Skip to main content
Log in

Elite interests and public spending: Evidence from Prussian cities

  • Published:
The Review of International Organizations Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

When do economic and political elites demand investment in public goods and services? The prevailing view is that non-democratic governments engage in low levels of government spending and taxation, because elites have interests in low taxation. Non-democracies exhibit significant variation in levels of government spending; the causes of these discrepancies have thus far not been thoroughly examined. I argue that where elites own capital that is conducive to government spending, regimes make higher investments. I test this argument using newly collected data on government spending as well as political and economic characteristics of 110 cities in 19th century Prussia. Using both standard regression models and instrumental variable analysis, I show that the economic needs of the local elites drove local government decisions on public spending.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1
Fig. 2
Fig. 3

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. But see recent work by Paglayan (2017, 2018).

  2. Gift and Wibbels (2014) make a similar point with regards to research on investments in education.

  3. Lastly, in the Online Appendix I present a bounding exercise concerning selection on unobservables, which lends additional credence to these findings (Oster 2017).

  4. See Mulligan et al. (2004) and personal calculation based on population data by the World Bank (World Bank Group 2018) and regime type coded by Boix et al. (2013).

  5. Data on regime type is based on Boix et al. (2013), expenditure data are taken from Mauro et al. (2015). The plot for years 1800-1900 excludes one data point for Greece in 1898 (Expenditure as % of GDP of 51.4%) to make the figure more readable.

  6. Mares and Queralt (2015) show that a similar development is true for the introduction of the income tax.

  7. As Hollenbach (2018) argues, this demand for spending also provides incentives to increase the capacity of the state to collect taxes.

  8. The county-level data is originally based on Prussian censuses and statistical yearbooks but is generally taken from Becker et al. (2014) and Galloway (2007). Electoral results for 1893 are based on Ziblatt (2009) and the electoral district map comes from Ziblatt and Blossom (2011).

  9. Specifically I divide the number of students in the Volksschule by the number of 5 to 15-year-olds, which approximates the number of children that are eligible to attend school. Unfortunately, the number of students for other schools is not available for the same year as the number of 5 to 15-year-olds, and thus cannot be included in the enrollment ratio. For years in which the number of Bürger- and Middleschool students is also available, the correlation between the number of Volksschul students and the total number of students in Volks-, Bürger-, and Middleschools is 0.997. This should alleviate concerns that the results are due to the reliance on Volksschulstudents.

  10. To create this variable I use data from the occupational census in 1882, which is taken from Becker et al. (2014). Specifically, I code all self-employed and employed workers in mining and steel mill operations, ground or treated mineral and earth manufacturing, metal processing, engineering, and the chemical industry as industrial workers. Data on employment is not available at the city level. I therefore use county-level data on employment and divide it by the total number of workers in the county. This is not a perfect measure, but I believe it is reasonable to assume that the share of industrial workers at the county level would be highly correlated with that in cities and that most industrial workers lived in cities. As an alternative, I use the logged absolute number of industrial workers in the county. The results are shown in Table C.3 in the Appendix.

  11. To calculate the Gini coefficient, some assumptions have to be made. First, I assume that for a given category of income, all persons in that group have the average income of that bin. For example, for incomes between 900 and 3000 marks, I assume all people in this bin earn 1,950 marks. For the last bin, e.g., incomes above 100,000 marks, I assume all persons in the bin earn the lower limit, i.e., 100,000 marks. This is more likely to underestimate inequality, assuming that most persons in the last category earn more than the lower limit. The data source provides seven income categories.

  12. As Hallerberg (2002) shows, the composition of the Prussian parliament stays mostly constant between 1880 and 1913, speaking to the strength of the Prussian electoral system in suppressing progressive votes.

  13. In addition to the large set of included control variables, I undertake a bounding exercise concerning selection on unobservables (Oster 2017). For space reasons, the results are discussed and presented in the Online Appendix but they generally lend support to the results presented below.

  14. Table C.6 in the Appendix shows the results when school expenditure is measured in 1895. Table B.1 in the Appendix shows the summary statistics for all variables, their source, and the year for which they are measured.

  15. The full results with all covariates are presented in Table C.1 in the Appendix.

  16. Table C.4 in the Appendix shows the full regression results in detail.

  17. As further discussed in the conclusion, it is likely that the theoretical mechanism outlined above also works through the development of taxation and tax capacity, as spending provides the underlying motivation for elites to increase taxation (Hollenbach 2018).

  18. For the IV models with enrollment as the dependent variable, I drop the logged rainfall covariate. Otherwise, the model suffers from singularity. Instead of dropping logged rainfall any of the other additional controls in the full model can be dropped with very similar results.

References

  • Acemoglu, D., Cantoni, D., Johnson, S., Robinson, J.A. (2011). The consequences of radical reform: the French revolution. American Economic Review, 101(7), 3286–3307.

    Google Scholar 

  • Acemoglu, D., Naidu, S., Restrepo, P., Robinson, J.A. (2013). Democracy, redistribution and inequality. Working paper. Prepared for the handbook of income distribution. http://economics.mit.edu/files/9396, (Accessed November 27 2013).

  • Angrist, J.D., & Pischke, J.-S. (2009). Mostly harmless econometrics. Princeton: Princeton University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Ansell, B.W. (2008). Traders, teachers, and tyrants: democracy, globalization, and public investment in education. International Organization, 62(2), 289–322.

    Google Scholar 

  • Asch, K. (2005). IGME 5000: 1:5 million international geological map of Europe and adjacent areas. Bundesanstalt für Geowissenschaften und Rohstoffe. https://www.bgr.de/karten/IGME5000/downloads.htm.

  • Baum, M.A., & Lake, D.A. (2003). The political economy of growth: democracy and human capital. American Journal of Political Science, 47(2), 333–347.

    Google Scholar 

  • Becker, S., Cinnirella, F., Hornung, E., Wössmann, L. (2014). iPEHD - the ifo Prussian economic history database. Historical Methods: A Journal of Quantitative and Interdisciplinary History, 47(2), 57–66.

    Google Scholar 

  • Becker, S.O., Hornung, E., Wössmann, L. (2011a). Education and catch-up in the industrial revolution. American Economic Journal, 3(1), 92–126.

    Google Scholar 

  • Becker, S.O., Hornung, E., Wössmann, L. (2011b). Web Appendix to Becker/Hornung/Woessmann, Education and Catch-up in the Industrial Revolution. http://www.aeaweb.org/aej/mac/app/2010-0021_app.pdf, (Accessed March 23, 2014).

  • Benabou, R. (2002). Tax and education policy in a heterogeneous-agent economy: what levels of redistribution maximize growth and efficiency? Econometrica, 70(2), 481–517.

    Google Scholar 

  • Betz, T., Cook, S.J., Hollenbach, F.M. (2018). Spatial interdependence and instrumental variable models. Political Science Research and Methods Forthcoming.

  • Boix, C. (1998). Political parties, growth and equality. New York: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Boix, C., Miller, M., Rosato, S. (2013). A complete dataset of political regimes, 1800-2007. Comparative Political Studies, 46(12), 1523–1554.

    Google Scholar 

  • Boix, C., & Svolik, M. (2013). Institutions, commitment, and power-sharing in dictatorships. Journal of Politics 75(2):Forthcoming.

  • Boix, C. (2003). Democracy and redistribution. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bourguignon, F., & Verdier, T. (2000). Oligarchy, democracy, inequality and growth. Journal of Development Economics, 62(2), 285–313.

    Google Scholar 

  • Brown, J.C. (1988). Coping with crisis? The diffusion of waterworks in late Nineteenth-Century German towns. The Journal of Economic History, 48(2), 307–318.

    Google Scholar 

  • Brown, J.C. (1989). Public reform for private gain? The case of investments in sanitary infrastructure: Germany 1880-1887. Urban Studies, 26(1), 2–12.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bueno de Mesquita, B., Smith, A., Siverson, R.M., Morrow, J.D. (2005). The logic of political survival. Cambridge: MIT Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Busemeyer, M.R. (2007). Determinants of public education spending in 21 OECD democracies, 1980-2001. Journal of European Public Policy, 14(4), 582–610.

    Google Scholar 

  • Cinnirella, F., & Hornung, E. (2016). Landownership concentration and the expansion of education. Journal of Development Economics, 121(Supplement C), 135–152.

    Google Scholar 

  • Coppedge, M., Gerring, J., Knutsen, C.H., Lindberg, S.I., Skaaning, S.-E., Teorell, J., Altman, D., Bernhard, M., Steven Fish, M., Cornell, A., Dahlum, S., Gjerløw, H., Glynn, A., Hicken, A., Krusell, J., Lührmann, A., Marquardt, K.L., McMann, K., Mechkova, V., Medzihorsky, J., Olin, M., Paxton, P., Pemstein, D., Pernes, J., von Römer, J., Seim, B., Sigman, R., Staton, J., Stepanova, N., Sundström, A., Tzelgov, E., Wang, Y., Wig, T., Wilson, S., Ziblatt, D. (2018). V-dem [Country-Year/Country-Date] Dataset v8 – Varieties of Democracy (V-Dem) Project. https://www.v-dem.net/en/data/data-version-8/ (Accessed October, 2018).

  • Drukker, D.M., Prucha, I.R., Raciborski, R. (2013). Maximum likelihood and generalized spatial two-stage least-squares estimators for a spatial-autoregressive model with spatial-autoregressive disturbances. The Stata Journal, 13(2), 221–241.

    Google Scholar 

  • Drukker, D.M., Egger, P., Prucha, I.R. (2013). On two-step estimation of a spatial autoregressive model with autoregressive disturbances and endogenous regressors. Econometric Reviews, 32(5-6), 686– 733.

    Google Scholar 

  • Engerman, S., & Sokoloff, K.L. (2002). Factor endowments, inequality, and paths of development among new world economies. Economia, 3(1), 41–109.

    Google Scholar 

  • Escribà-Folch, A. (2009). Do authoritarian institutions mobilize economic cooperation. Constitutional Political Economy, 20(1), 71–93.

    Google Scholar 

  • Fernihough, A., & O’Rourke, K.H. (2014). Coal and the European industrial revolution. University of Oxford: Discussion Papers in Economic and Social History. http://www.economics.ox.ac.uk/materials/papers/13183/Coal%20-%20ORouke%20124.pdf (Accessed February 2014).

  • Galloway, P.R. (2007). Galloway Prussia database 1861 To 1914 www.patrickgalloway.com (Accessed May, 2014).

  • Galor, O., & Moav, O. (2004). From physical to human capital accumulation: inequality and the process of development. Review of Economic Studies, 71(4), 1001–1026.

    Google Scholar 

  • Galor, O., & Moav, O. (2006). Das Human-Kapital: a theory of the demise of the class structure. Review of Economic Studies, 73(1), 85–117.

    Google Scholar 

  • Galor, O., Moav, O., Vollrath, D. (2009). Inequality in landownership, the emergence of human-capital promoting institutions, and the great divergence. The Review of Economic Studies, 76(1), 143–179.

    Google Scholar 

  • Gehlbach, S., & Keefer, P. (2011). Investment without democracy: ruling-party institutionalization and credible commitment in autocracies. Journal of Comparative Economics, 39(1), 123–139.

    Google Scholar 

  • Gift, T., & Wibbels, E. (2014). Reading, writing, and the regrettable status of education research in comparative politics. Annual Review of Political Science, 17, 291–312.

    Google Scholar 

  • Go, S., & Lindert, P.H. (2010). The uneven rise of american public schools to 1850. The Journal of Economic Historyi, 70(1), 1–26.

    Google Scholar 

  • Gutberlet, T. (2013). Cheap coal versus market access: the role of natural resources and demand in Germany’s industrialization. Working paper. http://gutbet.wp.rpi.edu/files/2014/02/LocationChoice_PaperDec2013.pdf, (Accessed June 2014).

  • Hallerberg, M. (2002). The political economy of taxation in Prussia, 1871-1914. Jahrbuch fü,r Wirtschaftsgeschichte, 2002(2), 11–33.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hollenbach, F.M. (2018). Autocracy, inequality and tax capacity: evidence from 19th century Prussia. Working Paper.

  • Hühner, M. (1998). Kommunalfinanzen, Kommunalunternehmen und Kommunalpolitik im Deutschen Kaiserreich Muenster. Germany: LIT Verlag.

    Google Scholar 

  • Iversen, T., & Stephens, J.D. (2008). Partisan politics, the welfare state, and three worlds of human capital formation. Comparative Political Studies, 41(4/5), 600–637.

    Google Scholar 

  • Jaeger, H. (1967). Unternehmer in der Deutschen Politik (1890–1918). Germany: Ludwig Röhrscheid Verlag.

    Google Scholar 

  • Jensen, N., Malesky, E.J., Weymouth, S. (2013). Unbundling the relationship between authoritarian legislatures and political risk. British Journal of Political Science, 44(3), 655–684.

    Google Scholar 

  • Kourtellos, A., Stylianou, I., Tan, C.M. (2013). Failure to launch? The role of land inequality in transition delays. European Economic Review, 62, 98–113.

    Google Scholar 

  • Krabbe, W.R. (1985). Kommunalpolitik Und Industrialisierung Industrialisierung: Die Entfaltung Der Städtischen Leistungsverwaltung Im 19. Und Frühen 20 Jahrhundert. Fallstudien Zu Dortmund Und Münster. Stuttgart: Verlag W. Kohlhammer/Deutscher Gemeindeverlag.

  • Lizzeri, A., & Persico, N. (2004). Why did the elites extend the suffrage? Democracy and the scope of government, with an application to britain’s age of reform. The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 119(2), 707–765.

    Google Scholar 

  • Mares, I., & Queralt, D. (2015). The Non-Democratic origins of income taxation. Comparative Political Studies In Print:1–36.

  • Mares, I., & Queralt, D. (2018). Fiscal innovation in nondemocratic regimes. Working Paper.

  • Marshall, M.G., Gurr, T.R., Jaggers, K. (2016). Polity IV project: political regime characteristics and transitions, 1800-2015, Dataset Users’ Manual. Center for Systemic Peace.

  • Mauro, P., Romeu, R., Binder, A., Zaman, A. (2015). A modern history of fiscal prudence and profligacy. Journal of Monetary Economics, 76, 55–70. http://www.sciencedirect.com/science/article/pii/S0304393215000938.

    Google Scholar 

  • MPIDR. (1975). Max Planck Institute for Demographic Research CGG – Chair for Geodesy and Geoinformatics, University of Rostock. 2011. MPIDR Population History GIS Collection. Rostock, Germany. Partly based on Hubatsch and Klein. http://censusmosaic.org/web/data/historical-gis-files (Accessed February 2014).

  • Mulligan, C.B., Gil, R., Sala-i Martin, X. (2004). Do democracies have different public policies than nondemocracies? Journal of Economic Perspectives, 18(1), 51–74.

    Google Scholar 

  • Oster, E. (2017). Unobservable selection and coefficient stability: theory and evidence. Journal of Business Economics and Statistics Forthcoming.

  • Paglayan, A.S. (2017). Civil war, state consolidation, and the spread of mass education. Working Paper.

  • Paglayan, A.S. (2018). Democracy and educational expansion: evidence from 200 years. Working Paper.

  • Persson, T., & Tabellini, G. (2003). Economic effects of constitutions. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Pierenkemper, T., & Tilly, R.H. (2004). The German economy during the nineteenth century. New York: Berghahn Books.

    Google Scholar 

  • Pomeranz, K. (2002). Political economy and ecology on the eve of industrialization: Europe, China, and the global conjuncture. American Historical Review, 107(2), 425–446.

    Google Scholar 

  • Sala-i Martin, X., Doppelhofer, G., Miller, R.I. (2004). Determinants of long-term growth: a baysian averagin of classical estimates (BACE). The American Economic Review, 94(4), 813–835.

    Google Scholar 

  • Silbergleit, H. (1908). Preussens Städte: Denkschrift zum 100jährigen Jubiläum der Städteordnung vom 19. November 1808. Berlin: Carl Haymanns Verlag.

    Google Scholar 

  • Spoerer, M. (2004). Steuerlast, Steuerinzidenz und Steuerwettbewerb: Verteilungswirkung der Besteuerung in Preußen Württemberg (1815–1913). Berlin: Akademie Verlag.

    Google Scholar 

  • Stasavage, D. (2005). Democracy and education spending in Africa. American Journal of Political Science, 49(2), 343–358. https://doi.org/10.1111/j.0092-5853.2005.00127.x.

    Google Scholar 

  • Thier, A. (1999). Steuergesetzgebung und verfassung in der konstitutionellen monarchie: staatssteuerreformen in Preussen, 1871-1893. vol 1 Frankfurt am Main. Germany: Vittorio Klostermann.

    Google Scholar 

  • Tilly, R. (1966). The political economy of public finance and the industrialization of Prussia, 1815-1866. The Journal of Economic History, 26(4), 484–497.

    Google Scholar 

  • Tilly, R.H. (1980). Kapital, staat und sozialer protest in der Deutschen industrialisierung: Gesammelte Aufsätze Goettingen. Germany: Vandenhoeck & Ruprecht.

    Google Scholar 

  • Tilly, R.H. (1990). Sozialer protest in Deutschland im 19. Jahrhundert. GESIS Datenarchiv, Köln. ZA8040 Datenfile Version 1.0.0. https://doi.org/10.4232/1.8040.

  • Tilly, R.H. (1991). Germany. In: Patterns Of European Industrialization: The Nineteenth Century, ed. RIchard Sylla and Gianni Toniolo. London, UK: Routledge chapter 9, pp. 175–196.

  • Tipton, F.B. (1996). Technology and industrial growth. In R. Chickering (Ed.) Imperial Germany: A Historiographical Companion (pp. 62–97). Westport: Greenwood Press.

  • Wittmütz, V. (2007). Die Preußische Elementarschule Im 19. Jahrhundert.

  • World Bank Group. (2018). World Bank Data Bank 2018. https://data.worldbank.org/, (Accessed October 2, 2018).

  • Wrigley, E.A. (2010). Energy and the english industrial revolution. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Ziblatt, D. (2009). Shaping democratic practice and the causes of electoral fraud: the case of Nineteenth-Century Germany. American Political Science Review, 103(1), 1–21.

    Google Scholar 

  • Ziblatt, D., & Blossom, J.C. (2011). Electoral district boundaries, Germany, 1890-1912. http://pelham.lib.harvard.edu:8080/opengeoportal/, (Accessed October 2018).

Download references

Acknowledgments

I thank Joshua Alley for excellent research assistance. The paper has been presented at the Meeting of the European Political Science Association, Milan, Italy, June 2017. I thank Franziska Keller, the editor, three excellent reviewers, and participants at the Texas A&M Conference on Taxation, Revenue, and Fiscal Capacity for helpful comments on this project. All remaining errors are my own.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Florian M. Hollenbach.

Additional information

Publisher’s note

Springer Nature remains neutral with regard to jurisdictional claims in published maps and institutional affiliations.

Electronic supplementary material

Below is the link to the electronic supplementary material.

(ZIP 1.21 MB)

(PDF 255 KB)

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Hollenbach, F.M. Elite interests and public spending: Evidence from Prussian cities. Rev Int Organ 16, 189–211 (2021). https://doi.org/10.1007/s11558-019-09347-z

Download citation

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s11558-019-09347-z

Keywords

JEL Classification

Navigation