Skip to main content
Log in

Local knowledge composition and the emergence of entrepreneurial activities across industries: evidence from Italian NUTS-3 regions

  • Published:
Small Business Economics Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

This paper investigates how the characteristics of the local knowledge bases, stemming from the accumulation and recombination of competences over time, spur the emergence of new entrepreneurial activities across industries at the Italian provincial level. To do so, we exploit information on the number of new firms appearing across diverse industries in each Italian NUTS-3 region (province) from 1997 to 2009 as an indicator of local entrepreneurial activity. To build indicators of both local technological knowledge stocks and local technological knowledge compositions, we collect information on patenting activity at the provincial level. Our findings suggest that the availability of local knowledge spillovers is not sufficient per se to trigger the creation of new firms. Indeed, looking at the properties of local knowledge bases, the rate of new firm formation appears to be higher in contexts featured by knowledge stemming from search activities shaped by the accumulated competences and dispersed across a wide area of the technology landscape. This suggests that, in Italy, entrepreneurship is mostly related to the exploitation of technological knowledge accumulated over time rather than to profiting from radical breakthroughs.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. See Vivarelli (2013) and Quatraro and Vivarelli (2015) for an extensive review of the determinants of entry dynamics and post-entry performances.

  2. See, for example, the special issue appeared in Small Business Economics in May 2011, titled “Entrepreneurial Dynamics and Regional Growth”

  3. Bae and Koo (2008) and Bishop (2012) provide empirical investigations in this direction.

  4. Italian NUTS-3 regions correspond exactly to Italian province administrative divisions. The Italian NUTS-3 classification changed in 2006 and 2009, when four and three new provinces were added, respectively. To ensure coherence in the dataset, we use the before 2006 classification. This poses a problem only with respect to the Barletta-Andria-Trani Province, which gathers together seven municipalities that were previously part of the Bari Province and three municipalities that were part of the Foggia Province. Data at the municipality level are not available so that we cannot solve this problem.

  5. It is well-known that these statistics show some limitations insofar as only firms reaching a certain threshold level in terms of size are required to register for VAT. This problem, common to all large datasets, can be overcome only by implementing dedicated surveys, at the cost of reducing geographical coverage. A second shortcoming is related to the fact that a new registered firm may simply be an already existent subsidiary of a foreign company that starts its activity in Italy. In this case, even if the business is new for the local context analyzed, the firm is not a new constituted entity. Unfortunately, we are not able to distinguish this case from the case in which a completely new business is created. However, MNE localization choices are driven, amongst other factors, also by local characteristics related to the availability of local knowledge and to the composition of its structure. This should mitigate, at least partially, this possible bias affecting our measure of new firm creation.

  6. However, we do not deny that local markets are not homogenous with respect to size and that this can introduce some biases in our results. For this reason, as we specify below, we introduce the provincial level of employment amongst the control variables.

  7. This section and the related Appendix 1 extensively builds on Krafft et al. (2014), Colombelli et al. (2013), and Quatraro (2010).

  8. Patel and Soete (1985) use a similar approach.

  9. The limits of patent statistics as indicators of technological activities are well-known. The main drawbacks can be summarized in their sector-specificity, the existence of non-patentable innovations, and the fact that they are not the only protecting tool for R&D investments. Moreover, the propensity to patent tends to vary over time as a function of the cost of patenting, and it is more likely to feature large firms (Pavitt 1985; Griliches 1990). Nevertheless, previous studies highlighted the usefulness of using patents as a measure of new knowledge production. Such studies show that patents represent very reliable proxies for knowledge and innovation outcomes, as compared to analyses drawing upon surveys directly investigating the dynamics of process and product innovation (Acs et al. 2002). Besides the debate about patents as an output rather than an input of innovation activities, empirical analyses showed that patents and R&D are dominated by a contemporaneous relationship, providing further support to the use of patents as a good proxy of technological activities (Hall et al. 1986).

  10. In the calculations, we use four-digit technological classes.

  11. It must be stressed that to compensate for intrinsic volatility of patenting behavior, each patent application is made last 5 years to reduce the noise induced by changes in technological strategy.

  12. A complete description of the implemented local knowledge measures is provided in Appendix 1.

  13. Results do not differ significantly from our preferred specifications and are available upon request by the authors.

  14. Tables 8, 9, 10, 11, and 12 in Appendix 2 report the results of the baseline estimations and further robustness checks. Precisely, presents the results of the estimations when we maintain the same structure as the regressions presented in the main text but estimating our models on the entire sample (i.e., without differentiating between Pavitt sectors). These regressions show the positive impact of higher local knowledge availability on firm formation. Importantly, they signal for the importance of local knowledge variety, while knowledge coherence seems to negatively affect firm creation. Finally, technological cognitive distance seems to not significantly affect firm formation. Tables 9, 10, 11, and 12 present instead the results for the sector-specific estimations when we exclude the main control variables described in Sect. 3.2.3. Relying on these latter estimations, AIC and BIC statistics suggest that adding control variables as we do for the main estimates significantly increases the robustness of our models.

  15. For the sake of clarity, the region and time indexes are omitted.

  16. For Engelsman and van Raan (1991), this approach produces meaningful results particularly at a “macro” level, i.e., for mapping the entire domain of technology.

References

  • Acs, Z. J., & Audretsch, D. B. (1989a). Small-Firm Entry in U.S. Manufacturing, Economica, London. School of Economics and Political Science, 56(222), 255–265.

    Google Scholar 

  • Acs, Z.J., and Audretsch, David B., (1989b). Small firms in U.S. manufacturing: A first report, Economics Letters, Elsevier, vol. 31(4), pages 399–402, December.

  • Acs, Z.J., Anselin, L., Varga, A., (2002). Patents and innovation counts as measures of regional production of new knowledge, research policy, Elsevier, vol. 31(7), pages 1069-1085, September.

  • Acs, Z. J., Audretsch, D. B., Braunerhjelm, P., & Carlsson, B. (2003). The missing link: The knowledge filter and endogenous growth. Stockholm: Center for Business and Policy Studies.

    Google Scholar 

  • Acs, Z. J., Braunerhjelm, P., Audretsch, D. B., & Carlsson, B. (2009). The knowledge spillover theory of entrepreneurship. Small Business Economics, 32(1), 15–30.

    Google Scholar 

  • Acs, Z. J., Audretsch, D. B., & Lehmann, E. E. (2013). The knowledge spillover theory of entrepreneurship. Small Business Economics, 41(4), 757–774.

    Google Scholar 

  • Aghion, P., & Howitt, P. (1992). A model of growth. Through creative destruction. Econometrica, 60(2), 323–351.

    Google Scholar 

  • Audretsch, D.B. (1995). Innovation and industry evolution, MIT Press Books, The MIT Press, edition 1, volume 1, number 0262011468, July.

  • Audretsch, D.B. & Fritsch, M., (1993). A note on the measurement of entry rates, papers 93–5, Bergakademie Freiberg Technical University - Faculty of Economics and Business Administration.

  • Audretsch, D. B., & Fritsch, M. (2002). Growth regimes over time and space. Regional Studies, 36, 113–124.

    Google Scholar 

  • Audretsch, D. B., & Keilbach, M. (2007). The theory of knowledge spillover entrepreneurship. Journal of Management Studies, Wiley Blackwell, 44(7), 1242–1254 November.

    Google Scholar 

  • Audretsch, D. B., & Lehmann, E. E. (2005). Do university policies make a difference? Research Policy, Elsevier, 34(3), 343–347 April.

    Google Scholar 

  • Audretsch, D. B., & Mahmood, T. (1995). New firm survival: New results using a Hazard function. The Review of Economics and Statistics, MIT Press, 77(1), 97–103.

    Google Scholar 

  • Audretsch, D. B., & Vivarelli, M. (1995). New-firm formation in Italy: A first report. Economics Letters, Elsevier, 48(1), 77–81.

    Google Scholar 

  • Audretsch, D.B., and Vivarelli, M., (1996). Determinants of new-firm startups in Italy, Empirica, Springer; Austrian Institute for Economic Research; Austrian economic association, vol. 23(1), pages 91-105, February.

  • Audretsch, D. B., Santarelli, E., & Vivarelli, M. (1999). Start-up size and industrial dynamics: Some evidence from Italian manufacturing. International Journal of Industrial Organization, Elsevier, 17(7), 965–983.

    Google Scholar 

  • Audretsch, D. B., Keilbach, M. C., & Lehmann, E. E. (2006). Entrepreneurship and economic growth. Oxford: Oxford University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Audretsch, D. B., Falck, O., Feldman, M. P., & Heblich, S. (2012). Local entrepreneurship in context. Regional Studies, Taylor & Francis Journals, 46(3), 379–389 April.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bae, J., & Koo, J. (2008). The nature of local knowledge and firm formation. Industrial and Corporate Change, 18, 1–24.

    Google Scholar 

  • Birch, D. (1979). The job generation process. Cambridge: MIT program on Neighbourhood and regional change.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bishop, P. (2012). Knowledge, diversity and entrepreneurship: a spatial analysis of new firm formation in Great Britain. Entrepreneurship and Regional Development, 24(7–8), 641–660.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bonaccorsi, A., Colombo, M. G., Guerini, M., & Rossi-Lamastra, C. (2013). University specialization and new firm creation across industries. Small Business Economics, 41(4), 837–863.

    Google Scholar 

  • Boschma, R. (2005). Proximity and innovation: A critical assessment, Regional Studies. Taylor & Francis Journals, 39(1), 61–74.

    Google Scholar 

  • Boschma, R. (2014). Constructing regional advantage and smart specialisation: Comparison of two European policy concepts. Scienze Regionali, FrancoAngeli Editore, 2014(1), 51–68.

    Google Scholar 

  • Boschma, R., & Iammarino, S. (2009). Related variety, trade linkages, and regional growth in Italy. Economic Geography, 85, 289–311.

    Google Scholar 

  • Boschma, R., Iammarino, S., & Steinmueller, E. (2013). Editorial: Geography, skills and technological change. Regional Studies, Taylor & Francis Journals, 47(10), 1615–1617 November.

    Google Scholar 

  • Breschi, S., Lissoni, F., & Malerba, F. (2003). Knowledge relatedness in firm technological diversification. Research Policy, 32, 69–97.

    Google Scholar 

  • Carree, M. A., & Thurik, A. R. (2003). The impact of entrepreneurship on economic growth. In Z. J. Acs & D. B. Audretsch (Eds.), Handbook of entrepreneurship research Boston. Dordrecht: Kluwer Academic Publishers.

    Google Scholar 

  • Cassia, L., and Colombelli, A., (2008). Do universities knowledge spillovers impact on new firm’s growth? Empirical evidence from UK, International Entrepreneurship and Management Journal, Springer, pp 13, pages 453–465, ISSN: 1554-7191.

  • Cassia, L., Colombelli, A., Paleari, S., (2009). Firms’ growth: Does the innovation system matter?, structural change and economic dynamics, Elsevier, vol. 20(3), pages 211-220, September.

  • Colombelli, A. (2016). The impact of local knowledge bases on the creation of innovative start-ups in Italy. Small Business Economics, 47, 383.

    Google Scholar 

  • Colombelli, A., Krafft, J., Quatraro F. (2013). Properties of knowledge base and firm survival: Evidence from a sample of French manufacturing firms, Technological Forecasting and Social Change, Elsevier, vol. 80(8), pages 1469–1483.

  • Colombelli, A., Krafft, J., & Quatraro, F. (2014a). The emergence of new technology-based sectors in European regions: A proximity-based analysis of nanotechnology. Research Policy, Elsevier, 43(10), 1681–1696.

    Google Scholar 

  • Colombelli, A., Krafft, J., & Quatraro, F. (2014b). High growth firms and knowledge structure: Evidence from a sample of listed companies. Industrial and Corporate Change, 23(1), 261–291.

    Google Scholar 

  • Colombo, M. G., & Delmastro, M. (2002). How effective are technology incubators? Evidence from Italy. Research Policy, 31(7), 1103–1122.

    Google Scholar 

  • Creedy, J., & Johnson, P. S. (1983). Firm formation in manufacturing industry. Applied Economics, 15, 177–185.

    Google Scholar 

  • Delgado, M., Porter, M. E., & Stern, S. (2010). Clusters and entrepreneurship. Journal of Economic Geography, 10(4), 495–518.

    Google Scholar 

  • Engelsman, E.C., van Raan, A.F.J., (1991). Mapping of technology, a first exploration of knowledge diffusion amongst fields of technology. Report to the Netherlands Ministry of Economic Affairs, published in the Policy Studies on Technology and Economy (BTE) Series, Nr.15 (ISSN 0923-3164), The Hague.

  • Engelsman, E. C., & van Raan, A. F. J. (1994). A patent-based cartography of technology. Research Policy, 23(1), 1–26.

    Google Scholar 

  • Evans, D. S., & Leighton, L. S. (1990). Small business formation by unemployed and employed workers. Small Business Economics, 2, 319.

    Google Scholar 

  • Feldman, M. P. (2001). The entrepreneurial event revisited: Firm formation in a regional context. Industrial and Corporate Change, 10(4), 861–891.

    Google Scholar 

  • Fleming, L. (2001). Recombinant uncertainty in technological search. Management Science, 47(1), 117–132.

    Google Scholar 

  • Fleming, L., & Sorenson, O. (2001). Technology as a complex adaptive system: Evidence from patent data. Research Policy, 30, 1019–1039.

    Google Scholar 

  • Foray, D. (2015). Smart specialisation: Opportunities and challenges for regional innovation policy. London: Routledge.

    Google Scholar 

  • Foray, D., David, P.A., Hall, B. (2009), Smart specialisation: The concept. In Knowledge for Growth Expert European Issues and Policy Challenge, Group Policy Brief No. 9, European Commission, Bruxelles.

  • Foti, A., and Vivarelli, M., (1994). An econometric test of the self-employment model: The case of Italy, Small Business Economics, Springer, vol. 6(2), pages 81–93, April.

  • Frenken, K., and Boschma, R.A., (2007). A theoretical framework for evolutionary economic geography: Industrial dynamics and urban growth as a branching process, Journal of Economic Geography, Oxford University Press, vol. 7(5), pages 635–649, September.

  • Frenken, K., Nuvolari, A. (2004). Entropy statistics as a framework to analyse technological evolution, in J. Foster and W. Ho¨lzl (eds), Applied Evolutionary Economics and Complex Systems. Edward Elgar: Cheltenham, UK; Northampton, MA.

  • Frenken, K., Van Oort, F., & Verburg, T. (2007). Related variety, unrelated variety and regional economic growth, Regional Studies. Taylor & Francis Journals, 41(5), 685–697.

    Google Scholar 

  • Fritsch, M., (2013). Entrepreneurship, innovation and regional development: An introduction. Papers in Regional Science, Wiley Blackwell, vol. 92(3), pages 683–684.

  • Fritsch, M., & Schindele, Y. (2011). The contribution of new businesses to regional employment—an empirical analysis. Economic Geography, 87(2), 153–180.

  • Geroski, P. (1995). What do we know about entry? International Journal of Industrial Organization, 13(4), 421–440.

    Google Scholar 

  • Greene, W.H., (2003). Econometric analysis. Prentice hall.

  • Griliches, Z., (1990). Patent Statistics as Economic Indicators: A Survey. NBER Working Paper No. 3301 (Also Reprint No. r1524).

  • Hall, B.H., Griliches, Z., Hausman, J.A., (1986). Patents and R and D: Is there a lag?, international economic review, Department of Economics, University of Pennsylvania and Osaka University Institute of social and economic research association, vol. 27(2), pages 265-283, June.

  • Hartog, M., Boschma, R., & Sotarauta, M. (2012). The impact of related variety on regional employment growth in Finland 1993-2006: High-tech versus medium/low-tech. Industry and Innovation, 19(6), 459–476.

    Google Scholar 

  • Jaffe, A. B. (1986). Technological opportunity and spillovers of R&D: Evidence from firms’ patents, profits, and market value. American Economic Review, 76(5), 984–1001.

    Google Scholar 

  • Jaffe, A. B. (1989). Real effects of academic research. American Economic Review, 79(5), 957–970.

    Google Scholar 

  • Khemani, R. S., & Shapiro, D. M. (1986). The determinants of new plant entry in Canada. Applied Economics, 18, 1243–1257.

    Google Scholar 

  • Knight, F.H., (1921). Risk, uncertainty, and profit. Boston, MA: Hart, Schaffner & Marx; Houghton Mifflin Co.

  • Krafft, J., Quatraro, F., Saviotti, P., (2014). Knowledge characteristics and the dynamics of technological alliances in pharmaceuticals: Empirical evidence from Europe, US and Japan, journal of evolutionary economics, springer, vol. 24(3), pages 587-622, July.

  • Lee, S. Y., Florida, R., & Acs, Z. (2004). Creativity and entrepreneurship: A regional analysis of new firm formation. Regional Studies, 38(4), 879–891.

    Google Scholar 

  • Mansfield, E. (1962). Entry, Gibrat's law, innovation, and the growth of firms. American Economic Review, 52(5), 1023–10 1962.

    Google Scholar 

  • Neffke, F., Henning, M., Boschma, R., (2009). How do regions diversify over time? Industry relatedness and the development of new growth paths in regions, Papers in Evolutionary Economic Geography (PEEG) 0916, Utrecht University, Section of Economic Geography, revised Oct 2009.

  • Nesta, L. (2008). Knowledge and productivity in the world’s largest manufacturing corporations. Journal of Economic Behaviour and Organization, 67, 886–902.

    Google Scholar 

  • Nesta, L., & Saviotti, P. P. (2006). Firm knowledge and market value in biotechnology. Industrial and Corporate Change, 15(4), 625–652.

    Google Scholar 

  • Orr, D. (1974). A note on the uselessness of transaction demand models. The Journal of Finance, 29(5), 1565–1572.

    Google Scholar 

  • Oxenfeldt, A. (1943). New firms and free Enterprise. Washington, D.C.: American Council on Public Affairs.

    Google Scholar 

  • Patel, P., & Soete, L. (1985). Recherche-développement importations de technologie et croissance économique: Une tentative de comparaison internationale. Revue Economique, 36(5), 975–1000.

    Google Scholar 

  • Pavitt, K. (1984). Sectoral patterns of technical change: Towards a taxonomy and a theory. Research Policy, 13(6), 343–373.

    Google Scholar 

  • Qian, H., Acs, Z. J., & Stough, R. R. (2013). Regional systems of entrepreneurship: The nexus of human capital, knowledge and new firm formation. Journal of Economic Geography, 13(4), 559–587.

    Google Scholar 

  • Quatraro, F. (2010). Knowledge coherence, variety and productivity growth: Manufacturing evidence from Italian regions. Research Policy, 39, 1289–1302.

    Google Scholar 

  • Quatraro, F., and Vivarelli, M., (2015). Drivers of entrepreneurship and post-entry performance of newborn firms in developing countries, World Bank Research Observer, World Bank Group, vol. 30(2), pages 277–305.

  • Reynolds, P.D. (1997). Who Starts New Firms? - Preliminary Explorations of Firms-in-Gestation. Small Business Economics, 9, 449–462.

  • Reynolds, P., Storey, D. J., & Westhead, P. (1994). Cross-national comparisons of the variation in new firm formation rates. Regional Studies, 28(4), 443–456.

    Google Scholar 

  • Santarelli, E., Carree, M., & Verheul, I. (2009). Unemployment and firm entry and exit: An update on a controversial relationship. Regional Studies, 43, 1061–1073.

    Google Scholar 

  • Saviotti, P. P., (1988). Information, variety and entropy in technoeconomic development, Research Policy, Elsevier, vol. 17(2), pages 89–103, April.

  • Schumpeter, J.A. (1934), The theory of economic development, Cambridge (mass.), Harvard University Press.

  • Schumpeter, J. A. (1939). Business cycles: A theoretical, historical and statistical analysis of the capitalist process. New York: McGraw-Hill.

    Google Scholar 

  • Stam, E. (2007). Why butterflies don’t leave: Locational behavior of new firms. Economic Geography, 83(1), 27–50.

    Google Scholar 

  • Sternberg, R. (2009). Regional dimensions of entrepreneurship. Foundations and Trends in Entrepreneurship, 5(4), 211–340.

    Google Scholar 

  • Storey, D. J. (1991). The birth of new firms – Does unemployment matter? A review of the evidence. Small Business Economics, 3(3), 167–178.

    Google Scholar 

  • Tamásy, C. (2006). Determinants of regional entrepreneurship dynamics in contemporary Germany: A conceptual and empirical analysis. Regional Studies, 40(4), 365–384.

    Google Scholar 

  • Teece, D., Rumelt, R., Dosi, G., & Winter, S. (1994). Understanding corporate coherence: Theory and evidence. Journal of Economic Behaviour and Organization, 23(1), 1–30.

    Google Scholar 

  • Vivarelli, M., (2004). Are all the potential entrepreneurs so good?, Small Business Economics, Springer, vol. 23(1), pages 41–49, 08.

  • Vivarelli, M., (2013). Is entrepreneurship necessarily good? Microeconomic evidence from developed and developing countries, Industrial and Corporate Change, Oxford University Press, vol. 22(6), pages 1453-1495, December.

  • Wagner, J., & Sternberg, R. (2004). Start-up activities, individual characteristics, and the regional milieu: Lessons for entrepreneurship support policies from German micro data. The Annals of Regional Science, 38(2), 219–240.

    Google Scholar 

  • Weitzman, M. L. (1998). Recombinant growth. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 113, 331–360.

    Google Scholar 

  • Wennekers, A. R. M., & Thurik, A. R. (1999). Linking entrepreneurship and economic growth. Small Business Economics, 13, 27–55.

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Alessandra Colombelli.

Additional information

Publisher’s note

Springer Nature remains neutral with regard to jurisdictional claims in published maps and institutional affiliations.

Appendices

Appendix 1. Internal characteristics of the knowledge base

1.1 Knowledge variety

Knowledge variety is measured using the information entropy index.Footnote 15 Entropy measures the degree of disorder or randomness of the system; systems characterized by high entropy are characterized by high degrees of uncertainty (Saviotti 1988). Informational entropy is a diversity measure which allows to account for variety, i.e., the number of categories into which system elements are apportioned, and balance, i.e., the distribution of system elements across categories.

Information entropy has some interesting properties (Frenken and Nuvolari 2004), including multidimensionality. Consider a pair of events (Xl, Yj), and the probability of their co-occurrence plj. A two-dimensional total variety (TV) measure can be expressed as follows:

$$ \mathrm{KV}\equiv \mathrm{H}\left(\mathrm{X},\mathrm{Y}\right)=\sum \limits_{\mathrm{l}}\sum \limits_{\mathrm{j}}{\mathrm{p}}_{\mathrm{l}\mathrm{j}}{\log}_2\left(\frac{1}{{\mathrm{p}}_{\mathrm{l}\mathrm{j}}}\right) $$
(10)

Let the events Xl and Yj be citation in a patent document of technological classes l and j, respectively. Then, plj is the probability that two technological classes l and j co-occur within the same patent. The measure of multidimensional entropy, therefore, focuses on the variety of co-occurrences or pairs of technological classes within patent applications.

The total index can be decomposed into “within” and “between” parts whenever the events being investigated can be aggregated into a smaller number of subsets. Within-entropy measures the average degree of disorder or variety within the subsets; between-entropy focuses on the subsets, measuring the variety across them. Let the technologies i and j belong to the subsets g and z of the classification scheme, respectively. If one allows lSg and jSz (g = 1,…,G; z = 1,…, Z), we can write:

$$ {P}_{gz}=\sum \limits_{l\in {S}_g}\sum \limits_{j\in {S}_Z}{p}_{lj} $$
(11)

which is the probability to observe the couple lj in the subsets g and z, while the intra subsets variety can be measured as follows:

$$ {H}_{gz}=\sum \limits_{l\in {S}_g}\sum \limits_{j\in {S}_z}\frac{p_{lj}}{P_{gz}} lo{g}_2\left(\frac{1}{p_{lj}/{P}_{gz}}\right) $$
(12)

The (weighted) within-group entropy can be finally written as follows:

$$ \mathrm{RKV}\equiv \sum \limits_{\mathrm{g}=1}^{\mathrm{G}}\sum \limits_{\mathrm{z}=1}^{\mathrm{Z}}{\mathrm{P}}_{\mathrm{g}\mathrm{z}}{\mathrm{H}}_{\mathrm{g}\mathrm{z}} $$
(13)

Between-group (or unrelated variety) can instead be calculated by using the following equation:

$$ \mathrm{UKV}\equiv {\mathrm{H}}_{\mathrm{Q}}=\sum \limits_{\mathrm{g}=1}^{\mathrm{G}}\sum \limits_{\mathrm{z}=1}^{\mathrm{Z}}{\mathrm{P}}_{\mathrm{g}\mathrm{z}}{\log}_2\frac{1}{{\mathrm{P}}_{\mathrm{g}\mathrm{z}}} $$
(14)

According to the decomposition theorem, we can rewrite the total entropy H(X,Y) as follows:

$$ \mathrm{KV}={\mathrm{H}}_{\mathrm{Q}}+\sum \limits_{\mathrm{g}=1}^{\mathrm{G}}\sum \limits_{\mathrm{z}=1}^{\mathrm{Z}}{\mathrm{P}}_{\mathrm{g}\mathrm{z}}{\mathrm{H}}_{\mathrm{g}\mathrm{z}} $$
(15)

Within-group entropy (or related variety) measures the degree of technological differentiation within the macro-field, while between-group variety (or unrelated variety) measures the degree of technological differentiation across macro-fields. The first term on the right-hand-side of Eq. (A6) is the between-entropy, and the second term is the (weighted) within-entropy.

We can label between- and within-entropy respectively as unrelated technological variety (UKV) and related technological variety (RKV), while total information entropy is referred to as general technological variety (Frenken et al. 2007; Boschma and Iammarino 2009). This means that we consider variety not only as a global entity but also as a new combination of existing bits of knowledge versus variety as a combination of new bits of knowledge. When variety is high (respectively low), this means that the search process has been extensive (respectively partial). When unrelated variety is high compared to related variety, the search process is based essentially on the combination of novel bits of knowledge rather than new combinations of existing bits of knowledge.

1.2 Knowledge coherence

We calculate the coherence of the regional (NUTS-3) knowledge bases, defined as the average relatedness or complementarity of a technology chosen randomly within the firm’s patent portfolio with respect to any other technology (Nesta and Saviotti 2006; Nesta 2008; Quatraro 2010).

Obtaining the knowledge coherence index requires a number of steps. First of all, we need to calculate the weighted average relatedness WARl of technology l with respect to all other technologies in the regional patent portfolio. This measure builds on the measure of technological relatedness amongst any pair of technologies i and j, τlj.

Following Teece et al. (1994), the weighted average relatedness, WARl is defined as the degree to which technology l is related to all other technologies jl in the region’s patent portfolio, weighted by patent count Pjt:

$$ WA{R}_{lt}=\frac{\sum_{j\ne l}{\tau}_{lj}{P}_{jt}}{\sum_{j\ne l}{P}_{jt}} $$
(16)

Finally, the coherence of the region’s knowledge base at time t is defined as the weighted average of the WARlt measure:

$$ CO{H}_t=\sum \limits_l WA{R}_{lt}\times \frac{P_{lt}}{\sum_l{P}_{lt}} $$
(17)

Note that this index implemented by analyzing the co-occurrence of technological classes within patent applications measures the degree to which the services rendered by the co-occurring technologies are complementary and is based on how frequently technological classes are combined in use. The relatedness measure τlj indicates that utilization of technology l implies use also of technology j in order to perform specific functions that are not reducible to their independent use.

1.3 Cognitive Distance

A useful index of distance can be derived from technological proximity proposed by Jaffe (1986, 1989), who investigated the proximity of firms’ technological portfolios. Breschi et al. (2003) adapted this index to measure the proximity between two technologies.

Let Plk = 1 if the patent k is assigned the technology l [l = 1, …, n], and 0 otherwise. The total number of patents assigned to technology l is Ol = ∑kPlk. Similarly, the total number of patents assigned to technology j is Oj = ∑kPjk. The number of patents that are classified in both technological fields l and j is \( {V}_{lj}=\sum \limits_k{P}_{lk}{P}_{jk} \). By applying this count of joint occurrences to all possible pairs of classification codes, we obtain a square symmetrical matrix of co-occurrences whose generic cell Vlj reports the number of patent documents classified in both of the technological fields l and j.

Technological proximity is proxied by the cosine index, which is calculated for a pair of technologies l and j as the angular separation or uncentered correlation of the vectors Vlm and Vjm. The similarity of technologies l and j can then be defined as follows:

$$ {S}_{\mathrm{lj}}=\frac{\sum_{m=1}^n{V}_{\mathrm{lm}}{V}_{\mathrm{jm}}}{\sqrt{\sum_{m=1}^n{V}_{\mathrm{lm}}^2}\sqrt{\sum_{m=1}^n{V}_{\mathrm{jm}}^2}} $$
(18)

The cosine index provides a measure of the similarity between two technological fields in terms of their mutual relationships with all the other fields. The greater the Slj, the more two technologies l and j co-occur with the same technologies. It is equal to one for pairs of technological fields with identical distribution of co-occurrences with all the other technological fields, while it goes to zero if vectors Vlm and Vjm are orthogonal (Breschi et al. 2003).Footnote 16 Similarity between technological classes is thus calculated on the basis of their relative position in the technology space. The closer technologies are in the technology space, the higher is Slj and the lower their cognitive distance (Engelsman and van Raan 1994; Jaffe 1986; Breschi et al. 2003).

The cognitive distance between j and l can be therefore measured as the complement of their index of technological proximity:

$$ {d}_{lj}=1-{S}_{lj} $$
(19)

Having calculated the index for all possible pairs, it needs to be aggregated at the regional level to obtain a synthetic index of distance amongst the technologies in the firm’s patent portfolio. This is done in two steps. First, we compute the weighted average distance (WAD) of technology l, i.e., the average distance of l from all other technologies.

$$ WA{D}_{lt}=\frac{\sum_{j\ne l}{d}_{lj}{P}_{jt}}{\sum_{j\ne l}{P}_{jt}} $$
(20)

where Pj is the number of patents in which the technology j is observed. The average cognitive distance at time t is obtained as follows:

$$ C{D}_t={\sum}_l WA{D}_{lt}\times \frac{P_{lt}}{\sum_l{P}_{lt}} $$
(21)

The cognitive distance index measures the inverse of the similarity degree amongst technologies. When cognitive distance is high, it signals the combination of core technologies with unfamiliar technologies.

Appendix 2. Further results

Table 8 Econometric results (full sample)
Table 9 Econometric results (SB – no controls)
Table 10 Econometric results (SS – no controls)
Table 11 Econometric results (SI – no controls)
Table 12 Econometric results (SD – no controls)

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Colombelli, A., Orsatti, G. & Quatraro, F. Local knowledge composition and the emergence of entrepreneurial activities across industries: evidence from Italian NUTS-3 regions. Small Bus Econ 56, 613–635 (2021). https://doi.org/10.1007/s11187-019-00192-3

Download citation

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s11187-019-00192-3

Keywords

JEL classifications

Navigation