Skip to main content

The Human Capital Transition and the Role of Policy

  • Reference work entry
  • First Online:
Handbook of Cliometrics

Abstract

Along with information and communication technology, infrastructure, and the innovation system, human capital is a key pillar of the knowledge economy with its scope for increasing returns. With this in mind, the purpose of this chapter is to investigate how industrialized economies managed to achieve the transition from low to high levels of human capital. The first phase of the human capital transition was the result of the interaction of supply and demand, triggered by technological change and boosted by the demands for (immaterial) services. The second phase of the human capital transition (i.e., mass education) resulted from enforced legislation and major public investment. The state’s aim to influence children’s beliefs appears to have been a key driver in public investment. Nevertheless, the roles governments played differed according to the developmental status and inherent socioeconomic and political characteristics of their countries. These features of the human capital transition highlight the importance of understanding governments’ incentives and roles in transitions.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this chapter

Institutional subscriptions

Notes

  1. 1.

    In contrast, another strand of the literature suggests that there might also be negative externalities because human capital would not increase productivities but only waste valuable resources due to signaling effects (e.g. Spence 1973). However, Lange and Topel (2006) do not find important negative impacts; the positive effects largely dominate.

  2. 2.

    In addition, the assumption of perfect competitive markets implies that capital markets should be perfectly functioning. In this case, parents should always be able to find a way of financing the education of their children. This, however, is not the case either (Johnes 1993).

  3. 3.

    For example, the existence of public schools may have led to a monopoly of these schools in certain geographical areas. Taking the point of view of the market, schools may thus not have been under market pressure to ensure quality standards and low operating costs. Some recent reforms have been aimed at improving the status quo and in part reorganizing the involvement of the state in this sector (Brewer et al. 2010).

  4. 4.

    For example, Milton Friedman also suggests that “a stable and democratic society is impossible without a minimum degree of literacy and knowledge on the part of most citizens and without widespread acceptance of some common set of values. Education can contribute to both” (Friedman 1962, p. 86; in Gradstein et al. 2005, p. 5). He further argues that “the major problem in the United States in the 19th and early twentieth century was not to promote diversity but to create the core of common values essential to a stable society… Immigrants were flooding the United States… speaking different languages and observing diverse customs … The public school had an important function in this task, not least by imposing English as a common language” (Friedman 1962, p. 96, in Gradstein et al. 2005, p. 9).

  5. 5.

    According to Sweetland (1996), the area of education can be further broken down: “[t]here is formalized education at primary, secondary, and higher levels (Cohn and Geske 1990), informal education at home and at work (Schultz 1981), on-the-job training and apprenticeships (Mincer 1974), and specialized vocational education at secondary and higher levels (Corazzini 1967)” (Sweetland 1996, p. 341).

  6. 6.

    An interesting question is whether there were also incentives for inventing technologies to sidestep the guilds. Epstein mentions that inventors had an incentive to keep their inventions secret from the guild. Yet, “although technical secrets were often kept within the craftsman’s family, it is unlikely that significant breakthroughs could withstand a guild’s scrutiny for long. On the other hand, an inventor had to weigh the guild’s offer of a temporary quasi-monopoly rent against the possibility of obtaining a one-off royalty (net of migration costs) from a rival craft or government” (1998 p. 704).

  7. 7.

    A comment from the early 1960s, after the decline in this form of training, summarizes what happened: “apprenticeship has all but disappeared, partly because it is now inefficient and partly because schools now perform many of its functions. Its disappearance has been hastened no doubt by the difficulty of enforcing apprenticeship agreements. Legally they have come to smack of indentured service” (Schultz 1961, p. 10).

  8. 8.

    They estimate this number in the following way: “Assuming that youths would earn a rising fraction of adult income with age (20% at age 14, 40% at age 15, 60% at age 16, 70% at age 17, 80% at age 18, 90% at age 19, and [100]% at age 20 – see Van Zanden (2009b), p. 160), a provincial adult unskilled wage of 1 s per day, that youths work 228 days per year (Voth 2001), and a discount rate of 7.5%, the present value of lost earnings during an apprenticeship, relative to a subsistence income of £5 per annum, was about 26 pounds” (Minns and Wallis 2013, p. 344).

  9. 9.

    In fact, the printing press was first invented in Korea. For more details, see Hippe (2015).

  10. 10.

    This fall in prices also had a major impact on the spread of the ideas of Protestantism. For example, Luther’s translation of the New Testament in 1522 was affordable even to laborers (Stöber 2004).

  11. 11.

    Similarly, Clark (2004, p. 8) calculates that “the estimated price of a standard page of text in the middle ages was 50 times the price in 1700–59.”

  12. 12.

    See Ekelund et al. (2002) for an economic interpretation of the Protestant reformation and Ekelund et al. (2004) for an exploration of the economics of the Counter-Reformation.

  13. 13.

    The question whether religious competition leads to more or less religious participation by individuals is still disputed. On the one hand, it is argued that the existence of various religions leads to a decrease in the plausibility of a given religion and thus less religious participation (Chaves and Gorski 2001). On the other hand, authors such as Adam Smith suggest that a non-state-sponsored religious group has to provide special care for its believers, raising the quality of and participation rate in religious activities (Iannaccone et al. 1997). For more information, see Höhener and Schaltegger (2012).

  14. 14.

    More generally, the authors see the values in formal education close to those of Protestantism, as highlighted by Weber (1958): “formal education’s emphasis on individual socialization and achievement parallels the Protestant emphasis on the individual’s unmediated relation to God and individual salvation” (Soysal and Strang 1989, p. 279).

  15. 15.

    Numbers from France emphasize the stark increase in newspaper production: “[i]n 1840 the monthly issue of all the Paris journals totalled less than three million copies. By 1882 it was up to 44 million copies (Cipolla 1969, p. 107).”

  16. 16.

    The same can be said of the evolution in numeracy (A’Hearn et al. 2009).

  17. 17.

    He distinguishes three cases: egalitarian, elite, and autocratic forms of power distribution. In the egalitarian case, the preferences of the majority were implemented by the elites. Thus, there was a high risk that policy measures were simply redundant or not meeting private demand. In these societies, the acquisition of education meant the prospect of moving up the social ladder, leading to popular demand. When the powers in society were more concentrated but upward mobility was still possible (e.g., in France and Germany), the effectiveness of public educational policy was probably higher. Finally, in the case of more autocratic forms of government, when power was extremely concentrated (such as in Spain and Portugal) and the masses lived at low standards of living, public action was ineffective. On the one hand, demand was low and actions by the state were perceived as intruding into family life. On the other hand, local elites blocked educational changes that may have been intended at the national level (Mitch 1992b).

  18. 18.

    Overall, the Prussian kings were not fervent promoters of the spread of mass education. They “did as much, and said as much, to block schooling and free thought as to spread it” (Lindert 2004, p. 118).

  19. 19.

    Here, it is assumed that all regions benefit socially from higher education levels.

  20. 20.

    Some studies have suggested the existence of a human capital Kuznets curve, adapting the idea of Kuznets (1955) to education. In other words, increases in human capital inequality in earlier phases are followed by subsequent reductions in human capital inequality in later phases of economic development. For empirical contributions, see, e.g., De Gregorio and Lee (2002), Castello and Domenech (2002), Lim and Tang (2008), and Morrisson and Murtin (2013); for theoretical models see, e.g., Galor and Tsiddon (1996), Glomm and Ravikumar (1998), and Matsuo and Tomoda (2012).

  21. 21.

    The level of salaries was quite diverse across Europe. However, for the most part, they seem to have been low. Thus, Cipolla (1969) suggests that the average salary of a teacher was comparable to that of a craftsman before the nineteenth century. In addition, the social status of teachers still varied importantly from one European country to the other in the nineteenth century. For example, teachers enjoyed high public respect in Germany (and Prussia in particular) (Cipolla 1969). Social prestige and income may thus be causes of high quality. Perhaps a long-standing tradition of the teaching profession was also an important factor. In contrast, schoolmasters and mistresses did not have a good reputation and did not have much prestige in England and southern Italy in the nineteenth century.

  22. 22.

    It uses a particular heaping phenomenon in the age distribution of censuses and other comparable data to calculate numeracy levels. More specifically, individuals over-reported ages ending in 0 and 5 to census takers, leading to significant spikes in the age distribution. The reason for this was that they were not able to count and to know their exact age, so that they rounded it. This is a well-known phenomenon that can be found in historical sources and in a range of developing countries today. For further information, see A’Hearn et al. (2009), Hippe and Baten (2012), Hippe (2012, 2013b, 2014).

References

  • A’Hearn B, Crayen D, Baten J (2009) Quantifying quantitative literacy: age heaping and the history of human capital. J Econ Hist, Cambridge University Press 68(3):783–808

    Google Scholar 

  • Adick C (2003) Globale Trends weltweiter Schulentwicklung: Empirische Befunde und theoretische Erklärungen. Z Erzieh 6(2):173–187

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Aghion P, Howitt P (1992) A model of growth through creative destruction. Econometrica 60:323–351

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Aghion P, Howitt P (1998) Endogenous growth theory. MIT Press, Cambridge

    Google Scholar 

  • Alesina A, Reich B (2013) Nation building, NBER working paper 18839, Feb 2013

    Google Scholar 

  • Alesina A, Spolaore E (2005) The size of nations. MIT Press, Cambridge

    Google Scholar 

  • Anderson CA (1965) Literacy and schooling on the development threshold: some historical cases. In: Anderson CA, Bowman MJ (eds) Education and economic development. Aldine, Chicago, pp 347–362

    Google Scholar 

  • Ang JB, Madsen JB (2011) Can second-generation endogenous growth models explain the productivity trends and knowledge production in the asian miracle economies? Rev Econ Stat 93(4):1360–1373

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Archer M (1979) Social origins of educational system. Sage, Beverly Hills

    Google Scholar 

  • Barro RJ (1991) Economic growth in a cross section of countries. Q J Econ 106(2):407–443

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Barro RJ, Lee JW (1993) International comparisons of educational attainment. J Monet Econ 32:363–394

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Baten J, Hippe R (2017) Geography, land inequality and regional numeracy in Europe in historical perspective. J Econ Growth 23(1):79–109

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Becker GS (1964) Human capital: a theoretical and empirical analysis with special reference to education, 1st edn. University of Chicago Press, Chicago

    Google Scholar 

  • Becker GS (1981) A treatise on the family. Harvard University Press, Cambridge

    Google Scholar 

  • Becker GS (1993) Human capital: a theoretical and empirical analysis with special reference to education, 3rd edn. University of Chicago Press, Chicago

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Becker SO, Woessmann L (2008) Luther and the girls: religious denomination and the female education gap in nineteenth-century Prussia. Scand J Econ 110(4):777–805

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Becker SO, Woessmann L (2009) Was weber wrong? A human capital theory of protestant economic history. Q J Econ 124(2):531–596

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Becker SO, Hornung E, Woessmann L (2011) Education and catch-up in the industrial revolution. Am Econ J Macroecon 3(3):92–126

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Benhabib J, Spiegel MM (1994) The role of human capital in economic development: evidence from aggregate cross-country and regional U.S. data. J Monet Econ 34(2):143–173

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Biller P, Hudson A (eds) (1996) Heresy and literacy, 1000–1530. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge

    Google Scholar 

  • Boli J (1992) Institutions, citizenship, and schooling in Sweden. In: Fuller B, Rubinson R (eds) The political construction of education. The State, State Expansion and Economic Change, Praeger, New York

    Google Scholar 

  • Bolt J, van Zanden JL (2014) The maddison project: collaborative research on historical national accounts. Econ Hist Rev 67(3):627–651

    Google Scholar 

  • Bowles S, Gintis H (1976) Schooling in capitalist America: educational reform and the contradictions of economic life. Basic Books, New York

    Google Scholar 

  • Brewer DJ, Hentschke GC, Eide ER (2010) Theoretical concepts in the economics of education. In: Brewer DJ, McEwan PJ (eds) Economics of education. Elsevier, Oxford

    Google Scholar 

  • Briggs J (1978) An italian passage. Yale University Press, New Haven

    Google Scholar 

  • Buringh E, van Zanden JL (2009) Charting the “Rise of the west”: manuscripts and printed books in Europe, a long-term perspective from the sixth through eighteenth centuries. J Econ Hist 69(2):409–445

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Campbell R (1747) The London Tradesman, being a compendious view of all the trades, professions, arts, both liberal and mechanic, now practised in the cities of London and Westminster. T. Gardner, London

    Google Scholar 

  • Carnoy M, Levin H (1985) Schooling and work in the democratic state. Stanford University Press, Stanford

    Google Scholar 

  • Carpentier V (2007) Education Policymaking: economic and social progress. mimeo, London

    Google Scholar 

  • Castello A, Domenech R (2002) Human capital inequality and economic growth: some new evidence. Econ J 112:187–200

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Chappell W (1970) A short history of the printed word. Nonpareil Books, Boston

    Google Scholar 

  • Chassant LA (1846) Dictionnaire des abréviations latines et françaises usitées dans les inscriptions lapidaires et métalliques, les manuscrits et les chartes du Moyen Âge. Cornemillot, Evreux

    Google Scholar 

  • Chaves M, Gorski PS (2001) Religious pluralism and religious participation. Annu Rev Sociol 27:261–281

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ciccone A, Papaioannou E (2009) Human capital, the structure of production, and growth. Rev Econ Stat 91(1):66–82

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cipolla CM (1969) Literacy and development in the West. Penguin Books, Baltimore

    Google Scholar 

  • Cipolla CM (1980) Before the industrial revolution: European society and economy, 1000–1700. Norton, New York

    Google Scholar 

  • Clark G (2004) Lifestyles of the rich and famous: living costs of the rich versus the poor in England, 1209–1869. In: Paper presented in conference “Towards a global history of prices and wages”. Available online at http://www.iisg.nl/hpw/papers/clark.pdf

  • Clark G (2007) A farewell to alms. Princeton University Press, Princeton

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Clark G, Levin P (2001) How different was the industrial revolution? The revolution in printing, 1350–1869, Working paper. University of California, Davis

    Google Scholar 

  • Cohen D, Soto M (2007) Growth and human capital: good data, good results. J Econ Growth 12:51–76

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cohn E, Geske TG (1990) The economics of education. Pergamon Press, New York

    Google Scholar 

  • Collins A, Halverson R (2010) The second educational revolution: rethinking education in the age of technology. J Comput Assist Learn 26:18–27

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cook SDN (2006) Technological revolutions and the Gutenberg myth. In: Hassan R, Thomas J (eds) The new media theory reader. McGraw-Hill, Berkshire (originally published in Internet Dreams (1997), MIT Press, Cambridge, MA)

    Google Scholar 

  • Corazzini AJ (1967) When should vocational education begin? J Hum Resour 2:41–50

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Council of the European Union (2009) Council conclusions of 12 May 2009 on a strategic framework for European cooperation in education and training (‘ET 2020’), C119/2, online. Last accessed on 22 Nov 2017. http://www.cedefop.europa.eu/EN/Files/ET_2020.pdf

  • Crayen D, Baten J (2010) Global trends in numeracy 1820–1949 and its implications for long-run growth. Explor Econ Hist 47:82–99

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cressy D (1980) Literacy and the social order: reading and writing in Tudor and Stuart England. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge, UK

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Cuijpers PMH (1998) Teksten als koopwaar: vroege drukkers verkennen de markt: een kwantitatieve analyse van de productie van Nederlandstalige boeken (tot circa 1550) en de ‘lezershulp’ in de seculiere prozateksten. De Graaf, Nieuwkoop

    Google Scholar 

  • De Gregorio J, Lee JW (2002) Education and income inequality: new evidence from cross-country data. Rev Income Wealth 51:395–416

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • De La Fuente A, Doménech R (2006) Human capital in growth regressions: how much difference does data quality make? J Eur Econ Assoc 4:1–36

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Demeulemeester JL, Diebolt C (2011) Education and growth: what links for which policy? Hist Soc Res 36(4):323–346

    Google Scholar 

  • Diebolt C (2000) Die Erfassung der Bildungsinvestitionen im 19. und 20. Jahrhundert. Z Erzieh 3(4):517–538

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Diebolt C, Fontvieille L (2001) Dynamic forces in educational development: a long-run comparative view of France and Germany in the 19th and 20th centuries. Compare 31(3):295–309

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Diebolt C, Hippe R (2017) Regional human capital inequality in Europe, 1850–2010. Région et Développement 45:5–30

    Google Scholar 

  • Diebolt C, Hippe R (2018a) Remoteness equals backwardness? Human capital and market access in the European regions: insights from the long run. Educ Econ 26(3):285–304

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Diebolt C, Hippe R (2018b) The long-run impact of human capital on innovation and economic development in the regions of Europe. Appl Econ. https://doi.org/10.1080/00036846.2018.1495820

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Diebolt C, Hippe R, Jaoul-Grammare M (2018) Bildungsökonomie. Eine Einführung aus historischer Perspektive [Education Economics. An introduction in historical perspective; in German]. Springer, Wiesbaden

    Google Scholar 

  • Dittmar J (2013) New media, firms, ideas, and growth: European cities after Gutenberg. National Bureau of Economic Research, Cambridge, MA

    Google Scholar 

  • Ekelund RB, Hébert RF, Tollison RD (2002) An economic analysis of the protestant reformation. J Polit Econ 110(3):646–671

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ekelund RB, Hébert RF, Tollison RD (2004) The economics of the counter-reformation: incumbent-firm reaction to market entry. Econ Inq 42(4):690–705

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Engelsing R (1973) Analphabetentum und Lektüre: Zur Sozialgeschichte des Lesens in Deutschland zwischen feudaler und industrieller Gesellschaft. Metzler, Stuttgart

    Google Scholar 

  • Epstein SR (1998) Craft guilds, apprenticeship, and technological change in preindustrial Europe. J Econ Hist 58(3):684–713

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Epstein SR (2004) Property rights to technical knowledge in premodern Europe, 1300–1800. Am Econ Rev 94(2):382–387

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fouquet R (2008) Heat, power and light: revolutions in energy services. Edward Elgar Publications, Cheltenham/Northampton

    Google Scholar 

  • Fouquet R, Broadberry S (2015) Seven centuries of European economic growth and decline. J Econ Perspect 29(4):227–244

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fourrier C (1965) L’Enseignement Francais de 1789 à 1945. Institut Pédagogique National, Paris

    Google Scholar 

  • Friedman M (1962) Capitalism and freedom. University of Chicago Press, Chicago

    Google Scholar 

  • Fuller B (1983) Youth job structure and school enrollment, 1890–1920. Sociol Educ 56:145–156

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fuller B, Rubinson R (1992) Does the state expand schooling? Review of the evidence. In: Fuller B, Rubinson R (eds) The political construction of education. The State, State Expansion and Economic Change, Praeger, New York

    Google Scholar 

  • Galor O (2005) From stagnation to growth: unified growth theory. In: Aghion P, Durlauf SN (eds) Handbook of economic growth, vol 1A. North Holland, Amsterdam, pp 171–293

    Google Scholar 

  • Galor O (2011) Inequality, human capital formation, and the process of development. In: Hanushek EA, Machin S, Woessmann L (eds) Handbook of the economics of education, vol 4. Elsevier, Oxford, pp 441–493

    Chapter  Google Scholar 

  • Galor O, Moav O (2002) Natural selection and the origin of economic growth. Q J Econ 117:1133–1192

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Galor O, Tsiddon D (1996) Income distribution and growth: the Kuznets hypothesis revisited. Economica 63:103–117

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Galor O, Weil DN (2000) Population, technology and growth: from the malthusian regime to the demographic transition. Am Econ Rev 90(4):806–828

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Galor O, Moav O, Vollrath D (2009) Inequality in landownership, the emergence of human-capital promoting institutions, and the great divergence. Rev Econ Stud 76:143–179

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gennaioli N, La Porta R, Lopez-de-Silanes F, Shleifer A (2013) Human capital and regional development. Q J Econ 128(1):105–164

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gilmont JF (1999) Protestant reformations and reading. In: Cavallo G, Chartier R (eds) A history of reading in the West. Polity Press, Oxford, pp 213–237

    Google Scholar 

  • Glenn CL (2012) Educational freedom and protestant schools in Europe. In: Jeynes W, Robinson DW (eds) International handbook of protestant education. Springer Science+Business Media B.V., Dordrecht, pp 139–161

    Chapter  Google Scholar 

  • Glomm G, Ravikumar B (1998) Increasing returns, human capital, and the Kuznets curve. J Dev Econ 55:353–367

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gradstein M, Justman M, Meier V (2005) The political economy of education. Implications for growth and inequality. MIT Press, Cambridge

    Google Scholar 

  • Graff HJ (1991) The literacy myth. Transaction Publishers, New Brunswick

    Google Scholar 

  • Green H (1979) The education of women in the reformation. Hist Educ Q 19:93–116

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Green A (1990) Education and state formation. Macmillan, Hampshire

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Grossman GM, Helpman E (1991) Innovation and growth in the global economy. MIT Press, Cambridge

    Google Scholar 

  • Guellec D (2004) Gutenberg revisité. Une analyse économique de l’invention de l’imprimerie. Rev Écon Polit 114(2):169–199

    Google Scholar 

  • Hamilton K, Liu G (2014) Human capital, tangible wealth, and the intangible capital residual. Oxf Rev Econ Policy 30(1):70–91

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hanushek E, Kimko D (2000) Schooling, labor force quality, and the growth of nations. Am Econ Rev 90(5):1184–1208

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hanushek EA, Woessmann L (2008) The role of cognitive skills in economic development. J Econ Lit 46(3):607–668

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Harris JR (1998) Industrial espionage and technology transfer. Britain and France in the Eighteenth Century. Ashgate, Aldershot

    Google Scholar 

  • Hippe R (2012) How to measure human capital? The relationship between numeracy and literacy. Econ Soc 45(8):1527–1554

    Google Scholar 

  • Hippe R (2013a) Are you NUTS? The factors of production and their long-run evolution in Europe from a regional perspective. Hist Soc Res 38(2):324–348

    Google Scholar 

  • Hippe R (2013b) Spatial clustering of human capital in the European regions. Econ Soc 46(7):1077–1104

    Google Scholar 

  • Hippe R (2014) Human capital and economic growth: theory and quantification. Econ Soc 49(8):1233–1267

    Google Scholar 

  • Hippe R (2015) Why did the knowledge transition occur in the West and not in the East? ICT and the role of governments in Europe, East Asia and the Muslim world. Econ Bus Rev 1(1):9–33

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hippe R, Baten J (2012) Regional inequality in human capital formation in Europe, 1790–1880. Scand Econ Hist Rev 60(3):254–289

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hippe R, Fouquet R (2018) The knowledge economy in historical perspective. World Econ 18(1):75–107

    Google Scholar 

  • Hippe R, Perrin F (2017) Gender equality in human capital and fertility in the European regions in the past. Investigaciones de Historia Económica – Econ Hist Res 13(3):166–179

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Höhener J, Schaltegger CA (2012) Religionsökonomie: eine Übersicht. Perspekt Wirtsch 13(4): 387–406

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Humphries J (2006) English apprenticeship: a neglected factor in the industrial revolution. In: David PA, Thomas M (eds) The Economic future in historical perspective. Oxford University Press, Oxford, pp 73–102

    Google Scholar 

  • Hurt J (1971) Education in evolution. Paladin, London

    Google Scholar 

  • Iannaccone LR, Finke R, Stark R (1997) Deregulating religion: the economics of church and state. Econ Inq 35:350–364

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Johnes G (1993) The economics of education. Macmillan Press, London

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Jones CI (2002) Sources of U.S. economic growth in a world of ideas. Am Econ Rev 92:220–239

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Krueger AB, Lindahl M (2001) Education for growth: why and for whom? J Econ Lit 39(4): 1101–1136

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kuznets S (1955) Economic growth and income inequality. Am Econ Rev 45:1–28

    Google Scholar 

  • Landes DS (1969) The unbound prometheus: technological change and development in Western Europe from 1750 to the present. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge

    Google Scholar 

  • Lange F, Topel R (2006) The social value of education and human capital. In: Hanushek EA, Welch F (eds) Handbook of the economics of education, Vol, vol 1, pp 459–509

    Google Scholar 

  • Lauterbach U (1994) Apprenticeship, history and development of. In: Husén T, Postlethwaite TN (eds) The international encyclopedia of education, 2nd edn. Pergamon, Oxford, pp 310–318

    Google Scholar 

  • Layard R (2005) Mental health: Britain’s biggest social problem? LSE research online. http://cep.lse.ac.uk/textonly/_new/staff/layard/pdf/RL414_Mental_Health_Britains_Biggest_Social_Problem.pdf

  • Lim ASK, Tang HW (2008) Human capital inequality and the Kuznets curve. Dev Econ 46:26–51

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lindert PH (2004) Growing public. Social spending and economic growth since the eighteenth century, vol I. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Lindert PH (2014) Private welfare and the welfare state. In: Neal L, Williamson JG (eds) The Cambridge history of capitalism. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge, pp 464–500

    Google Scholar 

  • Lochner L, Moretti E (2004) The effect of education on criminal activity: evidence from prison inmates, arrests and self-reports. Am Econ Rev 94(1):155–189

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lucas RE (1988) On the mechanics of economic development. J Monet Econ 22:3–42

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Luther M (1909) Eine Predigt, daß man Kinder zur Schule halten solle (A Sermon on Keeping Children in School). In: Dr. Martin Luthers Werke: Kritische Gesamtausgabe, vol 30, Part 2. Verlag Hermann Böhlhaus Nachfolger, Weimar

    Google Scholar 

  • Madsen JB (2010) The anatomy of growth in the OECD since 1870. J Monet Econ 57(6):753–767

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Madsen JB, Saxena S, Ang JB (2010) The Indian growth miracle and endogenous growth. J Dev Econ 93(1):37–48

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Malmström P (1813) Essai sur le système militaire de la Suède. Charles Delén, Stockholm

    Google Scholar 

  • Mankiw NG, Romer D, Weil DN (1992) A Contribution to the empirics of growth. Q J Econ 107(2):408–437

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Matsuo M, Tomoda Y (2012) Human capital Kuznets curve with subsistence consumption level. Econ Lett 116:392–395

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • McLaughlin E, Hanley N, Greasley D, Kunnas J, Oxley L, Warde P (2014) Historical wealth accounts for Britain: progress and puzzles in measuring the sustainability of economic growth. Oxf Rev Econ Policy 30(1):44–69

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Meyer JW (1989) Conceptions of christendom: notes on the distinctiveness of the West. In: Kohn M (ed) Cross-national research in sociology. Sage, Newbury Park, pp 395–413

    Google Scholar 

  • Mincer J (1958) Investment in human capital and personal income distribution. J Polit Econ 66:281–302

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mincer J (1974) Schooling, experience, and earnings. Columbia University Press, New York

    Google Scholar 

  • Minns C, Wallis P (2013) The price of human capital in a pre-industrial economy: premiums and apprenticeship contracts in 18th century England. Explor Econ Hist 50(3):335–350

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mitch D (1982) The spread of literacy in 19th century England, PhD dissertation, University of Chicago

    Google Scholar 

  • Mitch D (1986) The impact of subsidies to elementary schooling on enrolment rates in nineteenth-century England. Econ Hist Rev 39(3):371–391

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mitch D (1992a) The rise of popular literacy in Victorian England. The influence of private choice and public policy. University of Pennsylvania Press, Philadelphia

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Mitch D (1992b) The rise of popular literacy in Europe. In: Fuller B, Rubinson R (eds) The political construction of education. The State, State Expansion and Economic Change, Praeger, New York

    Google Scholar 

  • Mitch D (1999) The role of education and skill in the British industrial revolution. In: Mokyr J (ed) The British industrial revolution: an economic perspective, 2nd edn. Boulder, Westview, pp 241–279

    Google Scholar 

  • Mokyr J (2009) Intellectual property rights, the industrial revolution, and the beginnings of modern economic growth. Am Econ Rev 99(2):349–355

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Morgan NS (1997) Pen, print and Pentium. Technol Forecast Soc Chang 54:11–16

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Morrisson C, Murtin F (2013) The Kuznets curve of human capital inequality: 1870–2010. J Econ Inequal 11(3):283–301

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Murch J (1870) Five years’ retrospect of literature, science and art. Bath Express and County Herald Office, William Lewis

    Google Scholar 

  • Nelson RR, Phelps ES (1966) Investment in humans, technological diffusion, and economic growth. American Economic Association Papers and Proceedings 56(1–2):69–75

    Google Scholar 

  • Peretto P (1998) Technological Change and Population Growth. J Econ Growth 3(4):283–311

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Pritchett L (2001) Where has all the education gone? World Bank Econ Rev 15:367–391

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Pritchett L (2003) “When will they ever learn?” Why all governments produce schooling, BREAD working paper no. 031

    Google Scholar 

  • Psacharopoulos G, Patrinos HA (2004) Returns to investment in education: a further update. Educ Econ 12(2):111–134

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ramirez F, Boli-Bennett J (1982) Global patterns of educational institutionalization. In: Altbach P, Arnove R, Kelly G (eds) Comparative education. Macmillan, New York, pp 15–37

    Google Scholar 

  • Ramirez F, Ventraensca MJ (1992) Building the institution of mass schooling: isomorphism in the modern world. In: Fuller B, Rubinson R (eds) The political construction of education. The State, State Expansion and Economic Change, Praeger, New York

    Google Scholar 

  • Rappaport S (1989) Worlds within worlds: structures of life in sixteenth-century London. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Rashin AG (1958) Formirovanie rabochego Klassa Rossii. Sotsekgiz, Moscow

    Google Scholar 

  • Romer PM (1986) Increasing returns and long-run growth. J Polit Econ 94(5):1002–1037

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Romer PM (1990) Endogenous technological change. J Polit Econ 99(5):71–102

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Rubinson R, Ralph J (1984) Technical change and the expansion of schooling in the United States, 1890–1970. Sociol Educ 57:134–151

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Schultz TW (1961) Investment in human capital. Am Econ Rev 51:1–16

    Google Scholar 

  • Schultz TW (1971) Investment in human capital. Free Press, New York

    Google Scholar 

  • Schultz TW (1975) The value of the ability to deal with disequilibria. J Econ Lit 13(3):827–846

    Google Scholar 

  • Schultz TW (1981) Investing in people: the economics of population quality. University of California Press, Los Angeles

    Google Scholar 

  • Segerstrom PS, Anant ACT, Dinopoulos E (1990) A schumpeterian model of the product life cycle. Am Econ Rev 80(5):1077–1091

    Google Scholar 

  • Sianesi B, van Reenen J (2003) The returns to education: macroeconomics. J Econ Surv 17(2): 157–200

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Smits W, Stromback T (2001) The economics of the apprenticeship system. Edward Elgar, Cheltenham

    Google Scholar 

  • Solow RM (1956) A contribution to the theory of economic growth. Q J Econ 70(1):69–94

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Soysal YN, Strang D (1989) Construction of the first mass education systems in nineteenth-century Europe. Sociol Educ 62(4):277–288

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Spence M (1973) Job market signaling. Q J Econ 87:355–379

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Stöber R (2004) What media evolution is: a theoretical approach to the history of new media. Eur J Commun 19:483–505

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Stone L (1969) Literacy and education in England, 1640–1900. Past Present 42:69–139

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Sturm R (1993) How do education and training effect at country’s economic performance? A literature review. RAND, Santa Monica

    Google Scholar 

  • Swan TW (1956) Economic growth and capital accumulation. Econ Rec 32:334–361

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Sweetland SR (1996) Human capital theory: foundations of a field of inquiry. Rev Educ Res 66(3):341–359

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Thomas K (1986) The meaning of literacy in early modern England. In: Baumann G (ed) The written work: Literacy in transition. Claredon Press, Oxford, pp 97–131

    Google Scholar 

  • Tilly C, Tilly L (1973) The rebellious century, 1830–1930. Harvard University Press, Cambridge

    Google Scholar 

  • Uzawa H (1965) Optimum technical change in an aggregative model of economic growth. Int Econ Rev 6:18–31

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Van Zanden JL (2009a) The long road to the industrial revolution: the European economy in a global perspective, 1000–1800. Koninklijke Brill NV, Leiden

    Google Scholar 

  • Van Zanden JL (2009b) The skill premium and the ‘great divergence’. Eur Rev Econ Hist 13(1):121–153

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Vandenbussche J, Aghion P, Meghir C (2006) Growth, distance to frontier and composition of human capital. J Econ Growth 11:97–127

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Venezky RL (1996) The development of literacy in the industrialized nations of the West. In: Barr R, Kamil ML, Mosenthal P, Pearson D (eds) Handbook of reading research, vol 2. Lawrence Erlbaum Associates, Mahwah

    Google Scholar 

  • Vincent D (2000) The rise of mass literacy: reading and writing in modern Europe. Polity, Cambridge

    Google Scholar 

  • Voth HJ (2001) The longest years: new estimates of labor input in England, 1760–1830. J Econ Hist 61(4):1065–1082

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Wallis PH (2008) Apprenticeship and training in premodern England. J Econ Hist 68(3):832–861

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Walters P, O’Connell PJ (1988) The family economy, work, and educational participation in the United States, 1890–1940. Am J Sociol 93:1116–1152

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Weber M (1958) The protestant ethic and the spirit of capitalism. Charles Scribner’s Son, New York

    Google Scholar 

  • Weedon A (2003) Victorian publishing: the economics of book production for a mass market, 1836–1916. Ashgate Publishing, Aldershot

    Google Scholar 

  • Young A (1998) Growth without scale effects. J Polit Econ 106(1):41–63

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Zeira J (2009) Why and how education affects economic growth. Rev Int Econ 17:602–614

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Disclaimer

The views expressed are purely those of the writers and may not in any circumstances be regarded as stating an official position of the European Commission.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Ralph Hippe .

Editor information

Editors and Affiliations

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

Copyright information

© 2019 Springer Nature Switzerland AG

About this entry

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this entry

Hippe, R., Fouquet, R. (2019). The Human Capital Transition and the Role of Policy. In: Diebolt, C., Haupert, M. (eds) Handbook of Cliometrics. Springer, Cham. https://doi.org/10.1007/978-3-030-00181-0_79

Download citation

Publish with us

Policies and ethics