Skip to main content
Log in

The Poll Results Hypothesis

  • Published:
Atlantic Economic Journal Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

This empirical study seeks to broaden the interpretation of the rational voter model so as to reflect the potential impact of the results of polls of likely voters’ Presidential candidate preferences on the expected benefits of voting and hence on the voter participation rate. This study introduces the poll results hypothesis: in any given state, given the existence of the Electoral College, the greater the lead of a principal Presidential candidate over his/her closest rival as revealed in polls of likely voters, the lower, for at least some portion of prospective voters, the expected gross benefits of voting in that state and hence the lower the aggregate voter participation rate in that state. In a cross-section study of the 50 states during the 2004 general election, it is found, after allowing for a variety of other factors, that the greater the lead (as revealed in polls of likely voters) of either of the principal Presidential candidates over the other in any given state, the lower the voter turnout rate in that state.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Similar content being viewed by others

References

  • Aldrich, J. H. (1993). Rational choice and turnout. American Journal of Political Science, 37(2), 246–278.

    Google Scholar 

  • Aldrich, J. H., & Simon, D. M. (1986). Turnout in American national elections. In: S. Long (Ed.), Research in micropolitics, pp. 54–66. Greenwich, CT: JAI.

    Google Scholar 

  • Ashenfelter, O., & Kelley, S., Jr. (1975). Determinants of participation in presidential elections. Journal of Law and Economics, 18(4), 695–733.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Barreto, M. A., Segura, G. M., & Woods, N. D. (2004). The mobilizing effect of majority–minority districts on Latino turnout. American Political Science Review, 98(1), 65–76.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Borgers, T. (2004). Costly voting. American Economic Review, 94(1), 57–66.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Brazel, Y., & Silberberg, E. (1973). Is the act of voting rational? Public Choice, 16(1), 51–58.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Buchanan, J. M., & Tullock, G. (1962). The calculus of consent. Ann Arbor, MI: University of Michigan Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Cebula, R. J. (2001). The electoral college and voter participation: evidence on two hypotheses using results from the 1996 presidential election. Atlantic Economic Journal, 30(1), 67–75.

    Google Scholar 

  • Cebula, R. J. (2003). Tax evasion as a vote of disapproval of PAC election campaign contributions. Atlantic Economic Journal, 31(4), 756–765.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cebula, R. J. (2004). Expressive voting: alternative evidence. Atlantic Economic Journal, 32(3), 561–567.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cebula, R. J., & Kafoglis, M. (1983). In search of optimum relative unanimity. Public Choice, 40(2), 195–202.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Copeland, C., & Laband, D. (2002). Expressive voting. Public Choice, 110(3), 351–363.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cox, G. W., & Munger, M. C. (1989). Closeness, expenditures, and turnout in the 1982 U.S. House Elections. American Political Science Review, 83(2), 217–231.

    Google Scholar 

  • Downs, A. (1957). An economic theory of democracy. New York, NY: Harper and Row.

    Google Scholar 

  • Feddersen, T. J. (2004). Rational choice theory and the paradox of not voting. Journal of Economic Perspectives, 18(1), 99–112.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Green, D. P., Shapiro, I. (1994). Pathologies of rational choice theory: A critique of applications in political science. New Haven, CT: Yale University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Greene, K. V., & Nikolaev, O. (1999). Voter participation and the redistributive state. Public Choice, 98(2), 213–226.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • http://www.americanresearchgroup.com/ec2004/

  • http://www.census.gov/hhes/income/4person.html

  • http://www.uselectionatlas.org/USPRESIDENT/vto.php?year=2004&datatype=national

  • Kafoglis, M., & Cebula, R. J. (1981). The Buchanan–Tullock model: some extensions. Public Choice, 36(2), 179–186.

    Google Scholar 

  • Knack, S. (1999). Drivers wanted: motor voter and the election of 1996. P.S.: Political Science and Politics, 32(3), 237–243.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lapp, M. (1999). Incorporating groups into rational choice explanations of turnout: an empirical test. Public Choice, 98(2), 171–185.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ledyard, J. (1984). The pure theory of two candidate elections. Public Choice, 44, 7–41.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Leighly, J. (1996). Group membership and the mobilization of political participation. Journal of Politics, 58(2), 447–463.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Morton, R. (1987). A group majority model of voting. Social Choice and Welfare, 4(2), 117–131.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mueller, D. (2003). Public choice III, Cambridge, UK: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Piven, F. F., & Cloward, R. A. (1988). Why American don’t vote. New York, NY: Pantheon Books.

    Google Scholar 

  • Putnam, R. D. (2000). Bowling alone. New York, NY: Simon & Schuster.

    Google Scholar 

  • Riker, W. H., & Ordeshook, P. C. (1968). A theory to the calculus of voting. American Politcal Science Review, 62(1), 25–42.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Schram, A. J. H. C. (1992). Testing economic theories of voter behavior using micro-data. Applied Economics, 24(4), 419–428.

    Google Scholar 

  • Schwartz, T. (1987). Your vote counts on account of the way it is counted: an institutional solution to the paradox of voting. Public Choice, 54(1), 101–121.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Teixeira, R. (1992). The disappearing American voter. Washington, D.C.: The Brookings Institution.

    Google Scholar 

  • Tiebout, C. M. (1956). A pure theory of public expenditures. Journal of Political Economy, 64(2), 416–424.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Tullock, G. (1967). Towards a mathematics of politics. Ann Arbor, MI: University of Michigan Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Tullock, G. (1971). Public decisions as public goods. Journal of Political Economy, 79(4), 913–918.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • U.S. Census Bureau (2005), Statistical abstract of the United States, 2004–2005. Washington, D.C.: U.S. Government Printing Office.

    Google Scholar 

  • Verba, S., Schlozman, K. L., & Brady, H. E. (1995). Voice and equality: Civic volunteerism in American politics. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • White, H. (1980). A heteroskedasticity-consistent covariance matrix estimator and a direct test for heteroskedasticity. Econometrica, 48(4), 817–838.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Wolfinger, R. E., & Rosenstonem, S. J. (1980). Who votes? New Haven, CT: Yale University Press.

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Richard J. Cebula.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Cite this article

Cebula, R.J., Hulse, D. The Poll Results Hypothesis. Atl Econ J 35, 33–41 (2007). https://doi.org/10.1007/s11293-006-9048-4

Download citation

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s11293-006-9048-4

Keywords

JEL Classifications

Navigation