Skip to main content
Log in

Classification of objects into quality categories in the presence of hierarchical decision-making agents

  • General Paper
  • Published:
Accreditation and Quality Assurance Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

In many practical contexts, it is often required to classify some objects of interest into predetermined unordered quality categories. This operation—referred to as quality classification problem—has received considerable attention in many fields of research, such as Analytical Chemistry, Materials Science, Medicine, Manufacturing, Quality Engineering/Management, Decision Analysis. Assuming that multiple agents perform subjective assignments of categories to the objects of interest, a further problem is that of fusing these assignments into global classifications. To this purpose, the mode and the weighted mode are very practical measures, as long as agents are equi-important or their (different) importance is expressed in the form of a set of weights. Unfortunately, these measures are not appropriate for quality classification problems where the agents’ importance is expressed in the form of a rank ordering (hierarchy). The aim of this article is to present a new method, which addresses the latter quality classification problem in a relatively simple and practical way. The peculiarity of this method is that the different importance of agents determines a different priority in considering their assignments and not a different weight of these assignments. A detailed description of the new method is supported by a realistic example in the Analytical Chemistry field.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1
Fig. 2
Fig. 3

Similar content being viewed by others

References

  1. Stevens SS (1946) On the theory of scales of measurement. Science 103(2684):677–680

    Article  Google Scholar 

  2. Léger J, Martel JM (2002) A multicriteria assignment procedure for a nominal sorting problematic. Eur J Oper Res 138(2):349–364

    Article  Google Scholar 

  3. Zopounidis C, Doumpos M (2002) Multicriteria classification and sorting methods: a literature review. Eur J Oper Res 138(2):229–246

    Article  Google Scholar 

  4. Van Wieringen WN, De Mast J (2008) Measurement system analysis for binary data. Technometrics 50(4):468–478

    Article  Google Scholar 

  5. Belhoul L, Galand L, Vanderpooten D (2014) An efficient procedure for finding best compromise solutions to the multi-objective assignment problem. Comput Oper Res 49:97–106

    Article  Google Scholar 

  6. Ho LL, da Costa Quinino R, Galindo TA (2011) An np-control chart for inspection errors and repeated classifications. Qual Reliab Eng Int 27:1087–1093

    Article  Google Scholar 

  7. Bashkansky E, Gadrich T (2008) Evaluating quality measured on a ternary ordinal scale. Qual Reliab Eng Int 24:957–971

    Article  Google Scholar 

  8. Franceschini F, Galetto M, Maisano D (2007) Management by measurement: designing key indicators and performance measurement systems. Springer, Berlin

    Google Scholar 

  9. King B (2003) The selection and use of reference materials—a basic guide for laboratories and accreditation bodies. Accred Qual Assur 8(9):429–433

    Article  CAS  Google Scholar 

  10. ISO/TR 79:2015 (2015) Reference materials—examples of reference materials for qualitative properties, first edition 2015-04-15. International Organization for Standardization, Geneva

    Google Scholar 

  11. Jones BA, Bekeris LG, Nakhleh RE, Walsh MK, Valenstein PN (2009) Physician satisfaction with clinical laboratory services: a College of American Pathologists Q-probes study of 138 institutions. Arch Pathol Lab Med 133(1):38–43

    Google Scholar 

  12. ISO Guide 35:2006 (2006) Reference materials—general and statistical principles for certification. International Organization for Standardization (ISO), Geneva

    Google Scholar 

  13. Michalowski W, Rubin S, Slowinski R, Wilk S (2001) Triage of the child with abdominal pain: a clinical algorithm for emergency patient management. Paediatr Child Health 6(1):23–28

    Article  CAS  Google Scholar 

  14. World Health Organization (2010) International classification of diseases, 10th revision (ICD-10). Switzerland World Health Organization, Geneva

    Google Scholar 

  15. Mayden RL (1997) A hierarchy of species concepts: the denouement in the saga of the species problem. In: Claridge MF, Dawah HA, Wilson MR (eds) Species: the units of biodiversity. Chapman and Hall, London, pp 381–394

    Google Scholar 

  16. Chien C-F, Hsu S-C, Chen Y-J (2013) A system for online detection and classification of wafer bin map defect patterns for manufacturing intelligence. Int J Prod Res 51(8):2324–2338

    Article  Google Scholar 

  17. Hatefi SM, Torabi SA, Bagheri P (2014) Multi-criteria ABC inventory classification with mixed quantitative and qualitative criteria. Int J Prod Res 52(3):776–786

    Article  Google Scholar 

  18. Suvdaa B, Ahn J, Ko J (2012) Steel surface defects detection and classification using SIFT and voting strategy. Int J Softw Eng Its Appl 6(2):161–166

    Google Scholar 

  19. Häcker J, Engelhardt F, Freyw DD (2002) Robust manufacturing inspection and classification with machine vision. Int J Prod Res 40(6):1319–1334

    Article  Google Scholar 

  20. Chaudha A, Jain R, Singh AR, Mishra PK (2011) Integration of Kano’s model into quality function deployment (QFD). Int J Adv Manuf Technol 53(5–8):689–698

    Article  Google Scholar 

  21. Fung RYK, Tang J, Yiliu T, Chen Y (2003) Modelling of quality function deployment planning with resource allocation. Res Eng Des 14(4):247–255

    Article  Google Scholar 

  22. Van de Poel I (2007) Methodological problems in QFD and directions for future development. Res Eng Des 18(1):21–36

    Article  Google Scholar 

  23. Franceschini F, Maisano D, Mastrogiacomo L (2015) Customer requirement prioritization on QFD: a new proposal based on the generalized Yager’s algorithm. Res Eng Des 26(2):171–187

    Article  Google Scholar 

  24. Gochet W, Stam A, Srinivasan V, Chen S (1997) Multigroup discriminant analysis using linear programming. Oper Res 45(2):213–225

    Article  Google Scholar 

  25. Nieddu L, Patrizi G (2000) Formal methods in pattern recognition: a review. Eur J Oper Res 120(3):459–495

    Article  Google Scholar 

  26. Abrizah A, Zainab AN, Kiran K, Raj RG (2013) LIS journals scientific impact and subject categorization: a comparison between Web of Science and Scopus. Scientometrics 94(2):721–740

    Article  Google Scholar 

  27. Agresti A (2013) Categorical data analysis. Wiley, Hoboken

    Google Scholar 

  28. Nordin G, Dybkaer R, Forsum U, Fuentes-Arderiu X, Pontet F (2015) Vocabulary for nominal properties and nominal examinations—basic and general concepts and associated terms. IFCC-IUPAC recommendation 2015

  29. Kelly JS (1991) Social choice bibliography. Soc Choice Welf 8:97–169

    Google Scholar 

  30. Dubois D, Godo L, Prade H (2012) Weighted logics for artificial intelligence: an introductory discussion. In: Proceedings of the 20th European Conference on Artificial Intelligence (ECAI) Conference, Technical Report-IIIA-2012-04, 1-6, 28th August 2012, Montpellier, France

  31. Saaty TL (1980) The analytic hierarchy process: planning, priority and allocation. McGraw-Hill, New York

    Google Scholar 

  32. Ramanathan R, Ganesh LS (1994) Group preference aggregation methods employed in AHP: an evaluation and an intrinsic process for deriving members’ weightages. Eur J Oper Res 79(2):249–265

    Article  Google Scholar 

  33. Wang B, Liang J, Qian Y (2014) Determining decision makers’ weights in group ranking: a granular computing method. Int J Mach Learn Cybern. doi:10.1007/s13042-014-0278-5

    Google Scholar 

  34. Franceschini F, Maisano D, Mastrogiacomo L (2015) A novel algorithm for fusing preference orderings by rank-ordered agents. Fuzzy Sets Syst 266:84–100

    Article  Google Scholar 

  35. Franceschini F, Maisano D (2017) Consistency analysis in quality classification problems with multiple rank-ordered agents. Qual Eng. doi:10.1080/08982112.2016.1255332

    Google Scholar 

  36. Nederpelt R, Kamareddine F (2004) Logical reasoning: a first course. King’s College Publications, London

    Google Scholar 

  37. Tan KC, Shen XX (2000) Integrating Kano’s model in the planning matrix of quality function deployment. Total Qual Manag 11(8):1141–1151

    Article  Google Scholar 

  38. Franceschini F, Maisano D, Mastrogiacomo L (2015) Checking the consistency of solutions in ordinal semi-democratic decision-making problems. OMEGA 57(1):188–195

    Article  Google Scholar 

  39. Chen S, Liu J, Wang H, Augusto JC (2012) Ordering based decision making—a survey. Inf Fusion 14(4):521–531

    Article  Google Scholar 

  40. Jianqiang W (2007) Fusion of multiagent preference orderings with information on agent’s importance being incomplete certain. J Syst Eng Electron 18(4):801–805

    Article  Google Scholar 

  41. Brans JP, Mareschal B (2005) Multiple criteria decision analysis: state of the art surveys. In: Figueira J, Greco S, Ehrgott M (eds) Promethee methods. Springer-International series in operations research and management science, Berlin, pp 163–195

    Google Scholar 

  42. Figueira J, Greco S, Ehrgott M (2005) Multiple criteria decision analysis: state of the art surveys. Springer, New York

    Book  Google Scholar 

  43. De Mast J, Van Wieringen WN (2010) Modeling and evaluating repeatability and reproducibility of ordinal classifications. Technometrics 52(1):94–106

    Article  Google Scholar 

  44. Ross SM (2014) Introduction to probability and statistics for engineers and scientists, 5th edn. Academic Press, London

    Google Scholar 

  45. Arrow KJ, Raynaud H (1986) Social choice and multicriterion decision-making. The MIT Press, Cambridge

    Google Scholar 

  46. May K (1952) A set of independent, necessary and sufficient conditions for simple majority decisions. Econometrica 20:680–684

    Article  Google Scholar 

  47. Fishburn PC (1973) The theory of social choice. Princeton University Press, Princeton

    Google Scholar 

  48. Sen AK (1970) Collective choice and social welfare. Holden-Day, San Francisco

    Google Scholar 

  49. Yager RR (2001) Fusion of multi-agent preference orderings. Fuzzy Sets Syst 117(1):1–12

    Article  Google Scholar 

  50. Dym CL, Wood WH, Scott MJ (2002) Rank ordering engineering designs: pairwise comparison charts and Borda counts. Res Eng Des 13(4):236–242

    Article  Google Scholar 

  51. Kano N, Seraku N, Takahashi F, Tsuji S (1984) Attractive quality and must-be quality, Hinshitsu. Qual J Jpn Soc Qual Control 14:39–48

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Fiorenzo Franceschini.

Appendix

Appendix

Further considerations on the range of no-voting-order-effect

Let us provide a formal proof that when \(t \in \left] {{m \mathord{\left/ {\vphantom {m 2}} \right. \kern-0pt} 2},m} \right]\) (i.e., t is included in the no-voting-order-effect range), the global quality classification does not depend on the voting sequence.

For a single object of interest, given that (1) the sum of the scores (s) assigned by agents (d) to the quality categories (c) is equal to m (see weight definition in Table 4), i.e.,

$$\sum\limits_{d} {\sum\limits_{c} {s\left( {c,d} \right)} = m} ,$$
(5)

and (2) m/2 < t ≤ m, if there exists a quality category (c*) whose total score (obtained cumulating the scores assigned by the m agents) exceeds t, i.e.,

$${\text{one}}\,{\text{element}}\,c^{*} \,{\text{exists}}|\frac{m}{2} < t \le \sum\limits_{d} {s\left( {c^{*} ,d} \right)} \le m,$$
(6)

then c* will be the only global quality category, since the total score of no other category will be able to reach t, no matter the agents’ rank ordering.

Assuming ad absurdum that there exists a second global quality category (c ), then we would have that

$$\sum\limits_{d} {s\left( {c^{*} ,d} \right) \ge t} > \frac{m}{2}\quad {\text{and}}\quad \sum\limits_{d} {s\left( {c^{\dag } ,d} \right)} \ge t > \frac{m}{2},$$
(7)

since the total scores of c* and c would be both supposed to reach t. The sum of the total scores of the two quality categories c* and c (neglecting the remaining ones) would therefore be

$$\sum\limits_{d} {s\left( {c^{*} ,d} \right)} + \sum\limits_{d} {s\left( {c^{\dag } ,d} \right)} \ge 2 \cdot t > m,$$
(8)

which is absurd, because it is incompatible with the condition in Eq. 5.

This demonstrates that if \(t \in \left] {{m \mathord{\left/ {\vphantom {m 2}} \right. \kern-0pt} 2},m} \right]\) and a quality category c* has a total score exceeding t, this category will be the only global quality category, independently on the agents’ rank ordering.

Further considerations on the axiom of independence of irrelevant alternatives

This section provides a proof that the proposed method does not satisfy the axiom of independence of irrelevant alternatives (IIA).

Consider a quality classification problem where an object has been evaluated by three agents (d 1 > d 2 > d 3) and classified into 4 quality categories (c 1c 4) as follows:

$$\begin{aligned} & d_{1} :c_{3} ,c_{4} ; \\ & d_{2} :c_{1} ; \\ & d_{3} :c_{1} ,c_{2} ,c_{3} ,c_{4} . \\ \end{aligned}$$

In this case M = m = 3, so let us assume t = 1.25 and q = 1.5. Then, according to the proposed procedure, category c 1 is selected at turn 3 with a cumulative score of 1.25. Let us comment this result. We notice that c 1 is selected by d 2 and d 3, while quality categories c 3 and c 4 are selected by d 1 and d 3, but overall they are not selected (their cumulative scores are both 0.75), although they are chosen by a more important agent (d 1). The reason is that the assignments by d 1 and d 3 are both multiple and inherently uncertain, and consequently the relevant scores are fractionalized; on the other hand, the single assignment by d 2 entails a full score to c 1.

Now assume that quality category c 4 is removed from the analysis:

$$\begin{aligned} & d_{1} :c_{3} ; \\ & d_{2} :c_{1} ; \\ & d_{3} :c_{1} ,c_{2} ,c_{3} . \\ \end{aligned}$$

In this case, c 1 and c 3 are both selected, each having a score of 1.33 at turn 3. It is clear that the removal of the “non-global” quality category c 4 changed the result, thus leading to a violation of the IIA axiom. It can be shown that, in the particular case in which agents classify the object into a single quality category (i.e., no multiple assignments), the IIA axiom is fulfilled.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Franceschini, F., Maisano, D. Classification of objects into quality categories in the presence of hierarchical decision-making agents. Accred Qual Assur 23, 5–17 (2018). https://doi.org/10.1007/s00769-017-1291-7

Download citation

  • Received:

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s00769-017-1291-7

Keywords

Navigation