Skip to main content
Log in

Elections, lobbying and economic policies: an empirical investigation across Indian states

  • Original Paper
  • Published:
Constitutional Political Economy Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

This paper utilizes a balanced panel data-set comprising of data on 29 Indian states and Union Territories for the period 2003-2017 for both Legislative Assembly and Parliamentary elections at the state-level to address the following questions. First, whether an incumbent government manoeuvers fiscal policies for opportunistic gains, especially in light of tight electoral competition? Second, whether ideologically distinct or partisan electoral groups exhibit different economic policy positions during an election term? And third, whether clientelist practices undertaken by political candidates or parties contesting elections significantly translate into biasing policy choices in favour of their patrons? The analysis has been done for two categories of policy variables: expenditure and deficit parameters of the incumbent state government. The regression estimations include various political controls such as, electoral competition between political parties, voter participation rate, government’s ideological leaning, centre-state alignment and government incumbency. Apart from these, the estimations also control for political lobbying by using the data on monetary contributions provided to different political parties. The results for both Legislative Assembly and state-level Parliamentary elections provide remarkable evidence in favour of a significant presence of various interest groups, lobbying and monetary transfers at work in Indian politics, especially via a strong and organized industrial sector, which trickles down to influence the numerous policy positions of distinct political parties.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1

Source: Reserve Bank of India

Fig. 2

Source: Reserve Bank of India

Fig. 3

Source: Reserve Bank of India

Fig. 4

Source: Association of Democratic Reforms (2019)

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. https://thewire.in/political-economy/india-shadow-lobbies-business-electoral-funding

  2. https://www.indiatoday.in/magazine/the-big-story/story/20181119-political-funding-who-pays-for-the-party-1384158-2018-11-09.

  3. In order to study the corporate lobbying scenario in a comprehensive manner, it would be better to either segregate the political contributions made by industries and businesses or employ an industrial concentration index (constructed on the basis of the Hirschman-Herfindahl index) to measure the extent and influence of the lobbying power of big corporations and business groups in a state to evaluate their impact on firm or industry specific policies implemented by the incumbent governments across states.

  4. https://www.elections.in/assembly-constituencies.html.

  5. http://loksabhaph.nic.in/Members/StateWiseStatisticalList.aspx.

  6. On August 5, 2019, the Jammu and Kashmir Reorganization Act was passed in both Houses of the Indian Parliament, which revoked the special status of Jammu and Kashmir and reorganized the state into two union territories, namely the eponymous union territory of Jammu and Kashmir, and that of Ladakh.

  7. The states and UTs included in the empirical estimation are: Andhra Pradesh, Arunachal Pradesh, Assam, Bihar, Chattisgarh, Delhi (Union Territory), Goa, Gujarat, Haryana, Himachal Pradesh, Jammu and Kashmir, Jharkhand, Karnataka, Kerela, Madhya Pradesh, Maharashtra, Manipur, Meghalaya, Mizoram, Nagaland, Orissa, Punjab, Rajasthan, Sikkim, Tamil Nadu, Tripura, Uttarakhand, Uttar Pradesh and West Bengal. The state of Telangana has been excluded from the analysis because the time-period of the data-set is 2003-17 whereas the state of Telangana was formed on 2nd June 2014.

  8. 1 crore = 10 million.

  9. General services include interest payments, repayment of debt, defence, law and order, running of different organs of the state such as judiciary, auditing, etc. and pensions. Economic services include agriculture, irrigation, industry and minerals, employment generation, transport, communications, energy (power). Social services include education, health and family welfare, water supply and sanitation, welfare of marginalized sections, welfare of handicapped and destitute people and youth affairs and sports.

  10. In India, it is the number of seats won during elections (state-level or national level) and not the number of votes that matters for government formation. And, since this study analyzes the impact of electoral competition on different policy outcomes of the incumbent state governments, the measure of political competition based on seat-share difference seems more suitable as compared to the measure based on vote-share difference.

  11. INC (Indian National Congress) or Congress is treated as a centrist political party in this analysis.

  12. Refer to Appendix for a detailed list of all the political parties considered in this analysis along with their ideological stands. The ideological stands and political leanings of distinct political parties in India have been compiled from Dash and Raja (2012).

  13. In case of a state experiencing President’s rule during a financial year, it has been considered as aligned with the centre for the purpose of this analysis. This notion is in conformity with the proposition that state administrations under President’s rule will typically be in compliance with the central government.

  14. Government continuation dummy has been dropped from the state-level Parliamentary election estimations since it is invariant over the time period of the analysis.

  15. The yearly population of the state has been calculated by dividing the GSDP of the state (at constant prices) by the per-capita state domestic product (at constant prices).

  16. It should be noted that while the two terms: lobbying and clientelism, have been used together, they are not strictly synonymous with each other. In particular, lobbying is associated with efforts to influence government’s decisions and policies, while political clientelism, in very basic terms describes the distribution of selective benefits to individuals or clearly defined groups in exchange for political support. Nevertheless, lobbying and some forms of clientelism have been observed to moderately overlap with each other. For example, “new” clientelism is closely associated with the expansion of the economic and social role of the state including the provision of a wide range of financial benefits (welfare and pensions, industrial and agricultural subsidies, public housing) and public services (education, health), which in turn provides a greater ability to the incumbent party in a state to manipulate and channel these resources in exchange for political support (Hopkin 2006). Such fiscal maneuvering might very well be driven and intensified by the presence of organized interest groups which provide monetary contributions to the incumbent party in question, for they can coordinate amongst themselves and thus have a better ability to extract transfers from incumbent politicians. Utilizing this line of reasoning, the analysis in this paper relates the clientelist practices of the incumbent government as being an auxiliary supporting mechanism through which lobbying activities (channelled via political contributions) can influence the incumbent government’s spending decisions.

  17. file:///C:/Users/HOME/AppData/Local/Temp/103120000000009096.htmlof methodological issues.

  18. These are the donations received by BJP (Bharatiya Janata Party), INC, NCP (Nationalist Congress Party), CPI (Communist Party of India), CPM (Communist Party of India (Marxist)) and AITC (All India Trinamool Congress). Even though BSP (Bahujan Samaj Party) is also a national party but it was not considered in the analysis as it declared no receipt of voluntary contributions over INR 20,000 from any donor during the said time period.

  19. http://www.indiavotes.com/

  20. https://rajyasabha.nic.in/

  21. https://eci.gov.in/candidate-political-parties/contribution-reports/contribution-reports/

  22. In the descriptive statistics for state-level Parliamentary elections, apart from the political controls like political competition, voter participation, government ideology and political contributions, all other variables are identical to the variables in Legislative Assembly elections.

  23. Since both the dependent as well as the independent variables have been normalized by dividing them with variables measured in correspondingly identical respects, therefore, they are expressed in absolute terms. In consequence, the original measurement standards of these variables become defunct for this analysis. Hence, for all the regression estimations, “unit” has been used as a reliable terminology to interpret the regression coefficients of all the normalized variables.

  24. The estimated coefficients for the political competition variable should be interpreted in a reverse manner. This is because the extent of political competition in a state has been calculated by dividing the seat-share difference between the winner and the runner-up party by the total seats in that state and, a lowering of the seat-share difference between the winner and the runner-up political groups is synonymous with a greater degree of political competition. Thus, a negative coefficient for this variable, for say capital spending to GSDP ratio, indicates that a lowering of the seat-share difference entails an increase in the average share of capital expenditure.

  25. I would like to thank an anonymous referee for pointing out the need to highlight the corruption incentive of the incumbent working through the political competition variable constructed using the seat-shares data and its influence on capital spending to GSDP ratio.

  26. A more liberal government is perceived to be more left-oriented.

  27. The corporate sector accounts for a major share of donations received by the political parties in India according to a report by ADR (2019).

  28. Since the special category is a dummy variable and is constant over time, it is dropped from the Difference GMM regressions.

  29. A study by Dash and Mukherjee (2014) shows that states belonging to special category on an average have lower HDI (Human Development Index) scores as compared to the general category states, thus, indicating the prevalence of relatively sub-standard social conditions in the special category states.

References

  • Akhmedov, A., & Zhuravskaya, E. (2004). Opportunistic political cycles: Test in a young democracy setting. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 119, 1301–1338.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Alt, J., & Lassen, D. (2006). Transparency, political polarization, and political budget cycles in OECD countries. American Journal of Political Science, 50, 530–550.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Arellano, M., & Bond, S. (1991). Some tests of specification for panel data: Monte carlo evidence and an application to employment equations. Review of Economic Studies, 58, 277–297.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Arellano, M., & Bover, O. (1995). Another look at the instrumental variable estimation of error components models. Journal of Econometrics, 68, 29–51.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Arulampalam, W., Dasgupta, S., Dhillon, A., & Dutta, B. (2009). Electoral goals and center-state transfers: A theoretical model and empirical evidence from India. Journal of Development Economics, 88, 103–119.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Asher, S., & Novosad, P. (2017). Politics and local economic growth: Evidence from India. American Economic Journal: Applied Economics, 9, 229–273.

    Google Scholar 

  • Ashworth, J., Geys, B., Heyndels, B., & Wille, F. (2014). Competition in the political arena and local government performance. Applied Economics, 46, 2264–2276.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Association for Democratic Reforms (2019). Analysis of Donations from Corporates and Business Houses to National Parties for Financial Year 2016-17 and 2017-18, New Delhi.

  • Blundell, R., & Bond, S. (1998). Initial conditions and moment restrictions in dynamic panel data models. Journal of Econometrics, 87, 115–143.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Brender, A. (2003). The effect of fiscal performance on local government election results in Israel: 1989–1998. Journal of Public Economics, 87, 2187–2205.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Brender, A., & Drazen, A. (2005). Political budget cycles in new versus established democracies. Journal of Monetary Economics, 52, 1271–1295.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Chatterjee, S., & Sahoo, N. (2014). Corporate funding of elections: The strengths and flaws. Observer Research Foundation Issue Brief, 69, 1–12.

    Google Scholar 

  • Chhibber, P. (1995). Political parties, electoral competition, government expenditures and economic reform in India. The Journal of Development Studies, 32, 74–96.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cole, S. (2009). Fixing market failures or fixing elections? Agricultural Credit in India. American Economic Journal: Applied Economics, 1, 219–250.

    Google Scholar 

  • Dash, B. B., & Mukherjee, S. (2014). Political competition and human development: Evidence from the Indian States. The Journal of Development Studies, 51, 1–14.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dash, B. B. & Raja, A. V. (2012). Political determinants of the allocation of public expenditures: A study of the Indian States, NIPFP Working Paper No. 2012-101, New Delhi.

  • De Figueiredo, J. M., & Silverman, B. S. (2006). Academic earmarks and the returns to lobbying. Journal of Law and Economics, 49, 597–625.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Drazen, A. & Eslava, M. (2005). Electoral manipulation via voter-friendly spending: Theory and evidence, NBER Working Paper No. 11085.

  • Election Commission of India (2015). Background Paper on Political Finance and Law Commission Recommendations, New Delhi.

  • Election Commission of India (2017a). Contribution Reports by Recognized National Parties, New Delhi.

  • Election Commission of India (2017b). Contribution Reports by Recognized State Parties, New Delhi.

  • Fumagalli, E., & Narciso, G. (2012). Political institutions, voter turn out, and policy outcomes. European Journal of Political Economy, 28, 162–173.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ghosh, S. (2010). Does political competition matter for economic performance? Evidence from sub-national data. Political Studies, 58, 1030–1048.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gonzalez, M. (2002). Do changes in democracy affect political budget cycle? Evidence from Mexico. Review of Development Economics, 6, 204–224.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gordon, S., Hafer, C., & Landa, D. (2007). Consumption or investment? On motivations for political giving. Journal of Politics, 69, 245–261.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gray, V., & Lowery, D. (1999). The Population Ecology of Interest Representation: Lobbying Communities in the American States. Ann Arbor, MI: University of Michigan Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Gupta, S., & Swenson, C. W. (2003). Rent-seeking by agents of the firm. Journal of Law and Economics, 46, 253–268.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hopkin, J. (2006). Conceptualizing Political Clientelism: Political Exchange and Democratic Theory, Paper Prepared for APSA annual meeting, Philadelphia, 31 August - 3 September 2006, Panel 46–18.

  • Jacoby, W. G., & Schneider, S. K. (2001). Variability in State policy priorities: An empirical analysis. Journal of Politics, 63, 544–568.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kang, K. (2015). Policy influence and private returns from lobbying in the energy sector. Review of Economic Studies, 1, 1–43.

    Google Scholar 

  • Keefer, P. & Khemani S. (2004). Why Do The Poor Receive Poor Services?, Economic and Political Weekly: 935-943.

  • Kelly-Gagnon, M., & Geloso, V. (2013). Who Spends More: Left or Right? (pp. 1–4). Montreal Economic Institute: Economic Note.

    Google Scholar 

  • Khemani, S. (2004). Political cycles in a developing economy: Effect of election in the Indian States. Journal of Development Economics, 73, 125–154.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kneebone, R., & McKenzie, K. (2001). Electoral and partisan cycles in fiscal policy: An examination of Canadian Provinces. International Tax and Public Finance, 8, 753–774.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Langbein, L. I. (1986). Money and access: Some empirical evidence. Journal of Politics, 48, 1052–1062.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lijphart, A. (1997). Unequal participation: Democracy's unresolved dilemma. American Political Science Review, 91, 1–14.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lindeen, J. W., & Willis, G. L. (1975). Political, socioeconomic and demographic patterns of support for public higher education. The Western Political Quarterly, 28, 528–541.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mahoney, C. (2007). Lobbying success in U.S. and the European Union. Journal of Public Policy, 27, 35–56.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Manjhi, G., & Mehra, M. K. (2018). Political transfer cycles from the centre to the States. Ensayos Sobre Politica Economica, 86, 207–241.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Manjhi, G., & Mehra, M. K. (2019). Dynamics of political budget cycle. Italian Economic Journal, 5, 135–158.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Marshall, T. R. (1997). Bundling the cash: Why do interest groups bundle donations? American Review of Politics, 18, 291–308.

    Google Scholar 

  • Mohanty, N. (2013). The special category state conundrum in Odisha, Institute of Studies in Industrial Development, Working Paper No. 156.

  • Mueller, D. C., & Murrell, P. (1986). Interest groups and the size of the government. Public Choice, 48, 125–145.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Olper, A. (2007). Land inequality, government ideology and agricultural protection. Food Policy, 32, 67–83.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Padovano, F., & Ricciuti, R. (2007). Political competition and economic performance: Evidence from the OECD Countries, Mimeo.

  • Padovano, F., & Ricciuti, R. (2009). Political competition and economic performance: Evidence from the Italian regions. Public Choice, 138, 263–277.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Peltzman, S. (1992). Voters as fiscal conservatives. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 107, 327–361.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Persson, T., & Tabellini, G. (2002). Political Economics: Explaining Economic Policy. Cambridge: MIT Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Persson, T., & Tabellini, G. (2003). The Economic Effects of Constitutions. Cambridge: MIT Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Potrafke, N. (2009). Does government ideology influence political alignment with the U.S.? An Empirical Analysis of Voting in the UN General Assembly. Review of International Organizations, 4, 245–268.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Potrafke, N. (2012). Is German domestic social policy politically controversial? Public Choice, 153, 393–418.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Powell, L. W. (2013). The influence of campaign contributions on legislative policy. A Journal of Applied Research in Contemporary Politics, 11, 339–355.

    Google Scholar 

  • Reserve Bank of India. (2019a). Handbook of statistics on Indian States, Department of Economic and Policy Research, Reserve Bank of India, Mumbai.

  • Reserve Bank of India. (2019b). State finances: A study of budgets of 2019–20, Department of Economic and Policy Research, Division of State Finances, Reserve Bank of India, Mumbai.

  • Rogoff, K. (1990). Equilibrium political budget cycles. American Economic Review, 80, 21–36.

    Google Scholar 

  • Rogoff, K., & Sibert, A. (1988). Elections and macroeconomic policy cycles. Review of Economic Studies, 55, 1–16.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Shi, M. & Svensson, J. (2002). Conditional political budget cycles, CEPR Discussion Paper No. 3352.

  • Singh, P. (2015). Special category States in India, Paripex: Indian Journal of Research, 4: 170-175.

  • Suri, K. C., Elliott, C., & Hundt, D. (2016). Democracy, governance and political parties in India. Studies in Indian Politics, 4, 1–7.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Svensson, J. (2005). Controlling Spending: Electoral Competition, Polarization, and Primary Elections. The World Bank: Mimeo.

    Google Scholar 

  • Tandberg, D. (2010). Politics, interest groups and state funding of public higher education. Research in Higher Education, 416–450.

  • Tripathi, M., Anasolabehere, S., & Snyder, J. M. (2002). Are PAC contributions and lobbying linked? New evidence from the 1995 lobby disclosure act. Business and Politics, 4, 131–155.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Wolton S. (2017). Lobbying, inside and out: How special interest groups influence policy choices, Available at SSRN, https://ssrn.com/abstract=2190685.

  • Yadav, Y. (2000). Understanding the Second Democratic Upsurge, in F. Frankel (ed.) Transforming India: Social and Political Dynamics of Democracy. Delhi: Oxford University Press.

  • Yadav, V. (2006). Interest Group Dynamics in Developing Countries: An Empirical Comparison of Brazil and India, Prepared for Comparative Political Economy Workshop at Harvard University, October 7-8, 2005.

Download references

Funding

Not Applicable

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Deepti Kohli.

Ethics declarations

Conflict of interest

Not Applicable

Availability of Data and Material

Not Applicable

Code Availability

Not Applicable

Author’s Contributions

Not Applicable

Additional information

Publisher's Note

Springer Nature remains neutral with regard to jurisdictional claims in published maps and institutional affiliations.

Appendix

Appendix

See Table 7.

Table 7 Ideologies of National and State-level Political Parties in India

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Kohli, D. Elections, lobbying and economic policies: an empirical investigation across Indian states. Const Polit Econ 33, 255–300 (2022). https://doi.org/10.1007/s10602-021-09353-7

Download citation

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s10602-021-09353-7

Keywords

JEL Classification

Navigation