Skip to main content

Advertisement

Log in

Exploring the strategies of online and offline recycling channels in closed-loop supply chain under government subsidy

  • Research Article
  • Published:
Environmental Science and Pollution Research Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

The influence of online and offline dual recycling channels in a closed-loop supply chain (CLSC) is investigated in our work. The CLSC models of three recycling modes (single online recycling, single offline recycling, and dual recycling channels of online and offline) are established, respectively, and the impact of government subsidies on the pricing decision-making and recycling mode selection of channel members is therefore researched. The study found that the remanufacturer sets appropriate recycling price and transfer price to coordinate online and offline recycling channels and maximize its profits in the dual recycling modes; collector’s offline recycling faces the competitive threat of remanufacturers’ online recycling under the dual recycling modes, so the collector prefers a single offline recycling mode; the relationship between the collection quantities of the three modes depends on consumers’ preference of the online recycling channel. In the meanwhile, it is illustrated that government subsidy plays a positive role in promoting the recycling and remanufacturing willingness of remanufacturers and collectors. This work provides practical insights for the CLSC system to make recycle decisions.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1.
Fig. 2
Fig. 3
Fig. 4
Fig. 5
Fig. 6

Similar content being viewed by others

Data availability

Not applicable.

Notes

  1. The parameters are set as a = 0.1, k = 0.3, cn = 2.8, Δ = 1.2, cc = 0.8, cd = 0.7, s = 0.6, and τ = 0.1.

References

  • Atasu A, Özdemir Ö, Van Wassenhove LN (2013a) Stakeholder perspectives on e-waste take-back legislation. Prod Oper Manag 22(2):382–396

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Atasu A, Toktay LB, Van Wassenhove LN (2013b) How collection cost structure drives a manufacturer’s reverse channel choice. Prod Oper Manag 22(5):1089–1102

    Google Scholar 

  • Bulmuş SC, Zhu SX, Teunter RH (2014) Optimal core acquisition and pricing strategies for hybrid manufacturing and remanufacturing systems. Int J Prod Res 52(22):6627–6641. https://doi.org/10.1080/00207543.2014.906073

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Choi T-M, Li Y, Xu L (2013) Channel leadership, performance and coordination in closed loop supply chains. Int J Prod Econ 146(1):371–380

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dhanorkar S, Muthulingam S (2020) Do e-waste laws create behavioral spillovers? Quasi-experimental evidence from California. Prod Oper Manag 29(7):1738–1766

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Esenduran G, Kemahlıoğlu-Ziya E, Swaminathan JM (2017) Impact of take-back regulation on the remanufacturing industry. Prod Oper Manag 26(5):924–944

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Feng L, Govindan K, Li C (2017) Strategic planning: design and coordination for dual-recycling channel reverse supply chain considering consumer behavior. Eur J Oper Res 260(2):601–612

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ferguson ME, Toktay LB (2006) The effect of competition on recovery strategies. Prod Oper Manag 15(3):351–368. https://doi.org/10.1111/j.1937-5956.2006.tb00250.x

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Giri BC, Dey SK (2019) Game theoretic analysis of a closed-loop supply chain with backup supplier under dual channel recycling. Comput Ind Eng 129:179–191

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Han X, Yang Q, Shang J et al (2017) Optimal strategies for trade-old-for-remanufactured programs: receptivity, durability, and subsidy. Int J Prod Econ 193:602–616

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • He P, He Y, Xu H (2019) Channel structure and pricing in a dual-channel closed-loop supply chain with government subsidy. Int J Prod Econ 213:108–123. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.ijpe.2019.03.013

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hong X, Wang Z, Wang D et al (2013) Decision models of closed-loop supply chain with remanufacturing under hybrid dual-channel collection. Int J Adv Manuf Technol 68(5):1851–1865

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Huang H, Xiong Y, Zhou Y (2020) A larger pie or a larger slice? Contract negotiation in a closed-loop supply chain with remanufacturing. Comput Ind Eng 142:106377

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Huang M, Song M, Lee LH et al (2013) Analysis for strategy of closed-loop supply chain with dual recycling channel. Int J Prod Econ 144(2):510–520

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Jin M, Nie J, Yang F et al (2017) The impact of third-party remanufacturing on the forward supply chain: a blessing or a curse? Int J Prod Res 55(22):6871–6882

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Konstantaras I, Skouri K, Benkherouf L (2021) Optimizing inventory decisions for a closed–loop supply chain model under a carbon tax regulatory mechanism. Int J Prod Econ 239:108185

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kunter M (2012) Coordination via cost and revenue sharing in manufacturer–retailer channels. Eur J Oper Res 216(2):477–486

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Li C, Feng L, Luo S (2019) Strategic introduction of an online recycling channel in the reverse supply chain with a random demand. J Clean Prod 236:117683. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jclepro.2019.117683

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ma W-M, Zhao Z, Ke H (2013) Dual-channel closed-loop supply chain with government consumption-subsidy. Eur J Oper Res 226(2):221–227

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ma Z, Zhang N, Dai Y et al (2016) Managing channel profits of different cooperative models in closed-loop supply chains. Omega 59:251–262

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mahmoudi R, Rasti-Barzoki M (2018) Sustainable supply chains under government intervention with a real-world case study: an evolutionary game theoretic approach. Comput Ind Eng 116:130–143

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mitra S (2016) Models to explore remanufacturing as a competitive strategy under duopoly. Omega 59:215–227

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mitra S, Webster S (2008) Competition in remanufacturing and the effects of government subsidies. Int J Prod Econ 111(2):287–298

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Newell RG, Pizer WA, Raimi D (2019) U.S. federal government subsidies for clean energy: design choices and implications. Energy Econ 80:831–841

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Örsdemir A, Kemahlıoğlu-Ziya E, Parlaktürk AK (2014) Competitive quality choice and remanufacturing. Prod Oper Manag 23(1):48–64. https://doi.org/10.1111/poms.12040

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Panda S, Modak NM, Cárdenas-Barrón LE (2017) Coordinating a socially responsible closed-loop supply chain with product recycling. Int J Prod Econ 188:11–21. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.ijpe.2017.03.010

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Pazoki M, Samarghandi H (2020) Take-back regulation: remanufacturing or eco-design? Int J Prod Econ 227:107674

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Savaskan RC, Bhattacharya S, Van Wassenhove LN (2004) Closed-loop supply chain models with product remanufacturing. Manag Sci 50(2):239–252

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Savaskan RC, Van Wassenhove LN (2006) Reverse channel design: the case of competing retailers. Manag Sci 52(1):1–14

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Shi J, Zhang G, Sha J (2011) Optimal production and pricing policy for a closed loop system. Resour Conserv Recycl 55(6):639–647

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Shittu OS, Williams ID, Shaw PJ (2021) Global E-waste management: can WEEE make a difference? A review of e-waste trends, legislation, contemporary issues and future challenges. Waste Manag 120:549–563

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Souza GC (2013) Closed-loop supply chains: a critical review, and future research*. Decis Sci 44(1):7–38

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Vedantam A, Iyer A (2021) Revenue-sharing contracts under quality uncertainty in remanufacturing. Prod Oper Manag 30(7):2008–2026 n/a(n/a)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Wang Z, Huo J, Duan Y (2019) Impact of government subsidies on pricing strategies in reverse supply chains of waste electrical and electronic equipment. Waste Manag 95:440–449

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Wei J, Wang Y, Zhao J et al (2019) Analyzing the performance of a two-period remanufacturing supply chain with dual collecting channels. Comput Ind Eng 135:1188–1202

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Wu C-H (2021) A dynamic perspective of government intervention in a competitive closed-loop supply chain. Eur J Oper Res 294(1):122–137. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.ejor.2021.01.014

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Xia Y, Tan D, Wang B (2021) Use of a product service system in a competing remanufacturing market. Omega 102:102387

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Xiong Y, Zhao Q, Zhou Y (2016) Manufacturer-remanufacturing vs supplier-remanufacturing in a closed-loop supply chain. Int J Prod Econ 176:21–28. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.ijpe.2016.03.001

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Xu L, Wang C (2018) Sustainable manufacturing in a closed-loop supply chain considering emission reduction and remanufacturing. Resour Conserv Recycl 131:297–304. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.resconrec.2017.10.012

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Yang L, Hu Y, Huang L (2020) Collecting mode selection in a remanufacturing supply chain under cap-and-trade regulation. Eur J Oper Res 287(2):480–496

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Yao Z, Leung SCH, Lai KK (2008) Manufacturer’s revenue-sharing contract and retail competition. Eur J Oper Res 186(2):637–651

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Yenipazarli A (2016) Managing new and remanufactured products to mitigate environmental damage under emissions regulation. Eur J Oper Res 249(1):117–130

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Yi P, Huang M, Guo L et al (2016) Dual recycling channel decision in retailer oriented closed-loop supply chain for construction machinery remanufacturing. J Clean Prod 137:1393–1405

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Zhang Y, Hong Z, Chen Z et al (2020) Tax or subsidy? Design and selection of regulatory policies for remanufacturing. Eur J Oper Res 287(3):885–900. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.ejor.2020.05.023

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgements

The authors thank anonymous reviewers for their constructive suggestions that helped to improve the quality of this paper. Yanting Huang acknowledges the support of the National Natural Science Foundation of China.

Funding

This research is supported by the National Natural Science Foundation of China under Grant 72001147, Guangdong Planning Project of Philosophy and Social Science of China under Grant GD19YGL18, and the Startup Fund from Shenzhen University under Grants 2019023 and 860-000002110361.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Contributions

Yuqing Liang wrote the manuscript and participated in all phases. Yanting Huang guided the research, discussed the results, and commented on the manuscript at all stages. Both authors have read and approved the final manuscript.

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Yanting Huang.

Ethics declarations

Ethics approval and consent to participate

Not applicable.

Consent for publication

Not applicable.

Conflict of interest

The authors declare no competing interests.

Additional information

Responsible Editor: Marcus Schulz

Publisher’s note

Springer Nature remains neutral with regard to jurisdictional claims in published maps and institutional affiliations.

Appendices

Appendix 1

Derivation process of model MC Using the inverse regression method, for the collector’s profit function in Equation (10), we have \(\partial {\varPi}_C^{MC}/\partial {p}_c=k\left(b-{c}_c-2{p}_c+\theta {p}_d\right)/\theta \left(1-\theta \right)=0\), \({\partial}^2{\varPi}_C^{MC}/\partial {p_c}^2=-2\left(\frac{1}{\theta }+\frac{1}{1-\theta}\right)<0\). Hence, we determine that the collector’s profit function is a strictly concave function of pc, and has a unique optimal profit.

Then, we compute the Hessian Matrix of the objective function of the remanufacturer’s profit regarding pn, pd, and b ,which is expressed as

$${H}_M^{MC}==\left(\begin{array}{ccc}-2a& 0& 0\\ {}0& -\frac{k}{\theta \left(1-\theta \right)}& \frac{k}{1-\theta}\\ {}0& \frac{k}{1-\theta }& -\frac{k\left(2-\theta \right)}{1-\theta}\end{array}\right)<{0}_{\circ }$$

Hence, \({\varPi}_M^{MC}\) is strictly concave in pn, pd, and b, by deriving pn, pd, and b, we have

$$\left\{\begin{array}{c}\partial {\varPi}_M^{MC}/\partial {p}_n=1+a{c}_n-2a{p}_n=0\\ {}\begin{array}{c}\partial {\varPi}_M^{MC}/\partial b=k\left[\left(1-\theta \right)\left({c}_n-{c}_r\right)-2b+\theta {c}_d+{c}_c+2\theta {p}_d\right]/2\theta \left(1-\theta \right)=0\\ {}\partial {\varPi}_M^{MC}/\partial {p}_d=k\left[\left(1-\theta \right)\left({c}_n-{c}_r\right)+2b-\left(2-\theta \right){c}_d-{c}_c-2\left(2-\theta \right){p}_d\right]/2\left(1-\theta \right)=0\end{array}\end{array}\right.$$

Finally, we substitute the optimal price into Equation (10) and Equation (11), and we can obtain the optimal profits of each channel member.

Appendix 2

Proof of proposition 1

Since \({p}_n^{M\ast }=\frac{1+a{c}_n}{2a}\), \({p}_n^{C\ast }=\frac{1+a{c}_n}{2a}\), and \({p}_n^{MC\ast }=\frac{1+a{c}_n}{2a}\), hence we have \({p}_n^{M\ast }={p}_n^{C\ast }={p}_n^{MC\ast }\), similarly, it can be proved that DM = DC = DMC.

Proof of proposition 2

Because \({p}_C^{MC\ast }-{p}_C^{C\ast }=\frac{\left(1+\theta \right)\varDelta -{c}_c+\left(1-\tau \right)s-\theta \left({c}_d-\tau s\right)}{4}-\frac{\varDelta -{c}_c+s}{4}=\frac{\theta \varDelta -\tau s-\theta \left({c}_d-\tau s\right)}{4}\), therefore, it can be concluded that when \(\theta >\frac{\tau s}{\varDelta +\tau s-{c}_d}\) , \({p}_C^{MC\ast }>{p}_C^{C\ast }\).Similarly, other size relationship of prices could be certified.

Proof of proposition 3

Because \({Q}_r^{MC\ast }-{Q}_r^{C\ast }=k\frac{\left(1+\theta \right)\varDelta -{c}_c+\left(1-\tau \right)s-\theta \left({c}_d-\tau s\right)}{4\theta }-\frac{k\left(\varDelta -{c}_d+s\right)}{4\theta }=\frac{k}{4\theta}\left[\theta \left(\varDelta -{c}_d+\tau s\right)+{c}_d-{c}_c-\tau s\right]\), from the equation, it could be seen that when \(\theta >\frac{c_c+\tau s-{c}_d}{\varDelta +\tau s-{c}_d}\), \({Q}_r^{MC\ast }>{Q}_r^{C\ast }\). Therefore, other size of relationship of collection quantity under different recycling mode could be decided.

Proof of proposition 4

Since \({\varPi}_C^{MC\ast }=\frac{k{\left[\left(1-\theta \right)\varDelta -{c}_c+\left(1-\tau \right)s+\theta \left({c}_d-\tau s\right)\right]}^2}{16\theta \left(1-\theta \right)}<M=\frac{k{\left[\left(1-\theta \right)\varDelta -{c}_c+\left(1-\tau \right)s+\theta \left({c}_d-\tau s\right)\right]}^2}{16\theta {\left(1-\theta \right)}^2},\) therefore, to prove \({\varPi}_C^{C\ast }>{\varPi}_C^{MC\ast }\), we need to certify \({\varPi}_C^{C\ast }>M\). Because \({\varPi}_C^{C\ast }>M\Rightarrow \frac{k{\left(\varDelta -{c}_c+s\right)}^2}{16\theta }>\frac{k{\left[\left(1-\theta \right)\varDelta -{c}_c+\left(1-\tau \right)s+\theta \left({c}_d-\tau s\right)\right]}^2}{16\theta {\left(1-\theta \right)}^2}\), ⇒(Δ − cc + s)(1 − θ) > (1 − θ)Δ − cc + (1 − τ)s + θ(cd − τs),

θcc − θs >  − τs + θ(cd − τs) ⇒ (cd + s − τs − cc)θ < τs, it could reach that when \(\theta <\frac{\tau s}{c_d+\left(1-\tau \right)s-{c}_c}\), \({\varPi}_C^{C\ast }>{\varPi}_C^{MC\ast }.\)

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Huang, Y., Liang, Y. Exploring the strategies of online and offline recycling channels in closed-loop supply chain under government subsidy. Environ Sci Pollut Res 29, 21591–21602 (2022). https://doi.org/10.1007/s11356-021-17396-4

Download citation

  • Received:

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s11356-021-17396-4

Keywords

Navigation