skew-Brownian motion and consequently the real option evaluation under continuous setting.

Schmit et al. (2009) conduct a real options analysis of entry-exit decisions (based on Dixit & Pindyck, 1994) for dry-grind corn ethanol plants in order to incorporate the impact of rising volatility in market prices. In their approach, the stochastic gross margin follows a geometric Brownian motion. We differentiate since we use some of more restrictive assumptions, as skew-Brownian motions, that reflects accurately the risk and uncertainty in the ethanol industry and we prove that under the skew-geometric Brownian motions the project value increases its value.

Kirby and Davison (2010) model ethanol production as a discrete sum of spark spread options by considering the possibility that widespread ethanol production might cause a correlation between the corn and gasoline prices. Moreover, Kirby and Davison (2010) consider that ethanol production is highly subsidized and they value the real option investment opportunity as a simple exchange option (see Margrabe, 1978). Our paper connects to Kirby and Davison (2010) for the use of spread options in order to estimate the project value and for the real option methodology that overcomes the limitations of the discounted cash flows approaches. We differ from Kirby and Davison (2010) since we implement a compound option strategy (Kirby & Davison, 2010 use a simple exchange option) in order to evaluate a corn-ethanol plants organized in phased manner. The use of compound options is widely employed for valuation of R &D investments and therefore in the field of corn-ethanol plants. In addition, as seen above, we apply the skew-geometric Brownian motions assumption that, as analyzed in the case study, makes the gasoline and corn prices more realistic with respect to geometric Brownian motion considered in Margrabe (1978) approach.

Li et al. (2015) present a ROA for valuing the investment of a new technology for producing biofuels subject to construction lead times and uncertain fuel price. Their result indicates that the project profitability changes if the plant-investment is realized immediately or postponed. However, the sequential structure of the production process that requires the use of compound options is not addressed. So, we differentiate since the compound real option valuation is able to capture the value of flexibility that arises in the decision-making and operational processes.

Summing up, although previous works can represent a good starting point to propose a valuation methodology of corn-ethanol plant, they can be inadequate if the projects are characterized simultaneously by a high level of uncertainty, multistage nature and unpredictable future performance of corn and ethanol fuel prices. By using the compound exchange options model with skew-geometric Brownian motion, our valuation methodology can perform better than the existing literature for several reasons. First, the proposed model allows to monitor the uncertainty by including the operational flexibility to pursue the investment only if the revenues, adjusted for a time-dependent decreasing efficiency function, are higher than costs. Second, the compound options approach and its numerical valuation makes the model more suitable to incorporate potential managerial flexibility to proceed with the next investment stage only if the previous one is profitable. Third, we model adequately the corn and ethanol fuel prices by adopting the skew-geometric Brownian motion that performs a more realistic evolution of prices and fits better the relationship between corn and gasoline prices. This third point is an important novelty in the compound option pricing. Some recent papers, such as Bufalo et al. (2022), Zhu and He (2018), Pasricha and He (2022) apply the skew-geometric Brownian motion theory to portfolio optimization, or to simple or exchange option pricing, but to date we have seen no works which use these processes for compound option pricing. The major benefit brought by the skew-geometric Brownian motions consists of a better fitness with respect to the real data observed (see the statistical tests of Sect. 2.3), which results in a more accurate prevision about the positive outcome from the plant investment. Last but not least, our procedure provides an out of sample valuation methodology which allows an ex-ante investment decision in a corn-ethanol plant by forecasting its future performance. This is possible thanks to an accurate probabilistic assumption on the underlying processes which are modeled as skew-geometric Brownian motions, according to the statistical properties of the related time series observed. In this way, the out-of sample valuation is needed to make predictions on the processes and, consequently, on the future performances of the corn-ethanol plant.

2 Methodology

In this section we present a valuation methodology of a corn ethanol plant considering the basic characteristics of the project. First of all, we address our analysis to a general formulation in which there are: one engineering investment at time \(t_0\); n construction investments at time \(t_1,t_2,\ldots ,t_n\) and subsequently m operational phases. After that, to emphasize our results, we describe a corn ethanol plant project in which there are three main sequential phases related to different investments. These phases are not independent: this means that a potential investor should proceed to the following investments only if the previous stages are profitable. We have identified three main stages that characterize corn ethanol plant implementation: the first is the engineering design activities at time \(t_{0}\), then there is the construction of the plant at time \(t_{1}\), and finally the investor can proceed to the operating stage in which the plant produces fuel ethanol from corn at time \(t_{2}\). Different investment amounts are required for each stage. Specifically, \(I_{0}\) is the capital required to start the project with the engineering activities. If the engineering investment is successful, the investor should construct the plant by investing \(I_{1}\), and in sequence, if the construction phase is achieved without any failure, the investor can proceed to the operating stage by investing \(I_{2}\).

We propose a valuation methodology giving the potential investor the possibility to continue the project in each stage only if it is not characterized by some failures that could make the project unprofitable in the future. For example it might happen that the project turns out to be unfeasible in the engineering phase, or there can be some failures of procedural tasks in the construction phase, or again an increase of corn prices can makes the conversion financially unprofitable in the operating period. We model the valuation methodology of a corn ethanol plant project as a compound options model. In fact, the compound options model, also called compound ROA in the case of infrastructure investment, is used to price the investment characterized by various stages organized in phased manner (Villani, 2021; Cortelezzi & Villani, 2009). The goal of our valuation methodology is to allow the investor to make an ex-ante valuation of a corn ethanol plant investment after making a projection of the project in the future by embedding in the model skew-geometric stochastic motions. Although previous studies valuated the ethanol plants by using the real options approach with fluctuating corn and gasoline prices e.g., Kirby and Davison (2010), none of them embeds the exchange options model into a multi-stage framework that affects these investments. We proceed by adopting the compound ROA to valuate a corn ethanol plant taking into account the sequential logic of projects and the unpredictable nature of corn and gasoline prices included in the model by stochastic motions.

2.1 A compound options approach for corn ethanol plant valuation

The focus of this section is the value the corn ethanol project as a compound option with stochastic input and output prices following a skew-Brownian motion. The compound options logic is shown graphically in the Fig. 1 where \(c^m_n\) represents the operational flexibility value considered as a compound option, \(E_{t_n}\) represents the project value, and \(I_n\) represents the the investments required in each stage.

Fig. 1
figure 1

Corn ethanol plant as compound options—general case

Specifically, implementing the engineering investment (\(I_{0}\)), the investor obtains the compound option \(c^m_n\) so that he can make a reliable valuation of project at time \(t_{0}\) considering both the option both to abandon the project and the unpredictable possibility of corn conversion in fuel ethanol. This value is called real option value RO, namely:

$$\begin{aligned} \text{ RO }=-I_0+c^m_n \end{aligned}$$
(1)

where \(c^m_n\) is the n-fold compound option c whose value at time \(t_0\) is function of the next compound option exercisable \(n-1\) times (as underlying asset), the investment \(I_{1}\) (as strike price), and deadline \(\tau _1=t_1-t_0\). So we can write that:

$$\begin{aligned} c^m_n=c\left( c^m_{n-1},I_{1}, \tau _1\right) \end{aligned}$$

In particular \(c^m_n\) represents, at time \(t_0\), the value to realize the first construction phase investing the amount \(I_1\) at time \(t_1\), that gives the \((n-1)\)-fold compound option. Recursively, \(c^m_{n-1}\) denotes, at time \(t_1\), the value to implement the second construction investment \(I_2\) at time \(t_2\) in order to receive the \((n-2)\)-fold compound option. So:

$$\begin{aligned} c^m_{n-1}=c\left( c^m_{n-2},I_{2}, \tau _2\right) \end{aligned}$$

with \(\tau _2=t_2-t_1\).

Generalizing, the h-fold compound option, with \(h=2,\ldots ,n\) can be write as:

$$\begin{aligned} c^m_h=c\left( c^m_{h-1},I_{n-(h-1)},\tau _{n-(h-1)}\right) \end{aligned}$$
(2)

In addition, when \(h=1\), we obtain the evaluation at time \(t_{n-1}\) of the last construction phase that can be evaluated as a simple (1-fold) option denoted as s. So \(c_1^m\), values the opportunity to implement the last construction investment \(I_n\) at time \(t_n\) in order to receive the operating benefits \({\mathcal {V}}^m_{t_n}\):

$$\begin{aligned} c_1^m=s\left( {\mathcal {V}}^m_{t_n},I_n,\tau _n\right) \end{aligned}$$
(3)

with \(\tau _n=t_n-t_{n-1}\). Below we describe in more detail our approach.

Let \(({\varOmega },{\mathbb P},{{{\mathcal {F}}}},({{{\mathcal {F}}}}_t)_{t\ge 0})\) be a filtered probability space. The project value is calculated at time \(t_{n}\) starting from the initial date \(t_0\ge 0\), once the construction phase is completed and the operating phase represented by the real conversion starts. By selecting m equal time steps between \(t_{n}\) and the project maturity T each of length \({\varDelta } t=\frac{T-t_{n}}{m}\), by denoting the risk-free rate by r, and by assuming that \(h=1,2,\ldots m\), we can compute the project value asFootnote 1

$$\begin{aligned} \displaystyle E_{t_{n}}={\mathbb E}^{{\mathbb Q}}_{t_0}\bigl [ {\mathcal {V}}^m_{t_{n}}\bigr ], \end{aligned}$$
(4)

where \({\mathbb Q}\) is an equivalent martingale measure under which the (discounted) corn and gasoline processes are martingales (see Sect. 2.2),

$$\begin{aligned} \displaystyle {\mathcal {V}}^m_{t_{n}}= \sum _{h=1}^{m}e^{-r \cdot h{\varDelta } t} \cdot V_{t_{n}+h{\varDelta } t}, \end{aligned}$$
(5)

and \(V_{t_{n}+h{\varDelta } t}\) is the project value represented by the revenues derived from the conversion of corn to gasoline at all instants after time \(t_{n}\). For the sake of notation we shorten \((t_{n}+h{\varDelta } t)\) with \(t_{n,h}\). So, \(V_{t_{n,h}}\) is calculated as follows:

$$\begin{aligned} V_{t_{n,h}}= \max \{0; (F_{t_{n,h}} \cdot \gamma _{t_{n,h}} - C_{t_{n,h}} )\cdot q\}, \end{aligned}$$
(6)

where \(F_{t_{n,h}}\) and \(C_{t_{n,h}}\) are respectively the fuel and corn prices at time \(t_{n,h}\), \(\gamma _{t_{n,h}}\) is an efficiency factor at \(t_{n,h}\), q is the expected quantity of fuel to be sold.

Notice that \(\gamma _t\) is the product of a suitable constant \({\bar{\gamma }}\) (see Sect. 3.1) by the decreasing function \(f(t,{\varvec{b}})\), i.e., \(\gamma _{t}={\bar{\gamma }}\cdot f(t,{\varvec{b}})\), where \({\varvec{b}}=[b_1,b_2]\) is a vector of some parameters. More specifically, \(f(t,{\varvec{b}})\) is defined as:

$$\begin{aligned} f(t,{\varvec{b}})=1-b_1\left( \frac{t-t_{n}}{T-t_{n}}\right) ^{b_2} \quad (t\in [t_n,T]). \end{aligned}$$
(7)

where \(b_1\,\in [0,1]\) denotes the ratio of industrial plant deterioration and \(b_2\) measures the efficiency intensity of the plant. Figure 2 shows the trend of plant efficiency \(f(t,{\varvec{b}})\) by varying the parameters \(b_1\) and \(b_2\). We remark that, when \(b_2\) rises, the plant efficiency remains almost constant for a long time, after which it tends to rapidly decrease. Instead, when the value of \(b_1=1\), the plant efficiency tends to zero at final time T. For other values of \(b_1\), the plant efficiency remains positive in T.

Fig. 2
figure 2

From the top left to the right, first row: a \(f(t,{\varvec{b}})\) when \(b_1=1\) and \(b_2\in \{ 2,4,8\}\); b \(f(t,{\varvec{b}})\) when \(b_2=2\) and \(b_1\in \{ 0.1,0.3,1\}\). From the top left to the right, second row: a \(f(t,{\varvec{b}})\) when \(b_2=2\) and \(b_1\in [0,1]\); b \(f(t,{\varvec{b}})\) when \(b_1=1\) and \(b_2\in [1,10]\)

The expression in Eq. (6) explains that the investor gains by the difference between the price of the converted fuel \(F_{t_{n,h}}\) and the price of corn \(C_{t_{n,h}}\) during their time evolution, but if the price of corn becomes higher than fuel the investor should avoid to produce fuel by obtaining 0.

Finally, the simple (s) and compound (c) options are defined as

$$\begin{aligned} {\left\{ \begin{array}{ll} s\left( {\mathcal {V}}^m_{t_{n}},I_{n},\tau _n\right) =e^{-r\tau _n}\cdot {\mathbb E}^{{\mathbb Q}}_{t_0}\left[ \max \{{\mathcal {V}}^m_{t_n}-I_{n};0\}\right] .\\ c\left( c^m_{h-1},I_{n-(h-1)},\tau _{n-(h-1)}\right) =e^{-r\tau _{n-(h-1)}}\cdot {\mathbb E}^{{\mathbb Q}}_{t_0}\left[ \max \left\{ c^m_{h-1}-I_{n-(h-1)};0\right\} \right] , \end{array}\right. } \end{aligned}$$
(8)

with the following boundary conditions

$$\begin{aligned} {\left\{ \begin{array}{ll} s\left( {\mathcal {V}}^m_{t_{n}},I_{n},0\right) =\max \{ E_{t_n}-I_n;0\}\\ c\left( c^m_{h-1},I_{n-(h-1)},0\right) =\max \left\{ {\mathbb E}^{{\mathbb Q}}_{t_0}\left[ c^m_{h-1}\right] -I_{n-(h-1)};0\right\} . \end{array}\right. } \end{aligned}$$
(9)

We assume that the operational prices parameters change only slowly over time, in contrast to the rapid fluctuations in corn and gasoline commodity prices. As such, it appears a reasonably assumption that this cost set \(I_h\) can be modelled as constant within this period. In fact, previous studies such as Pederson and Zou (2009) does not consider the stochasticity in the investment values \(I_h\) by adopting them as constant. However, for a generalization of Eqs. (2) and (3) to stochastic costs \(I_h\), refer to Appendix C.

We proceed using backward induction to the starting time \(t_{0}\). The value of c, calculated at time \(t_{n-h}\) for \(h\in [1,n]\) becomes the new underlying asset value from which is subtracted the investment required to build the plant (\(I_{n-(h-1)}\)). We therefore have an n-fold that allows us to capture the sequential investment characterized by various stages. The value of such compound option at \(t_0\) is given by \(c^m_n\) through Eqs. (2) and (3).

2.2 Gasoline and corn stochastic dynamics

As showed in Sect. 2.3, the historical gasoline and corn prices do not exhibit normal returns. The same occurs in many project involving renewable energies whose price do not follow the usual geometric Brownian motion, see e.g., Chinhamu et al. (2021), Nunes et al. (2021).

In contrast to claims by Andersen et al. (2001), and/or Rogers (2018) the asset returns do not seem to be unconditionally normally distributed, but often show a significant amount of skewness and extra-curtosis. As investigated by Orlando and Bufalo (2021), note that a “more realistic work hypothesis is that time series follow a t-skew distribution”. The t-skew distribution can be seen as a mixture of skew-normal distributions Kim (2001) which generalizes the normal distribution thanks to an extra parameter regulating the skewness.

The main properties of the skew-normal distribution, first introduced by Azzalini (1985) and Henze (1986), are summarized in Appendix A.

First of all, recall the definition of a skew-Brownian motion.

Definition 1

The stochastic process \(Y_t\) is said to be a (standard) skew-Brownian motion if the following conditions hold true

  1. (i)

    \(Y_0=0\);

  2. (ii)

    for any \(t\ge 0\), \(Y_t\) has continuous sample paths;

  3. (iii)

    for any \(t\ge 0\), \(Y_t\) is skew-normally distributed with location and scale parameters equal to 0 and t, respectively.

Following Corns and Satchell (2007), we characterize a (standard) skew-Brownian motion \(Y_t\) as the sum of a standard Brownian motion and a reflected Brownian motion, i.e.,

$$\begin{aligned} Y_t=\sqrt{1-\delta ^2}\cdot W_t+\delta |U_t|, \end{aligned}$$
(10)

where \(W_t\) and \(U_t\) are two independent (standard) Brownian motions and \(\delta \) is the rescaled shape parameter. In the light of the above, we assume that both the gasoline and corn price follows a skew-geometric Brownian motion, i.e.,

$$\begin{aligned} {\left\{ \begin{array}{ll} F_t=F_0\,e^{ \mu t+\sigma Y^F_t} \\ C_t=C_0\,e^{ \theta t+\eta Y^C_t}, \end{array}\right. } \end{aligned}$$
(11)

where \((F_0,C_0)\in {\mathbb R}^2_+\) and \(Y^F_t\) and \(Y^C_t\) are two correlated (standard) skew-Brownian motions. In order to correlate the two processes in Eq. (11) we follow (Bufalo et al., 2022, Proposition 4). More precisely, the next proposition generalizes such a result which is valid in the case of centered skew-Brownian motions, while our statement holds true for any skew-Brownian motion with non-zero expectation. So, let us define the process \(Y^C_t\) as

$$\begin{aligned} Y^C_t=\rho Y^F_t+\sqrt{\biggl ( 1-\frac{2\delta ^2}{\pi }\biggr )(1-\rho ^2)}\cdot B_t, \end{aligned}$$
(12)

where \(\rho \in (-1,1)\) is the correlation coefficient, \(\delta =\frac{\beta }{\sqrt{1+\beta ^2}}\) is the rescaled shape parameter of \(Y^F_t\) and \(B_t\) is a (standard) Brownian motion independent from \(Y^F_t\).

Proposition 1

The stochastic process \(Y^C_t\) is a (standard) skew-Brownian motion with shape parameter

$$\begin{aligned} \alpha =\frac{\beta }{\sqrt{1+(1+\beta ^2)\biggl ( 1-\frac{2\delta ^2}{\pi }\biggr )\biggl ( \frac{1}{\rho ^2}-1\biggr )}}, \end{aligned}$$
(13)

such that \(Corr(Y^C_t,Y^F_t)=\rho \).

Proof

See Appendix B.1. \(\square \)

To evaluate the project at the starting time \(t_0\) through the compound option \(c^m_n\) (see Eq. (1)) we have to determine an equivalent martingale measure under which we compute the (conditioning) expectations.

We consider a market comprising two assets \(F_t\) and \(C_t\) with dynamics as in Eq. (11) together with a zero-coupon non-defaultable bond \(D_t\) with deterministic dynamics given by

$$\begin{aligned} dD_t=rD_tdt, \quad D_0=1, \end{aligned}$$

where r is the risk-free rate. According to Eq. (10), \(Y^F_t\) may be written as

$$\begin{aligned} Y^F_t=\sqrt{1-\delta ^2}\cdot W_t+\delta |U_t|. \end{aligned}$$

Then, following Zhu and He (2018), there exists an equivalent martingale measure \({\mathbb Q}\), under wich the process

$$\begin{aligned} F_t=F_s\,e^{ \bigl (r-\frac{\sigma ^2}{2} \bigr )(t-s) +l(t-s)+\sigma {{\bar{Y}}}^F_{t-s} } \quad (s\ge 0), \end{aligned}$$
(14)

with

$$\begin{aligned} l(t-s)=\ln \biggl [ {\varPhi }\biggl ( \frac{(t-s)\delta \sigma ^2 +\delta |U_s|}{\sqrt{t-s}\cdot \delta \sigma }\biggr )+e^{-2\delta |U_s|}{\varPhi }\biggl ( \frac{(t-s)\delta \sigma ^2 -\delta |U_s|}{\sqrt{t-s}\cdot \delta \sigma }\biggr ) \biggr ], \end{aligned}$$
(15)

and

$$\begin{aligned} {{\bar{Y}}}^F_t=\sqrt{1-\delta ^2}\cdot \biggl (W_t +\frac{\bigl ( \mu -r+\frac{\sigma ^2}{2}\bigr )(t-s)}{\sqrt{1-\delta ^2}\cdot \sigma } \biggr )+\delta |U_t|, \end{aligned}$$
(16)

is a martingale if discounted at risk-free rate r, i.e., \({\mathbb E}^{{\mathbb Q}}_s\bigl [ e^{-rt}F_t \bigr ]=e^{-rs}F_s\) (\(0\le s<t\)). The same occurs for \(C_t\), more specifically, we setFootnote 2

$$\begin{aligned} {{\bar{Y}}}^C_t=\rho {{\bar{Y}}}^F_t+\sqrt{\biggl ( 1-\frac{2\delta ^2}{\pi }\biggr )(1-\rho ^2)}\cdot {{\bar{B}}}_t, \end{aligned}$$
(17)

where \({{\bar{B}}}_t\) is a (standard) Brownian motion independent of \({{\bar{Y}}}^F_t\).

From here on we express the processes \(F_t,C_t\) under the risk-neutral measure \({\mathbb Q}\).

With refer to Sect. 2.1, in order to evaluate any (compound) option \(c^m_h\) (\(h\in [1,n]\)) we give the next result. The next Proposition 2 and its related considerations help to implement the Monte Carlo technique for simulating the processes involved in our model.

First of all, let us introduce \(R^F_t\) and \(R^C_t\) the (log-)returns of the processes \(F_t,\,C_t\), respectively; i.e.,

$$\begin{aligned} R^F_t=\ln \biggl ( \frac{F_{t}}{F_{s}} \biggr ), \qquad R^C_t=\ln \biggl ( \frac{C_{t}}{C_{s}} \biggr ) \qquad (0\le s<t); \end{aligned}$$
(18)

and denote by \(X^F_t,X^C_t\) the stochastic part of such processes. Notice that the function \({\varPhi }(\cdot )\) denotes, hereinafter, the (standard) normal CDF.

Proposition 2

The conditional densities of the processes \(X^F_t,X^C_t\) are:

$$\begin{aligned} f_{X^F_t|X^F_s}(x_1|y,z)=\frac{1}{\sqrt{2\pi (t-s)\sigma }}\biggl (e^{-\frac{(x_1-y-z)^2}{2\sigma ^2(t-s)}}{\varPhi }(a_1)+e^{-\frac{(x_1-y+z)^2}{2\sigma ^2(t-s)}}{\varPhi }(a_2)\biggr ) \quad (x_1\in {\mathbb R}_+), \end{aligned}$$
(19)

and

$$\begin{aligned} f_{X^C_t|X^C_s}(x_2|{{\tilde{y}}},{{\tilde{z}}})=\frac{1}{\sqrt{2\pi (t-s)\eta }}\biggl (e^{-\frac{(x_2-{{\tilde{y}}}-{{\tilde{z}}})^2}{2\eta ^2(t-s)}}{\varPhi }({{\tilde{a}}}_1)+e^{-\frac{(x_2-{{\tilde{y}}}+{{\tilde{z}}})^2}{2\eta ^2(t-s)}}{\varPhi }({{\tilde{a}}}_2)\biggr ) \quad (x_2\in {\mathbb R}_+), \end{aligned}$$
(20)

respectively, where

$$\begin{aligned} a_{1,2}= & {} \frac{\delta ^2(x_1-y \mp z)\pm z}{\delta \sigma \sqrt{(t-s)(1-\delta ^2)}}, \quad {{\tilde{a}}}_{1,2}=\frac{\delta ^2\rho ^2(x_2-{{\tilde{y}}} \mp {{\tilde{z}}})\pm {{\tilde{z}}}}{\delta \eta \rho \sqrt{(t-s)}\cdot \bigl [\sqrt{1-\delta ^2}+\sqrt{\bigl ( 1-\frac{2\delta ^2}{\pi }\bigr )(1-\rho ^2)\bigr ] } },\\ y= & {} \sqrt{1-\delta ^2}\cdot W_s, \quad {{\tilde{y}}}=\rho y+\sqrt{\biggl ( 1-\frac{2\delta ^2}{\pi }\biggr )(1-\rho ^2)}\cdot {{\bar{B}}}_s, \quad z=\delta |U_s|, \quad {{\tilde{z}}}=\rho z. \end{aligned}$$

Proof

See Appendix B.2\(\square \)

Now, we can compute the density of the process \({\mathcal {V}}_{t_n}\) defined in Eq. (5) by the convolution of the densities of each variable \(e^{-r \cdot h{\varDelta } t} V_{t_{n,h}}\), due to the independence of the skew-Brownian motion increments. But \(V_{t_n,h}\) is a function of two correlated logarithmic skew-normal variables (see, e.g., Lin & Stoyanov, 2009), whose explicit density is unknown in literature.

To avoid this issue, we will use the densities (19), (20) to simulate under \({\mathbb {Q}}\) the stochastic part of the processes \(F_{t_{n,h}},C_{t_{n,h}}\) and, consequently, those of \(V_{t_{n,h}}\) and \({\mathcal {V}}_{t_{n,h}}\). These considerations, allow us to evaluate the simple and compound options in Eqs. (2) and (3) through the Monte Carlo approach.

2.3 Empirical analysis on the distribution of gasoline and corn returns

This subsection provides a statistical analysis on the gasoline and corn returns. Our dataset is referred to a period from January 1994 to September 2021 (see Fig. 3), and it consists of monthly global price of corn in U.S. Dollars per Bushel and the U.S. all grades all formulations monthly retail gasoline prices in U.S. Dollars per Gallon.Footnote 3

Fig. 3
figure 3

From the top left to the right, first row: a Gasoline prices ($/gallon), b Gasoline log-returns (%). From the top left to the right, second row: a Corn prices ($/bushel), b Corn log-returns (%)

Among our tests, we mention the moments (see Table 1), the histograms (see the first picture of Figs. 4 and 5) and the quantile–quantile (Q–Q) plot Wilk and Gnanadesikan (1968) where are considered the normal distribution versus the skew-normal distribution. In order to prove that such returns are skewed and not normally distributed, we perform:

  • the Kolmogorov–Smirnov (K–S) test Kolmogorov (1933), that is a nonparametric test of the equality of probability distributions, used to compare a sample with one reference probability distribution;

  • the Dvoretzky–Kiefer–Wolfowitz (DKW) inequality Dvoretzky et al. (1956) which provides a measure of the distance between the empirical and normal CDF. This method is based on the Glivenko–Cantelli Theorem Tucker (1959) that estimates the tail probability of the Kolmogorov–Smirnov statistic.

    As in Orlando and Bufalo (2021), we introduce the variable, named “DKW exceeds”, which enumerates the percentage of points of the theoretical CDF that exceed the DKW upper and lower bounds.

To be thorough, we compare the normal and skew-normal distribution with the following ones:

  • Generalized hyperbolic (GH) distribution,

    $$\begin{aligned} f(x;a_1,a_2,a_3,a_4,a_5)= & {} \frac{(a_2^2-a_3^2)^{a_1/2}\cdot a_2^{a_1+1/2} \sqrt{a_4^2+(x-a_5)^2}\,K_{a_1-1/2} }{\sqrt{2\pi (a_2^2-a_3^2)}\,a_4^{a_1+1} K_{a_1} \cdot (a_4^2+(x-a_5)^2)^{1/4-a_1/2}}\nonumber \\{} & {} (x\in {\mathbb R}), \end{aligned}$$
    (21)

    where \(a_3 \in {\mathbb R}\) is the asymmetry parameter, \(a_4 \in {\mathbb R}\) is the scale parameter, \(a_5 \in {\mathbb R}\) is the location, \(a_2\in R,\;(a_2^2>a_3^2)\), and \(K_{a_1}\;(a_1\in {\mathbb R})\) denotes the modified Bessel function of the second kind.

  • Generalized Pareto (GP) distribution,

    $$\begin{aligned} f(x;\alpha _1,\alpha _2,\alpha _3)=\frac{(1+\alpha _3\bigl (\frac{x-\alpha _1}{\alpha _2}\bigr ))^{-(1/\alpha _3+1)}}{\alpha _2} \qquad (x> \alpha _1), \end{aligned}$$
    (22)

    where \(\alpha _3 \in {\mathbb R}\) is the shape parameter, \(\alpha _2 \in {\mathbb R}_+\) is the scale parameter, and \(\alpha _1 \in {\mathbb R}\) is the location.

The second row of Figs. 4 and 5 displays the Q–Q plots. These graphs represent the distribution quantiles comparing the CDF of the observed time series, which is unknown, a priori, with that of a specified distribution, chosen as benchmark. If the observed variable follows the theoretical distribution chosen, the Q–Q plot thickens across the line that connects the first and third quantiles of the data. The Q–Q plots show that the skew-normal performs better than the Gaussian (with the exception of some outliers).

Table 1 First four central moments for Gasoline and Corn prices and their log-returns

The second picture of first row of Figs. 4 and 5 reveals that the empirical CDF of returns is far from the theoretical normal CDF and widely exceeds from the DKW lower and upper bounds.

Fig. 4
figure 4

From the top left to the right, first row: a Gasoline log-returns histogram, b Empirical CDF versus standard normal CDF for Gasoline log-returns. The dotted black lines represent the DKW upper and lower bounds. From the top left to the right, second row: a Gasoline log-returns Q–Q plot from Gaussian distribution, b Gasoline log-returns Q–Q plot from skew-normal distribution

Fig. 5
figure 5

From the top left to the right, first row: a Corn log-returns histogram, b Empirical CDF versus standard normal CDF for Corn log-returns. The dotted black lines represent the DKW upper and lower bounds. From the top left to the right, second row: a Corn log-returns Q–Q plot from Gaussian distribution, b Corn log-returns Q–Q plot from skew-normal distribution

The last check on the normality is performed by the KS test (see Table 2), which demonstrates that the most indicated distributions are the skew-normal and the generalized hyperbolic while the Gaussian and the generalized Pareto distributions do not seem to fit well.

Table 2 K–S test to detect the original distribution for the log-return time series

2.4 Calibration and numerical simulation

The parameters of a skew-geometric Brownian motion are calibrated through the maximum log-likelihood (MLE) estimation.

Let \(R^F_t\) be the returns of the corn price process defined in Eq. (18), then \(R^F_t=\mu t+\sigma Y^F_t\sim SN(\mu t,\sigma ^2 t,\beta )\). Hence, if \(r^C_t\) denote the observations of \(R^C_t\) over n periods, the likelihood function of \(R^C_t\) is

$$\begin{aligned} {\mathcal {L}}^C(\mu ,\sigma ,\beta )=\frac{2^n}{(\sigma \sqrt{t})^n} \prod _{t=1}^n \varphi \biggl ( \frac{r^C_t-\mu t}{\sigma \sqrt{t}}\biggr ) {\varPhi }\biggl ( \beta \frac{r^C_t-\mu t}{\sigma \sqrt{t}}\biggr ), \end{aligned}$$

and the estimated parameters can be found as

$$\begin{aligned} ({{\hat{\mu }}},{{\hat{\sigma }}},{{\hat{\beta }}})=\arg \biggl ( \max _{(\mu ,\sigma ,\beta )} \ln {\mathcal {L}}^C(\mu ,\sigma ,\beta )\biggr ). \end{aligned}$$

The above procedure is implemented in the helpful R package of Azzalini (2021).

To estimate the correlation coefficient \(\rho \) we use the Spearman’s rank correlation (see, e.g., Wayne, 1990) between \(r^c_t\) and the observations \(r^F_t\) of \(R^F_t\). Then, Proposition 1 soon implies that

$$\begin{aligned} {{\hat{\alpha }}}= \frac{{{\hat{\beta }}}}{\sqrt{1+(1+{{\hat{\beta }}}^2)\biggl ( 1-\frac{2{{\hat{\delta }}}^2}{\pi }\biggr )\biggl ( \frac{1}{{{\hat{\rho }}}^2}-1\biggr )}}, \end{aligned}$$

where \({{\hat{\delta }}}=\frac{{{\hat{\beta }}}}{\sqrt{1+{{\hat{\beta }}}^2}}\) (see also Appendix A).

Finally, following Bufalo et al. (2022, Section 5.1), the likelihood function of the correlated process \(R^F_t=\theta t+\eta Y^F_t\sim SN(\theta t,\eta ^2 t,\alpha )\) (conditioned to \(({{\hat{\alpha }}},{{\hat{\delta }}},{{\hat{\rho }}})\)) is

$$\begin{aligned}{} & {} {\mathcal {L}}^C(\theta ,\eta )=\frac{2^n}{\left( \eta \sqrt{{{\hat{\rho }}}^2 t+\left( 1-\frac{2{{\hat{\delta }}}^2}{\pi } \right) (1-{{\hat{\rho }}}^2)t }\right) ^n} \\{} & {} \quad \cdot \prod _{t=1}^n \varphi \left( \frac{r^F_t-\theta t}{\eta \sqrt{{{\hat{\rho }}}^2 t+\left( 1-\frac{2{{\hat{\delta }}}^2}{\pi } \right) (1-{{\hat{\rho }}}^2)t }} \right) {\varPhi }\left( {{\hat{\alpha }}} \frac{r^F_t-\theta t}{\eta \sqrt{{{\hat{\rho }}}^2 t+\left( 1-\frac{2{{\hat{\delta }}}^2}{\pi } \right) (1-{{\hat{\rho }}}^2)t }} \right) , \end{aligned}$$

and the remaining estimations can be found as

$$\begin{aligned} ({{\hat{\theta }}},{{\hat{\eta }}})=\arg \biggl ( \max _{(\theta ,\eta )} \ln {\mathcal {L}}^F(\theta ,\eta )\biggr ). \end{aligned}$$

In particular, in order to simulate the processes \(F_t,C_t\) under \({\mathbb {Q}}\), we use the risk-free rate r in their drift instead of the estimates \({{\hat{\mu }}},\,{{\hat{\theta }}}\), which are involved into the skew-Brownian motions \({{\bar{Y}}}^F_t,\,{{\bar{Y}}}^C_t\) (according to Eq. (16)).

The above parameters are estimated in the time horizon \([0,t_0]\), while the out of sample simulations regards the remaining period \((t_0,T]\). The simulations are taken through the mean of \(N=10^5\) trajectories of a discretized scheme for the processes \(C_t,F_t\).

Figure 6 shows the corn and gas prices (the solid black line and the dotted black one, in the horizon \([0,t_0]\) and \((t_0,T]\), respectively) versus the their future expected values (the solid blue line in \((t_0,T]\)). We set \(t_0=14\,Y,\, T=13\,Y\), according to the case study analyzed in Sect. 3. The dotted red lines represent the 95% confidence interval of our predictions, which are calculated according to Qi et al. (2022). Moreover, Table 3 lists the estimated parameters of our model for any \(t\in [0,t_0]\).

Fig. 6
figure 6

Upper figure. Real corn prices (past, i.e., \(t\in [0,t_0]\)—solid black line, and future, i.e., \(t\in (t_0,T]\)—dotted black line) versus forecasted corn prices (\(t\in (t_0,T]\)—solid blue line). Lower figure. Real gas prices (past, i.e, \(t\in [0,t_0]\)—solid black line, and future, i.e., \(t\in (t_0,T]\)—dotted black line) versus forecasted gas prices (\(t\in (t_0,T]\)—solid blue line). The dotted red line represent the 95% confidence interval. (Color figure online)

Table 3 Estimated parameters for the processes \(C_t\) and \(F_t\)

Observe that the correlation \(\rho \) is 0.2265, while Fig. 7 displays the Spearman’s correlation between \(C_t\) and \(F_t\) from \(t_0\) on, through a rolling window of (fixed) size equal to 60, i.e., 5 years. With a minimum value of 0.18, we can assess that the corn and gas time series are always correlated both before and after the starting date of project \(t_0\).

Fig. 7
figure 7

Spearman’s correlation between \(C_t\) and \(F_t\) computed for any \(t\in [t_0, T]\) through a rolling window of size 60 months

3 Case study

3.1 The project valuation with compound options approach

In this section we propose an ideal case study by using plausible parameters that involves all the steps to start a corn ethanol plant project with 20 million gallons total production capacity of fuel ethanol. With refer to Sect. 2.1, we set the construction-engineering phases equal to \(n=2\). The investor expects to pursues the engineering costs \(I_{0}\) at time \(t_{0}=0\), the construction investment \(I_{1}\) at time \(t_{1}=1\,Y\), the operating costs \(I_{2}\) at time \(t_{2}=3\,Y\) that lasts up to maturity \(T=13\,Y\).Footnote 4 We expect that in the operating period the plant is able to produce an expected quantity of fuel to be sold 1.818 million gallons per year (20 million gallons/11 Y) in order to obtain a total production capacity of 20 million gallons.

This corn ethanol plant involves a construction cost of 2.25 $/gallons and the plant expects to produce 20 million gallons of fuel ethanol in order to obtain \(I_{1}= \$\,45\) million (\(2.25 \times 20\) million gallons).Footnote 5 Once the construction investment is calculated, it is easy to calculate the engineering investment \(I_{0}\) as a percentage of \(I_{1}\) that in this case is equal to 2%, by obtaining \(I_{0} =\$\,0.90\) million. As above, to proceed in the operating period requires another investment \(I_{2}\) that includes production expenses such as labor and maintenance costs, administrative and insurance costs, fees. This cost is equal to 0.15 $/gallons \(\times \) 1.818 million gallons of fuel ethanol per year (our expected production).Footnote 6 The value of \(I_2=\$\,2.103\) million is calculated as the discounted sum of operating costs at time \(t_{2}=3\,Y\) that is the starting year of operating period by using a discount rate equal to \(i=8\)%.Footnote 7 Moreover, we use a conversion factor \({{\bar{\gamma }}}=3.09\) that has been chosen by using the average value of the range studied by Kirby and Davison (2010) that goes from 2.87 to 3.31. We set the parameters \(b_1,b_2\) of Eq. (7) equal to 1 and 2, respectively.Footnote 8 Before proceeding to apply our compound options model with stochastic parameters, we pursue a static Net Present Value (NPV) based on the simple Discounted Cash Flows (DCF) approach. This allows to make a comparison between the two approaches by discussing them. To make this analysis we consider the annual average of global prices of corn in terms of U.S. Dollars per BushelFootnote 9 and the U.S. all grades all formulations annual average retail gasoline prices in terms of Dollars per Gallon from 2011 to 2021.Footnote 10 By using a discount rate \(i=8\)%, a static DCF analysis is shown in Table 4.

Table 4 Discounted cash flows method

Following the DCF analysis, the investor should reject the corn ethanol plant project since it gives a negative result (NPV \(=\) \(-\) $ 1.096 million). At this point, we can apply the compound options approach by considering the stochastic nature of revenues and costs.

The analysis starts by calculating the project value \(E_{t_{2}}\) where the gasoline (\(F_{t}\)) and corn price (\(C_{t}\)) follows a skew-geometric Brownian motion (as described in Sect. 2.2). To obtain \(E_{t_{2}}\) we consider a simulation derived from the historical series of monthly global price of corn in terms of U.S. Dollars per BushelFootnote 11 and the U.S. all grades all formulations monthly retail gasoline prices in terms of Dollars per GallonFootnote 12 from January 1994 to September 2021. Since we consider monthly time series, we use a monthly expected quantity of fuel to be sold \(q=151\,515.15\) gallons (\(1\,818\,181/12\)).

The first step gives a project value \(E_{t_{2}}\) equal to $ 53.6 million after using a risk-free rate \(r=4\%\).Footnote 13 Then, we proceed via backward induction according the logic described in Eqs. 8 and 1 by using monthly instant times, and we obtain a real option (RO) value skew-geometric Brownian motion equal to $ 0.8 million. Moreover, we extrapolated the RO value under the geometric Brownian motion in order to make a comparison between it and our skew-geometric Brownian motion assumption.

All the values used for the NPV and compound options valuation are summarized in Table 5.

Table 5 Results of compound ROA

3.2 Sensitivity analysis

This section provides a sensitivity analysis of how the RO value under skew-geometric Brownian motion varies by changing \(t_1\), \(t_2\), \({{\bar{\gamma }}}\) and \(b_2\). Figure 8 shows that by delaying the time period of construction investment \(t_1\) or time period of operating investment \(t_2\), the RO value tends to increase. This is because the extension of the time period of project investment makes the project riskier about its future performance and the operational flexibility captured by RO value becomes more valuable. Figure 8 also shows that if the value of \({{\bar{\gamma }}}\) goes up, the RO value tends to increase. This is a quite intuitive aspect since by improving the conversion factor allows to makes the project more attractive. Moreover, we can also state that an increase in the plant efficiency intensity \(b_2\) increases average plant efficiency and the RO value.

Fig. 8
figure 8

From the top left to the right, first row: a RO values when \(t_1\in [1,36]\) (months), b RO values when \(t_2\in [330,350]\) (months). From the top left to the right, second row: a RO values when \({{\bar{\gamma }}} \in [3,3.2]\), b RO values when \(b_2\in [2,18]\). The red circle point denotes the RO value reported in Table 5, i.e., $ 0.8 million. (Color figure online)

3.3 Discussion of results

According the analysis made in the previous section, the corn ethanol plant investment is profitable for potential investor since the RO value under skew-geometric Brownian motion, equal to $ 0.8 million, is positive and quite high. In fact, we note that the ratio between the compound option value (\(c^m_2\)) and the investment to initiate the project (\(I_0\)) is higher than 1 to demonstrate the positive revenue-generating capacity of the plant (\(\frac{c^m_2}{I_0}=\frac{1.7}{0.9}=1.89>1\)). The profitability of the corn-ethanol plant is confirmed also by the RO value under Geometric-Brownian motion since its positive value is equal to $ 0.194 million, even if it is lower than RO value under skew-geometric Brownian motion. In fact, by making a comparison between these two RO values, we note that the compound options model based on geometric Brownian motion tends to underestimates the project value. This is because the skew-Brownian motion allows to price more adequately the irregularity of corn and gasoline prices in comparison to Geometric-Brownian motion. The compound options valuation under skew-Brownian motion encourages the corn-ethanol plant projects. These findings are in line with the studies of Pederson and Zou (2009) and Schmit et al. (2009). The RO value represents an ex-ante project valuation that allows to makes aware the investor about the future opportunities of the project. Differently from the classical Net Present Value (NPV), the RO value embeds the “optionality” to change investment decision during the lifetime of the project if a certain stage turns out to be unprofitable. The literature terms this as ‘managerial flexibility’. We have also shown a valuation comparison between NPV and RO approaches. Following the NPV method the investor should reject the corn-ethanol plant project since it is not able to value the managerial flexibility. So, we can state that, there is a huge difference between the discounted cash flows approach and our innovative approach. The standard indicator based on discounted cash flows method leads to a rejection of this corn-ethanol plant investments since it gives a negative results (NPV \(=\) \(-\) $ 1.096 million). This would represents a wrong support to decision making. Differently from the NPV, the corn-ethanol plant valuation based on our compound options approach increases in value (RO \(=\) + $ 0.8 million) since the model includes the managerial flexibility aspects and an adequate stochastic approach of prices evolution based on skew-Brownian motion. In this sense, the operational flexibility to activate the investment options at each stage—acting as compound options—is valuable. These results are in line with the study of Ross (1995) that explained that the NPV can lead to reject a project that should be accepted.

In this case study, a positive RO value means that the project appears attractive in financial terms in addition to pursue sustainability goal considering that it is viewed as a renewable investment. As the results of Sect. 3.1 show, despite the presence of uncertainty and sequential stage decisions, using compound ROA with skew-geometric Brownian motion driven price uncertainties and incorporating the value of managerial flexibility allows the investor to appropriately price corn ethanol plant projects.

4 Conclusions

This article proposes a methodology to value corn ethanol plant projects characterized by corn and gasoline price uncertainty. The staged nature of the decisions available to the project owner arises because the investor proceeds with the following investment only if it is on average profitable given the information obtained at the end of the previous stage. To consider these valuation characteristics, we adopt compound ROA modelling corn and gasoline prices to follow, in accordance with historical data, skew-geometric Brownian motions. We also propose a case study to apply our valuation methodology to likely data. The results show that the corn ethanol plant project appears attractive and financially profitable by using compound ROA with skew-geometric Brownian motions for corn and gasoline prices. By adding these results to the sustainability goal of the plant allows to have a wider vision of the benefits of the renewable investments like this. In this paper we model a corn ethanol plant valuation as a compound options approach with stochastic revenues and costs parameters. Further research can embed in this approach the option to abandon the corn ethanol plant project for a salvage value. This would allow to provide a broader view of the operational flexibility insight in the project valuation. In addition, it could be interesting to determine, as another subsequent contribution, an optimal time in which, before reaching the lifetime ends in which efficiency approaches zero, it is advisable to replace the plant with a new one, modelled as the real option to switch.