Skip to main content
Log in

Advertising intensity, investor recognition, and implied cost of capital

  • Original Research
  • Published:
Review of Quantitative Finance and Accounting Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

The main purpose of this paper is to test Merton’s (J Finance 42(3):483–510, 1987) hypothesis that better investor recognition is correlated with lower expected returns. We measure investor recognition with the firms’ advertising intensity and offer consistent evidence that higher advertising intensity is associated with lower implied cost of capital, as derived from Value Line target prices and dividend forecasts. Investor recognition plays an important role in attracting investors, improving liquidity, and ultimately reducing the cost of capital. The findings shed light on the capital market implications of advertising expenditures and complement the extant research on investor recognition.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. Specifically, he conjectures that “[the] model provides a rationale for expenditures on advertising about the firm that is targeted for investors and on public relations designed to generate stories about the firm in the financial press” (Merton 1987, p. 501).

  2. In the paper, we use implied cost of (equity) capital and ex ante cost of (equity) capital interchangeably.

  3. In their study, improved liquidity includes the reduced bid-ask spread, smaller price impacts, and greater depth for the common stock of the advertising firm.

  4. The liquidity issue can be more important in emerging market, as evidenced in Hsieh et al. (2008).

  5. However, it should be noted that Chan et al. (2001) seek to investigate the valuation effects of a firm’s intangible assets, such as advertising expenditures, rather than highlighting their role in increasing the firm’s visibility.

  6. Elton (1999) identifies a few market phenomena that cast doubt on the belief that realized return can be averaged to proxy expected return. For example, from 1973 to 1984, realized returns on average were lower than the risk free rate; from 1927 to 1981, risky long-term bonds under-performed the risk free rate; and in the recent past, the US has had stock market returns of higher than 30% per year while Asian markets have had negative returns, although the US market should not have been riskier than the Asian market in this period.

  7. In their examination of the inter-temporal risk-return relationship, Pastor et al. (2008) show that with moderate assumptions, the implied cost of capital can be perfectly correlated with the conditional expected return over time.

  8. Stern Stewart provides information on WACC for the 1,000 best performing—in terms of market value added—companies.

  9. PEG stands for price/earnings/growth.

  10. Implementation of the Ohlson and Juettner-Nauroth (2005) model requires positive and increasing earnings forecasts (in order to impute positive growth rates). For firms where analysts’ long-term growth forecasts are not available, Gebhardt et al. (2001) also require that a firm have positive and increasing earnings forecasts for year t + 1 and t + 2. Easton’s (2004) PEG and MPEG approaches also require that earnings forecasts be both positive and increasing.

  11. We also use different deflators in computing advertising intensity as robustness checks. We find results with book-value- and market-value- adjusted advertising expenditures, but no results with sales-adjusted advertising expenditures.

  12. For example, all VL report in January, February, or March are assigned to the first calendar quarter of the year.

  13. The results are similar if we use the COC estimates in the fourth quarter of the same calendar year or the average value of the quarterly COC estimates within the same calendar year.

  14. They find that, over a 34-year period, the average return on stocks with high sensitivities to liquidity exceeds that for stocks with low sensitivities by 7.5% annually, adjusted for exposures to the market return as well as size, value, and momentum factors.

  15. The specification is as follows:

    $$ {\frac{{{\text{TCA}}_{\text{it}} }}{{{\text{Assets}}_{\text{it}} }}} = \phi_{0} + \phi_{1} {\frac{{{\text{CFO}}_{{{\text{it}} - 1}} }}{{{\text{Assets}}_{\text{it}} }}} + \phi_{2} {\frac{{{\text{CFO}}_{\text{it}} }}{{{\text{Assets}}_{\text{it}} }}} + \phi_{3} {\frac{{{\text{CFO}}_{{{\text{it}} + 1}} }}{{{\text{Assets}}_{\text{it}} }}} + \nu_{\text{it}} $$

    where TCA is total current accruals (=∆CA − ∆CL − ∆Cash + ∆STDEBT). Assets are total assets (#6); CFO is cash flows from operations computed as net income before extraordinary items (#18) minus total accruals (=∆CA − ∆CL − ∆Cash + ∆STDEBT-Dep); ∆CA is change in current assets (item #4) between year t − 1 and year t; ∆CL is change in current liabilities (item #5); ∆Cash is change in cash (item #1); ∆STDEBT is change in debt in current liabilities (item #34); Dep is depreciation and amortization expense (#14).

  16. The opposite trend in advertising intensity and ex ante cost-of-capital estimate over time will not affect our inferences, because we are testing their cross-sectional relationship.

  17. To account for the serially correlated dividend expectation, we also estimate a pooled regression and assess statistical inference using Newey and West’s (1987) standard errors, which control for unspecified heteroscedasticity and autocorrelation effects. Results from this procedure yield similar inferences.

  18. To see this, assume that a constant growth model holds and that the spread between the cost of equity and the permanent dividend growth rate is no greater than 5%. Denote V 0(R 0) as the firm value (cost-of-equity capital) before the increase in advertising intensity and V 1(R 1) as the firm value (cost-of-equity capital) after the increase in advertising intensity. Assume no changes in expected dividends and a constant dividend growth rate of g. Then V 1/V 0 = (R 0 − g)/(R 1 − g) = 1+(R 0 − R 1)/(R 1 − g) ≥ 1 + 0.36%/5% = 1.072.

  19. In particular, we follow Erickson and Jacobson (1992) in including the following variables as additional instruments: the natural logarithm of total assets, firm age, leverage, the firm-level abnormal return-to-equity, the industry-level abnormal return-to-equity, the Herfindahl index on sales within an industry, and the industry dummies as classified by Fama and French (1997).

  20. Estimation details are provided in the appendix.

  21. The results do not change if we use the median values of the four estimates in the tests.

  22. Hail and Leuz (2006) argue that the estimation of the implied cost-of-capital models makes simplified assumptions about long-term growth rates beyond the explicit forecast horizons of analysts. These assumptions are likely to have measurement errors that could confound the results.

References

  • Acharya VV, Pedersen LH (2005) Asset pricing with liquidity risk. J Financ Econ 77(2):375–410

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Amihud Y (2002) Illiquidity and stock returns: cross-section and time series effects. J Financ Markets 5(1):31–56

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Botosan C (1997) Disclosure level and the cost of equity capital. Account Rev 72:323–349

    Google Scholar 

  • Botosan C, Plumlee M (2005) Assessing alternative proxies for the expected risk premium. Account Rev 80(1):21–53

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Boulding W, Lee E, Staelin R (1994) Mastering the mix: do advertising, promotions and sales force activities lead to differentiation? J Market Res 31(2):159–172

    Google Scholar 

  • Brav A, Lehavy R, Michaely R (2005) Using expectations to test asset pricing models. Financ Manag 34(3):31–64

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Chan LKC, Lakonishok J, Sougiannis T (2001) The stock market valuation of research and development expenditures. J Finance 56(6):2431–2456

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Chen KCW, Chen Z, Wei KCJ (2009) Disclosure, corporate governance and the cost of equity in emerging market. J Corporate Finance 15(3):273–289

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cheng CSA, Collins D, Huang HH (2006) Shareholder rights, financial disclosure and the cost of equity capital. Rev Quant Financ Acc 27(2):175–204

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Claus JJ, Thomas JK (2001) Equity premia as low as three percent? Evidence from analysts’ earnings forecasts for domestic and international stock markets. J Finance 56(5):1629–1666

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Core J (2001) A review of the empirical disclosure literature: discussion. J Account Econ 31(1–3):441–456

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dechow P, Dichev I (2002) The quality of accruals and earnings: the role of accounting estimation errors. Account Rev 77(supplementary):35–59

    Google Scholar 

  • Easton P (2004) PE ratios, PEG ratios, and estimating the implied expected rate of return on equity capital. Account Rev 79(1):73–95

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Elton EJ (1999) Expected return, realized return and asset pricing tests. J Finance 59(4):1199–1220

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Erickson G, Jacobson R (1992) Gaining comparative advantage through discretionary expenditures: the returns to R&D and advertising. Manage Sci 38(9):1264–1279

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fama EF, French KR (1997) Industry costs of equity. J Financ Econ 43(2):153–193

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fama EF, MacBeth JD (1973) Risk, return and equilibrium: empirical test. J Polit Econ 81(3):607–636

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Francis J, LaFond R, Olsson P, Schipper K (2004) Costs of equity and earnings attributes. Account Rev 79(4):976–1010

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gebhardt WR, Lee CMC, Swaminathan B (2001) Toward an implied cost of capital. J Account Res 39(1):135–176

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gelb DS, Siegel P (2000) Intangible assets and corporate signaling. Rev Quant Financ Acc 15(4):307–324

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gode D, Mohanram P (2003) Inferring the cost of capital using the Ohlson-Juettner model. Rev Acc Stud 8(4):399–431

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Grullon G, Kanatas G, Weston JP (2004) Advertising, breadth of ownership, and liquidity. Rev Financ Stud 17(2):439–461

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hail L, Leuz C (2006) International differences in cost of capital: do legal institutions and securities regulation matter? J Account Res 44(3):485–531

    Google Scholar 

  • Hsieh TY, Chuang SS, Lin CC (2008) Impact of tick-size reduction on the market liquidity—evidence from the emerging order-driven market. Rev Pacific Basin Financ Markets Policies 11(4):591–616

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kihlstrom RE, Riordan MH (1984) Advertising as a signal. J Polit Econ 92(31):427–450

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Klein A (1998) Firm performance and board committee structure. J Law Econ 41(1):275–303

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Larcker DF, Rusticus TO (2010) On the use of instrumental variables in accounting research. J Account Econ 49(3):186–205

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lehavy R, Sloan R (2008) Investor recognition and stock return. Rev Acc Stud 13:327–361

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Merton R (1987) A simple model of capital market equilibrium with incomplete information. J Finance 42(3):483–510

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Nelson P (1974) Advertising as information. J Polit Econ 82(4):729–754

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Newey WK, West KD (1987) A simple, positive semi-definite, heteroskedasticity and autocorrelation consistent covariance matrix. Econometrica 55(3):703–708

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ohlson J (1995) Earnings, book values, and dividends in equity valuation. Contempor Account Res 11:661–687

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ohlson JAM, Juettner-Nauroth BE (2005) Expected EPS and EPS growth as determinants of value. Rev Acc Stud 10(2–3):349–365

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Pastor L, Stambaugh RF (2003) Liquidity risk and expected stock returns. J Polit Econ 11(3):642–685

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Pastor L, Sinha M, Swaminathan B (2008) Estimating the intertemporal risk-return tradeoff using the implied cost of capital. J Finance 63(6):2859–2891

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Rupp WT, Smith AD (2003) Challenges associated with web-based strategies: implications for electronic advertising. J Internet Commerce 3:65–86

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Singh M, Sheri F, Nejadmalayeri A (2005) Capital market impact of product market strategy: evidence from the relationship between advertising expenses and cost of capital. J Acad Market Sci 33(4):432–444

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Stigler GJ (1961) The economics of information. J Polit Econ 69(3):213–225

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Stulz RM (1999) Globalization of equity markets and the cost of capital. NBER working paper

  • Tirole J (1995) The theory of industry organization. MIT Press, Cambridge

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgments

We are grateful to Alon Brav for access to estimates of implied cost-of-equity capital based on Value Line reports. The authors appreciate the comments from Cheng Few Lee (the editor), two anonymous reviewers, John Wei, Chu Zhang, Guochang Zhang and seminar participants at the Hong Kong Polytechnic University. The authors acknowledge the financial support of the Hong Kong Polytechnic University Research Grant (A-PA7J).

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Yuan Huang.

Appendix: Estimation of cost-of-equity capital

Appendix: Estimation of cost-of-equity capital

To ease the discussion, we first define the variables used in the following four models:

P t :

Market price of a firm’s common stock at time t. We use the price at month +4 after the latest fiscal year end

B t :

Book value of equity from the most recent available financial statement at time t

FEPS t+i :

Median forecasted EPS from I/B/E/S or derived EPS forecasts for next ith year at time t

POUT:

Forecasted dividends payout ratio. We use the ratio of the indicated annual dividends from I/B/E/S to FEPSt+1 to measure the forecasted payout ratio. If FEPSt+1 is negative, we assume a return of assets of 6% to calculate earnings. If the indicated annual dividends are missing in I/B/E/S, we use four times the cash dividends paid in the previous fiscal quarter instead. POUT is winsorized between 0 and 1.

1.1 Rgls: Gebhardt et al. (2001)

$$ P_{t}^{*} = B_{t} + \sum\limits_{i = 1}^{T - 1} {{\frac{{\left[ {{\text{FROE}}_{t + i} - R_{\text{GLS}} } \right] \times B_{t + i - 1} }}{{\left( {1 + R_{\text{GLS}} } \right)^{i} }}}} + {\frac{{\left[ {{\text{FROE}}_{t + T} - R_{\text{GLS}} } \right] \times B_{t + T - 1} }}{{\left( {1 + R_{\text{GLS}} } \right)^{T - 1} R_{\text{GLS}} }}} $$
(4)

We explicitly use I/B/E/S analysts’ forecasts to proxy for the market expectation of a firm’s earnings for the next 3 years. Thereafter, the model measures the market earnings expectation by assuming that the future return on equity declines linearly to an equilibrium return on equity from the fourth year to the Tth year. This equilibrium return on equity is measured by a historical, 10-year, industry-specific median return on equity. The return on equity (ROE) is calculated as income available for common shareholders (Compustat data item #237) scaled by the lagged total book value of equity (Compustat data item #60). We classify all firms into 48 industries as defined by Fama and French (1997). Firm-year observations with a negative return on equity are eliminated in the calculation. The future book value of equity is estimated by assuming the clean surplus relation, that is, B t+1 = B t  + EPS t+1 − DPS t+1. The future dividend, DPS t+i , is calculated by multiplying EPS t+i by POUT. We assume that T = 12. We use a numerical approximation program to solve for Rgls that equates the right- and left-hand sides of Eq. (4) within a $0.001 difference.

1.2 Rct: Claus and Thomas (2001)

This model is similar to the one introduced by Gebhardt et al. (2001), except that it assumes that the abnormal earnings after 5 years grow at a rate of (1 + g lt) in perpetuity, where g lt is analysts’ long-term growth forecast. Under this assumption, we have

$$ P_{t}^{*} = B_{t} + \sum\limits_{i = 1}^{5} {{\frac{{\left[ {{\text{FEPS}}_{t + i} - R_{\text{CT}} \times B_{t + i - 1} } \right]}}{{\left( {1 + R_{\text{CT}} } \right)^{i} }}}} + {\frac{{\left[ {{\text{FEPS}}_{t + 5} - R_{\text{CT}} \times B_{t + 4} } \right] \times \left( {1 + g_{\text{lt}} } \right)}}{{\left( {R_{\text{CT}} - g_{\text{lt}} } \right)\left( {1 + R_{\text{CT}} } \right)^{5} }}} $$
(5)

To implement the model, we explicitly use the I/B/E/S earnings forecasts to derive the abnormal earnings for the next 5 years. Earnings forecasts for the future fourth and fifth years are derived from earnings forecasts for the future third year and the long-term earnings growth rate. If the latter is missing in I/B/E/S, an implied earnings growth rate from EPS t+2 and EPS t+3 is used instead. The long-term abnormal earnings growth rate is calculated using the contemporaneous risk-free rate (the yield on 10-year treasury bonds) minus 3%. The future book value of equity is also estimated by assuming the clean surplus relation, that is, B t+1 = B t  + EPS t+1 − DPS t+1. The future dividend, DPSt+i, is calculated by multiplying EPSt+i by the payout ratio, POUT. We use a numerical approximation program to solve for Rct that equates the right- and left-hand sides of Eq. (5) within a $0.001 difference.

1.3 Roj: Ohlson and Juettner-Nauroth (2005) implemented by Gode and Mohanram (2003)

$$ P_{t}^{*} = {\frac{{E_{t} \left( {{\text{EPS}}_{t + 1} } \right)}}{{R_{\text{OJ}} }}} + {\frac{{E_{t} \left( {{\text{EPS}}_{t + 1} } \right)E_{t} \left[ {g_{\text{st}} - R_{\text{OJ}} \times \left( {1 - {\text{POUT}}} \right)} \right]}}{{R_{\text{OJ}} \left( {R_{\text{OJ}} - g_{\text{lt}} } \right)}}} $$
(6)

where \( g_{\text{st}} = {\frac{{{\text{EPS}}_{t + 2} - {\text{EPS}}_{t + 1} }}{{{\text{EPS}}_{t + 1} }}} \). The implementation requires EPS t+1 > 0 and EPS t+2 > 0.

The long-term asymptotic growth rate, g lt , is calculated using the contemporaneous risk-free rate (the yield on 10-year treasury bonds) minus 3%. We use a numerical approximation program to solve for Roj that equates the right- and left-hand sides of Eq. (6) within a $0.001 difference.

1.4 Rmpeg: Modified PEG ratio model by Easton (2004)

$$ P_{t}^{*} = {\frac{{E_{t} \left( {{\text{EPS}}_{t + 1} } \right)}}{{R_{\text{MPEG}} }}} + {\frac{{E_{t} \left( {{\text{EPS}}_{t + 1} } \right)E_{t} \left[ {g_{\text{st}} - R_{\text{MPEG}} \times \left( {1 - {\text{POUT}}} \right)} \right]}}{{R_{\text{MPEG}}^{2} }}} $$
(7)

We use a numerical approximation program to solve for Rmpeg that equates the right- and left-hand sides of Eq. (7) within a $0.001 difference. This model requires E t (EPSt+2) ≥ E t (EPSt+1) ≥ 0.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Cite this article

Huang, Y., Wei, S.X. Advertising intensity, investor recognition, and implied cost of capital. Rev Quant Finan Acc 38, 275–298 (2012). https://doi.org/10.1007/s11156-011-0228-1

Download citation

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s11156-011-0228-1

Keywords

JEL Classification

Navigation